National Poverty Center Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy, University of Michigan www.npc.umich.edu “Consumption, Income, and the Well‐Being of Families and Children” This paper was delivered at a National Poverty Center conference. Any opinions, findings, conclusions, or recommendations expressed in this material are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the view of the National Poverty Center or any sponsoring agency. Consumption, Income, and Well-Being Among the Mature Population Kerwin Kofi Charles* Sheldon Danziger ** Laurie Pounder** Robert F. Schoeni** April 2006 Abstract: Using nationally representative survey data, from a mature population that includes measures of income, consumption, and a broad set of indicators of well-being, we study whether income or consumption better identifies individuals' material well-being. We find that, for the mature population, income appears superior to consumption. We provide some speculative evidence about why this relationship is different than that found for other populations in the recent literature. * University of Chicago. ** University of Michigan. Financial support was received from a grant to the National Poverty Center at the University of Michigan from the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, U. S. Department of Health and Human Services. Address correspondence to Robert Schoeni, University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Ann Arbor, MI 48109; bschoeni@umich.edu. Any views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Poverty Center. CONSUMPTION, INCOME, AND WELL-BEING AMONG THE MATURE POPULATION I. INTRODUCTION What is the best way to summarize an individual’s well-being – especially whether or not they fall below the poverty threshold? In both policy applications and academic research, conventional practice is to classify individuals as poor on the basis of their income. Incomebased poverty measures have much to recommend them. First, because income is readily available on many household surveys and from various business and tax records, estimating income poverty is straightforward. Second, because income data have been collected for many years and in most countries, trends in poverty within a country over time and comparisons in poverty across countries can be readily studied. Finally, an income-based measure corresponds to the size of a households’ budget set – the amount of goods and services it could command. Income-based poverty measures are agnostic about differences in preferences which might cause households to allocate resources differently out of their disposable income. Measuring poverty using income classifies households based on what they are able to do given the resources they command, rather than based on what they choose to do with those resources – a distinction that is appealing because it denotes poverty as an economic constraint. Despite these advantages, many authors have argued that measuring poverty on the basis of consumption might be superior to the conventional income-based approach (Jencks, 1984; Mayer and Jencks, 1989; Slesnick, 2001). Because income fluctuations from one year to the next tend to be greater than consumption fluctuations, income measured in any given period is, at best, an imperfect indicator of a household’s true underlying level of hardship. By contrast, theory suggests that households smooth consumption over time, with the relatively constant level consumed over the lifecycle reflecting people’s true underlying level of command over resources, or their latent “permanent income.” That an individual’s income at any point in time is only weakly related to her underlying level of economic hardship is documented by Jencks and Mayer (1989; 1993) who show that income-based poverty explains only about one quarter of the variation in explicit questions of 2 material hardship.1 Similarly, Meyer and Sullivan (2003; 2004) show that hardship among single-mother families is better predicted by low consumption than by low reported income. A second reason for measuring poverty based on consumption relates to measurement error. Meyer and Sullivan (2003) show that reported consumption at the lower end of the income distribution often exceeds reported income. Of course, this fact does not reveal whether it is income or consumption that is mis-reported. However, they argue it is likely that most measurement error is attached to income, especially for those at the lower end of the distribution due to differences in the complexity of reporting income and consumption. For persons of low income, flows of income into the household come from a range of earnings and transfers, some of which may be in kind (Edin and Lein, 1997). Moreover, because eligibility for certain government programs requires that a household’s income remain below some level, low income respondents may be inclined to underreport income to survey interviewers. The situation is different for consumption; households gain nothing by claiming to have consumed less or more than is true, and, it is argued, consumption for these households can be more succinctly summarized. In this paper, we use the Health and Retirement Study to evaluate income poverty, consumption poverty and their associations with a range of hardship indicators among mature Americans (those over 52 years of age). The connection between income, consumption and well-being differs for older persons compared to the rest of the population. For example, theory suggests that mature persons are more likely to have consumption which exceeds income for reasons of life-cycle consumption so that an income/consumption differential does not necessarily suggest the presence of measurement error in income. Mature persons also confront circumstances that make their poverty experiences qualitatively different from that of younger persons. One factor is labor force withdrawal, which lowers earnings and raises dependence on previously-acquired savings to maintain consumption levels and the receipt of government transfers like Social Security. Finally, elderly persons typically experience reductions in health and physical functioning that contribute to significant expenditures on health and personal care. We begin by measuring the incidence of poverty using both income and consumption measures. We find that fewer mature persons are consumption poor than are income poor. 1 Indeed, these authors find that controls for permanent income do not appreciably increase the explanatory power of income-based measures, further raising concerns about how accurately any measure of income measures the level of hardship a family confronts. 3 These results are similar to those of Meyer and Sullivan (2003) who study income and consumption poverty among welfare mothers, and Slesnick (1993) and Cutler and Katz (1991) who find that the prevalence of consumption poverty is generally lower than its income-based counterpart, especially for the elderly. We document that the consumption poor are not merely a subset of the income poor because many consumption poor households are not classified as poor under an income-based measure. Having estimated two measures of poverty among mature persons, we consider which measure is more highly correlated with a range of indicators of economic and other hardships. Previous work, with the possible exception of Cutler and Katz (1991), suggests that the consumption based measures should be preferred.2 For example, although he does not directly measure hardship, Poterba (1990) argues that consumption-based measures are superior to income measures as indicators of economic well-being for the elderly.3 Similarly, Slesnick argues that consumption-based rather than income-based measures best identify persons who most need assistance. Finally, Meyer and Sullivan (2003; 2004), in a several recent papers focused on single mother families, find that their consumption poverty tends to be more strongly correlated with alternative measures of material hardship than is true for income poverty. Following a similar procedure to that of Meyer and Sullivan, we relate households’ income poverty and consumption poverty to a range of indicators of economic hardship, including subjective wellbeing, home quality, and food security. We find that, across many measures, consumption poverty is not more closely associated with hardship than is income poverty. Thus, the superiority of consumption-based poverty measures over income-based measures cannot be presumed for all subpopulations. For mature persons, a complete picture of poverty seems to require knowing about both the degree to which both household income and consumption do not rise to particular levels. We discuss in the end of the paper why this might be more likely for the mature population than for other groups of poor persons. The remainder of the paper is as follows. In the next section, we describe the data we analyze from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS). In Section III, we classify mature 2 Cutler and Katz (1991) contend that income-based poverty measures are not appreciably worse than consumption measures. They show that consumption and income moved very closely in the 1980s and that groups with large declines in income tended to have similar declines in consumption. They conclude that, “ Standard income-based measures do not seem to be a misleading guide to change in the distribution of permanent income.” 3 Poterba implicitly argues that the divergence between income and consumption is a measure of the degree of mismeasurement in the former. He shows that the divergence between one’s position in the income and expenditure distributions is larger for mature persons than for other groups, hence he recommends the use of consumption. 4 individuals by whether they are poor as defined by income on the one hand and consumption on the other, and assess the degree to which these classifications overlap. In Sections IV and V, we relate individuals’ positions in the income and consumption distributions to their levels of material hardship. Section IV looks at the relationship between well-being and being specifically in the two categories of persons who are income and consumption poor; Section V studies how well-being is related to consumption and income throughout the entire distribution of these two variables. In Section VI, we discuss alternative explanations for our finding that consumption seems to a worse – and certainly does not do a better – job of identifying hardship for mature persons than do income based measures. II. DATA The 2001 Consumption and Activities Mail Survey (CAMS) of the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) panel was mailed to a random sample of 5,000 HRS households, who were interviewed by telephone in 2000. With a response rate of seventy-seven percent, the 2001 CAMS data has 3,866 household observations. Designed to be nationally representative of the population over age 50 as of 1998, by 2001 the HRS, and therefore the CAMS, includes households with respondents aged 53 and over. The CAMS asked respondents about individual activities and household consumption across twenty-six separate categories. Consumption expenditures were reported in weekly, monthly, or annual amounts. Respondents were also asked for purchase prices paid in the past twelve months on vehicles and on specific household durable goods.4 Comparing the consumption categories included in the CAMS with the more-detailed Consumer Expenditure Survey (CE) shows that the CAMS accounts for over 90 percent of total CE spending. Despite a less-comprehensive list of categories, after annualizing amounts 4 Household durables in the CAMS include refrigerators, dishwashers, washing machines, TVs, and computers. 5 reported as weekly or monthly in the CAMS, total average annual spending in the CAMS is somewhat higher than in the CE for this population (Hurd and Rohwedder, 2006).5 The expenditure information in the CAMS is not equivalent to the economic concept of consumption. This is particularly true for the elderly – many of whom consume housing with almost no expenditures because they own their homes outright. Thus, total consumption differs from CAMS total spending in two ways. First, the purchase price for vehicles and household durables is not included in current consumption. (Any difference between purchase price and actual expenditure that year, most relevant for vehicles, is not available in CAMS). Instead, a value for vehicle consumption is imputed based on the relationship between household characteristics and net outlays on new and used cars and trucks in the 2001 CE. Second, for homeowners, spending on mortgage, property tax, and homeowners’ insurance is replaced by an imputed rental equivalence value for their home. Rental equivalence values were estimated using the relationship between housing characteristics and reported rental equivalence for owned homes in the 2001 CE. These imputations are described more fully in the appendix. Income data are drawn from the 2002 HRS core interview which administered a detailed set of questions about all income sources. The core HRS interview is also the source of numerous measures of well-being. III. THE JOINT DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME AND CONSUMPTION POVERTY Table 1 shows the joint distribution of families across the two poverty measures. The columns divide the sample into three income-based poverty categories; the rows do the same for consumption poverty. A household’s income is divided by the official poverty line defined for its household size and whether or not the family head is aged 65 or older. Poor families are those with a ratio of less than 100 percent of their poverty threshold; near poor families are those with incomes between 101 and 150 percent of the relevant threshold; and non-poor are those with 5 Following a procedure suggested by Hurd and Rohwedder (2006), the CAMS data were modified to address design and data entry issues. To identify egregious cases of decimal placement error or respondent error where monthly or annual dollar figures were reported as weekly or monthly spending, for certain spending categories, each household’s reported annualized spending in the 2001 CAMS was compared to its response in the 2003 CAMS. Where spending within a category varied between these years by more than a factor of 6, reasonable ranges were used to determine if one observation was distorted by a factor of 12 (monthly for annual), 52/12 (weekly for monthly), or 100 (misplaced decimal). In addition, twelve outliers in the categories of home maintenance and yard supplies were adjusted for decimal placement and time period errors based on visual inspection of the handwritten questionnaire. 6 family incomes greater than 150 percent of the relevant threshold. This classification scheme is similar to those used by other authors who have studied income and consumption poverty. The last row in the first column shows that in 2001, 13.9 percent of individuals ages 53 and older were income poor in the HRS/CAMS. The second and third columns of the last row show that 11.2 and 74.9 percent of HRS/CAMS respondents were, respectively, near-poor and nonpoor. The consumption poverty rate of 6.9 percent shown in the first row and last column of the table is half the income poverty rate. This consumption poverty rate is very similar to consumption poverty rates found for the 1980s by authors like Cutler and Katz (1991), and Slesnick (1989).6 Another 8.8 percent of respondents are near consumption poor and 84.3 percent are not consumption poor. The table allows for an easy examination of the extent to which households’ poverty status overlap as defined by the two measures. We find that only thirty percent (4.2/13.9) of the income poor are also consumption poor. About two-thirds of the income poor are not consumption poor: twenty-two percent (3.1/13.9) are consumption near-poor and 47 percent are not consumption poor. Thus, given that a household is income poor, it is relatively difficult to predict the category into which it falls on the dimension of consumption poverty. Is it similar difficult to predict income poverty, conditional on knowing a household’s consumption poverty? The first row of Table1 shows that fully forty percent of the consumption poor [(1.2 + 1.5)/6.9] are not income poor; these consumption poor families are either income near poor or non-poor as measured by income. The joint distribution presented in Table 1 shows that the consumption poor are not simply a subset of the income poor; to a significant degree the populations corresponding to the two different poverty measures are not overlapping. Table 2 displays the relationship between income and consumption for the full distribution of income (columns) and consumption (rows), divided into deciles. Both income and consumption are adjusted for family size differences using the official poverty line equivalence scales. The table shows that at both the upper and lower ends of the distribution, individuals’ relative positions in the income and consumption distributions are quite similar. For example, among individuals in the lowest income decile, 39 percent are in the lowest 6 Cutler and Katz estimate elderly consumption poverty ranging from 4 to 6 percent over the 1980s. Slesnick has rates of 5 to 11 percent for those ages 55 to 64 and 2 to 4 percent for those over age 65, averaging about 6 percent across the years and the two age groups. 7 consumption decile, and 67 percent are within the bottom three deciles. Only 10 percent of the lowest income decile rise to the top three deciles in the consumption distribution. The patterns are broadly similar reading across the rows. Eighty percent of those in the lowest consumption decile are in the bottom three income deciles, while only 1 percent of those in either of the top two income deciles are in the lowest consumption decile. In the middle of both the income and consumption distributions, individuals tend to be more evenly distributed across deciles as defined by the alternative measures. For example individuals in the 5th consumption decile are equally likely to be in any income decile from the 3rd to the 8th. Similarly, individuals in the 5th income decile are distributed relatively evenly across the 3rd to 8th deciles of consumption. Overall, the simple correlation between an individual’s income-to-needs rank and their consumption-to-needs rank is 0.54. Looking across the entries in the table, it is clear that this relatively small number reflects the fluidity in the middle of the two distributions. However, for persons in either the lowest income or consumption deciles, being in one of these very low-resource groups is rarely associated with being in a substantially higher category according to the other measure. IV. INCOME AND CONSUMPTION POVERTY AND WELL-BEING The HRS/CAMS includes many measures of well-being across several domains, including physical health, mental health, housing, food security, and wealth. Intuitively, it would seem that a measure which more accurately represented true underlying poverty would be much more closely associated with these alternative objective indicators of hardship. Our results indicate that, consumption poverty appears much more weakly associated with direct measures of hardship than income poverty. The top panel of Table 3 shows results for twelve indicators of physical health. Only for one—arthritis--is there a statistically greater prevalence among the consumption poor than among the income poor, where “poor” is here defined as being in the lowest decile. For the other categories of physical health, mean prevalence does not differ significantly for those in the bottom decile of income and consumption. Within the second decile, five physical health indicators--hypertension, heart disease, arthritis, activities of daily living (ADL), and instrumental activities of daily living (IADL)--are statistically significant and worse for the income poor relative to the consumption poor. In no 8 case is the prevalence of any physical health problem higher for the second consumption decile than for the second income decile. A similar pattern is evident for the five mental health problems shown in the second panel of Table 3. In the two cases where there are statistically significant differences between the bottom income decile and the bottom consumption decile--not enjoying life in the past week, and not being happy in the past week--the income poor have lower well-being. The nine housing variables shown in the third panel include subjective measures, such as quality of housing and neighborhoods, and objective measures, such as the number of rooms in the home. However, some objective measures, specifically the number of rooms and the type of housing (single family home, mobile home, etc), are included in the imputation of rental equivalence and therefore directly affect the consumption measure. Therefore, it is not surprising that the bottom income group has more rooms in their homes than the bottom consumption group (5.1 vs. 4.6 rooms). Since these measures are mechanically related to consumption, they cannot be interpreted as independent indicators of well-being from the perspective of comparing income and consumption measures. For the housing and neighborhood quality measures that are not included in imputed consumption, the estimated correlations with hardship do not, in general, suggest that the consumption poor are worse off than the income poor. For example, individuals in the lowest income decile report living in worse neighborhoods than those in the lowest consumption decile: 24.7 vs. 16.6 percent, respectively, say their neighborhood is fair or poor quality. The rental equivalence consumption attributed to homeowners also means that the bottom consumption decile contains relatively few homeowners, generating low mean housing wealth for the consumption poor. This translates into somewhat higher mean total asset levels for the income poor relative to the consumption poor: $88,400 vs. $52,800. Average values for wealth are, however, highly susceptible to outliers. Because of this concern, we trim 1 percent from the top and bottom of the wealth distributions. The mean asset values for income and consumption poor with this trimmed sample fall to $59,400 and $45,500 respectively, which are not significantly different (not shown in tables). We also find no significant difference in nonhousing wealth. (The trimmed estimates show slightly higher values for the consumption poor). Finally, total assets including housing wealth is indistinguishable at the median of the distribution. 9 Socio-demographic factors are highly correlated with well-being, and the distribution of these factors for each of the two groups is displayed at the bottom of Table 3. The two groups are fairly similar in terms of education and racial composition. The age distributions, however, differ. The age distribution of the bottom two consumption deciles looks not unlike the age distribution for the whole sample. However, for income, the mean age jumps from 64.9 for the lowest decile to 71.7 for the second decile. Compared to the second decile, the lowest decile is less populated by the retired and widows and more populated by disabled, unemployed, maritally separated, and other households with recent income losses, all of which tend to be younger than the retirees and widows that make up more of the second decile. In Table 4, we report differences in well-being between the income poor and the consumption poor for each measure shown in Table 3. The first and fifth columns, labeled “All,” replicate the differences from columns three and six of Table 3, respectively. The other columns show these differences when the sample is restricted to retirees or to widows, or when medical out of pocket expenditures (“No MOOP”) are excluded from consumption. The deciles evaluated in each column pertain to the bottom and second lowest decile within that subsample. Much interest in old-age poverty focuses on widows, who account for 35 percent of poor people 65 and older. Among widows, there is no evidence that the consumption poor are worse off than the income poor. For example, six measures of well-being are found to be statistically significantly different between the income and consumption poor, but four show that well-being is worse for the income poor than the consumption poor. And the only two comparisons that favor consumption variables are both mechanically related to imputed consumption (single family home and number of rooms in the house). In the second decile, well-being is worse for the consumption poor for two of the three significantly different indicators that are not used to impute consumption. Table 4 also shows analyses restricted to individuals who report themselves as having retired from the labor force. There are even fewer statistical differences for the retired: only two indicators not used to impute consumption had significant differences between those in the bottom deciles of income and consumption. One was worse for the consumption poor (arthritis) and one was worse for the income poor (home condition). Thus far, we have included medical out-of-pocket spending (MOOP) in total consumption. Some MOOP spending, such as nursing-home services or home health care, 10 represents direct consumption of services and should be included in consumption expenditures. But some MOOP spending, such as on prescription drugs, may be treated as analogous to durable goods purchases, with flows of good health resulting from the purchase. Returning to the entire sample, columns 4 and 8 in Table 4 compare well-being between the income and consumption poor if MOOP is excluded from consumption. The results are quite similar to those in columns 1 and 5 respectively for all spending. On the whole, we find that across multiple measures, and for particular sub-groups of the elderly, consumption poverty is either less closely or equally (in a statistical sense) related to hardship than is income poverty. V. INCOME, CONSUMPTION AND WELLBEING THROUGHOUT THE DISTRIBUTION IS WELL-BEING The preceding section looks at the relationship between poverty and well-being according to income and consumption. In this section, we study how well-being is related to income and consumption through the full distributions for these two variables. Formally, for each of the 23 indicators of well-being, we estimate a regression controlling for age and gender, with the key covariate being the individual’s percentile in the distribution of income-to-needs. Identical models are estimated using the percentile of the consumption-to-needs distribution as the key covariate. Again, the logic here is that the estimated relationship between well-being and percentile rank would be larger for whichever outcome (income or consumption) better reflects underlying well-being. For all 23 measures, we expect that higher income and consumption will be associated with higher well-being, keeping in mind that for some measures (i.e., “own a second home” and “number of rooms”) a higher value means a better outcome. The results in Table 5 show that this expectation is confirmed for 22 of the 23 measures, with the exception being cancer, which shows a small positive association with both income and consumption. All of the regression coefficients in Table 5 are significant. Logit models are estimated for all dichotomous dependent variables and OLS for the remaining dependent variables. The association with income and consumption is substantial for many outcomes. An increase in income-to-needs percentile by 10 points lowers the probability of being in poor or fair health by 4.5 percentage points (column 2). A similar increase in the consumption-to-needs percentile is associated with a reduction in the probability of being in fair or poor health of 2.9 11 percentage points (column 4). BTthe consumption effect is statistically significantly smaller than the income effect (column 5). Taking all of the results together, for only 2 of the 23 indicators (cancer and number of rooms) is consumption more strongly associated with the indicator than is income, and the difference between the measures for these two indicators is not significant. Clearly the evidence does not support the use of consumption over income. The regression specifications in Table 5 implicitly presume an underlying linear relationship for the patterns of interest. We loosened this assumption by calculating nonparametric estimates of the relationships of interest. Figures 1-8 display non-parametric kernel density plots for eight different well-being measures assuming a band width of 0.4 (0.2 leads to the same substantive conclusions), the top panel for income and the bottom panel for consumption. These plots reveal the same basic pattern as those shown in Table 5. That is, there is no evidence indicating that consumption is more strongly associated with well-being. The models in Table 5 use the percentile of the income-to-needs ratio or the consumption-to-needs ratio as the key covariate. An alternative would be to focus on the marginal effect on well-being of a needs-adjusted dollar increase in income or consumption. These results (Table 6) are qualitatively quite similar to those shown earlier, in that they again show a generally weaker estimated relationship between consumption and well-being than that between income and well-being. VI. WHY IS CONSUMPTION NOT A BETTER MEASURE OF WELL-BEING? Why does consumption appear to be an inferior measure of well-being and actual hardship among mature individuals as compared to income? Earlier, we noted that several considerations ought conceptually to affect the relative desirability of income versus consumption as indicators of underlying well-being. In the particular case of the mature population, three of these factors, lower the relative desirability of consumption as a measure of well-being. One consideration is measurement error. Unlike the young single mothers or other at-risk groups, income flows for the elderly may well be measured with considerably less error. Social Security income is a large part of the transfers the elderly receive, and the value of these flows can be readily determined. Simply because of the relatively small errors that confound it, income for the elderly may more accurately reflect underlying well-being. 12 Another consideration has to do with the fact that some aspects of measured consumption do not reflect expenditures on outlays for things that are unambiguously “good”. A prime example of this type of consumption is that spent on health care. Individuals oftentimes devote resources to health care because in fact their well-being has deteriorated and they need medical treatment. For no other group do health expenditures constitute as large a part of overall measured consumption as it does for the elderly. For this reason alone, we would expect consumption – especially measured in the form of expenditures as is done in the paper and in most of the literature – to be an imperfect indicator of true well-being for the elderly. A third consideration about consumption-based measures is that such measures necessarily involve an element of choice. Thus, someone measured in the data as consumption poor might be able to afford more than he or she chooses to expend because of factors related to preferences. Many factors related to preferences probably do not differ between the elderly and other groups, but this is not true about discount rates, time preference, bequest motives, or changing marginal utility for important consumption items. Is there evidence that some portion of the consumption poor are actually consuming less than they could because of preferences? In much of the analysis above, we have compared low income and low consumption households decile by decile and examined the association of income and consumption with wellbeing throughout the distributions. However, both for policy purposes and conceptual clarity, it is also important to describe the population who is income poor and the population who is consumption poor using standard poverty thresholds. In this section, where we briefly review the evidence about the role of preference, we therefore focus on groups characterized by whether they are poor according to the two measures. Table 7 presents the HRS well-being measures for four groups: individuals who are both income and consumption poor, income poor but consumption non-poor, income non-poor but consumption poor, and neither income nor consumption poor.7 The results in the first column demonstrate that the group which is poor by both measures is noticeably, and sometimes dramatically, worse off than any of the other groups. Most measures within each domain-physical health, mental health, housing, food, wealth, and work and income--show very low 7 Any concern about comparing two groups of different sizes (there are more income poor households than consumption poor households) could be addressed by adding the consumption near-poor to the consumption poor group (but no change with the income groups). This would effectively equalize the number of households in the second and third columns of Table 7. Such an exercise shows no substantive change to our analysis or conclusions. 13 levels of well-being for this group. The mean wealth for this truly poor group is about one-tenth that of groups who are poor by only measure, shown in the second and third column. About sixty percent of those who are both income and consumption poor have less than $1000 of net wealth, even including housing assets. The median value for their non-housing assets was just $60 in 2000. The very low outcomes for this group for most dimensions of well-being suggest that their poverty status by either measure reflects the presence of genuine resource constraints. At the other extreme are persons who are not poor by either measure. The mean values for this group are shown in the fourth column. Two findings are noteworthy. One is that, by every measure, these non-poor persons fare better than any other group. The other result is that even though they do not appear to be resource-constrained, some outcomes, especially health, are quite negative.8 While this group is far less likely than others to rate its health as “poor” or “fair”, more than eighty percent have some major health condition. Similarly, one-fifth describes their activities over the past week as having been an “effort”. Thus, as discussed above, the relationship between well-being and control over material resources (or consumption) is complicated for elderly households. Of course, the most interesting numbers in Table 7 are for those persons who are poor by one definition, but not poor by the other. Are income-poor/consumption non-poor households worse off than consumption-poor/income non-poor households? And, what does the difference in their objective indicators of well-being suggest about the degree to which low consumption among the elderly reflects an aspect of choice rather than resource constraint? The table indicates that income poor but consumption non-poor persons (group 2) are, by virtually every measure, either similar to or worse off than consumption poor/ income non-poor persons (group 3).. Among the well-being measures not included in the imputation of consumption, cancer prevalence is the only one that shows substantially lower well-being for the latter group. Group 3 appears to be composed primarily of older persons, who on average are still accumulating wealth, and have relatively low levels of food insecurity and depression, and higher levels of life enjoyment and neighborhood quality. In contrast, the income poor persons in group 2 are, on average, spending down wealth, and have markedly worse food insecurity, 8 That this group is probably not resource constrained is evidenced by the fact that thirteen percent of this group owns a second home. Also, the mean asset values for group overall is more than $350,000. 14 health problems, depression, home condition, and neighborhood quality relative to group3. This income poor group spends five times more than the consumption poor/income non-poor on health expenditures. In addition, the median non-housing wealth for group 2 decreased by 20 percent during this period in contrast to an increase for group 3 of 26 percent. The only measure(s) for which group 3 could be considered worse off than group 2 are the objective housing measures. Among group 3, fifty-five percent are renters and only thirtytwo percent are homeowners. They are more likely to live in mobile homes, less likely to live in single family homes, and have on average fewer rooms in their homes. However, despite homeownership and size of home, subjective measures of home and neighborhood quality suggest that housing conditions for group 2 may actually be worse than that of group 3. In fact, 22 percent of group 2 said their home condition was only fair or poor compared to 13 percent of group 3; 18 percent of group 2 said their neighborhood quality and safety was only fair or poor versus just 5 percent for group 3. The latter is the same as the rate among individuals who are not poor measured either by income or consumption. Overall, the elderly consumption poor who are not income poor do not seem to be particularly needy. They are happy and relatively healthy for their age. The markedly lower health expenditures they make as a result partially accounts for their much lower overall consumption. In contrast, the elderly income-poor/ consumption non-poor demonstrate some of the hardship of those who are poor by both measures. They are likely to have consumption that is exaggerated by larger than average health expenditures and imputed housing consumption that does not align well with their subjective assessments of housing and neighborhood satisfaction. Separate analyses for the populations under and over 65 years old lead to similar characterizations of groups 2 and 3 (not shown in tables; available on request). For the 53-64 year olds, individuals in the income poor group (group 2) are much more likely to be disabled and unemployed (Table 7). The median household in this group lost over half their income between these two periods while the median for the consumption poor/income non-poor (column 3) experienced gains of 6 percent. To summarize, the income poor who are not consumption poor seem to face some economic constraints and hardships and have exaggerated measured consumption relative to their standard of living. The consumption poor/income non-poor are older but healthier, have 15 high subjective measures of satisfaction with their lives and housing, and a large portion of them are still accumulating wealth. VII. DISCUSSION Our results in this paper suggest that income-based measures appear to better distinguish the truly poor than do consumption-based measures. Using a large number of indicators from a broad set of domains including physical health, mental health, housing, food security, and wealth, when there are differences they are in favor of income as a proxy for well-being. The income poor appear to have lower well-being than the consumption poor, and income is more strongly predictive of well-being. Measurement error is an important consideration when comparisons are made between income and consumption. For persons with low income, flows of resources into the household come from a range of sources, including earnings, government transfers, and family transfers, as well as assistance in kind (Edin and Lein, 1997). This complexity of sources of support may lead to under-reporting in typical income surveys. While this may be the case for younger poor families, it may not be as significant for older low-income people. Social Security is the major income source for most elderly households, especially the poor. Social Security is a regular payment made each month with no stigma attached, making it less susceptible to mis-reporting than other government transfers. The typical approach to estimating consumption is to use survey data on expenditures combined with characteristics of durable goods ownership to impute a flow of services from the durables. While collecting accurate income data is difficult, calculating consumption has its own challenges. Some expenditures, such as those for medical care, are quite challenging to measure. Moreover, the imputation of the flows of services from cars, homes, and other durables are derived from imperfect methods that most likely have substantial error. The consumption data used in our analysis, although comparable to the Consumer Expenditure Survey in the aggregate, uses broad categories of spending recalled over a combination of weekly, monthly, and annual time periods, thus making measurement error a potential concern. Finally, consumption and income measures are distinct economic phenomenon and represent different components of financial well-being. Researchers and policy analysts should continue to assess and evaluate both domains and strive to improve their measurement. While a 16 single summary indicator is useful for some policy driven purposes, both measures should be examined by the scientific community. 17 APPENDIX: IMPUTATON OF TOTAL CONSUMPTION Similar to Cutler and Katz (1991), the household characteristics used to impute vehicle consumption include income, family size, education, age, and gender of head, total household expenditures (less vehicle expenditures), and total expenditures squared. The CE measure of vehicle consumption, not outlays, is regressed on these characteristics, all of which are available in the HRS. The coefficients from this imputation regression are applied to households that either report owning a vehicle in the 2000 HRS or report paying vehicle insurance in the CAMS. The imputation regression is reported in Table A1. To impute the flow of consumption from housing, housing characteristics including property value, census district, urban/rural, number of rooms, and type of housing (such as single family, apartment, or trailer) were regressed on reported rental equivalence in the 2001 CE for homes owned by households where the head was over age 52. The coefficients were then applied to each household’s housing characteristics as reported in the 2002 HRS. This regression, whose estimates are reported in Table A2, has an R-square of .40, very similar to that for the hedonic regression in Johnson, Shipp, and Garner (1997) that regresses actual rent paid by renters on factors such as location, rooms, and housing type. 18 REFERENCES Cutler, David and Lawrence Katz (1991) “Macroeconomic Performance and the Disadvantaged” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Vol. 1991 No.2. Edin, Kathryn and Laura Lein. 1997. Making Ends Meet: How Single Mothers Survive Welfare and Low-Wage Work. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Jencks, Christopher. 1984. “The Hidden Prosperity of the 1970s.” Public Interest. 77 (Fall): 3761. Johnson, David, Stephanie Shipp, and Thesia Garner (1997) “Developing Poverty Thresholds Using Expenditure Data” in Proceedings of the Government and Social Statistics Section, American Statistical Association, August 1997. Mayer, Susan E. and Christopher Jencks. 1989. “Poverty and the Distribution of Material Resources.” Journal of Human Resources, 24:88-114. Mayer, Susan E. and Christopher Jencks. 1993. “Recent Trends in Economic Inequality in the United States: Income vs. Expenditure vs. Well-Being,” in Poverty and Prosperity in America at the Close of the Twentieth Century, eds: Edward Wolff and Demitri Popademitrious. New York: St. Martin’s Press. Meyer, Bruce D. and James X. Sullivan. 2004. “The Effect of Welfare and Tax Reform: The Material Well-Being of Single Mothers in the 1980s and 1990s,” Journal of Public Economics, 88, July, 1387-1420. __________. 2003. “Measuring the Well-Being of the Poor Using Income and Consumption” Journal of Human Resources, 38:S, 1180-1220. Poterba, James M. 1990. “Is the Gasoline Tax Regressive?” NBER Working Paper #3578, January. Slesnick, Daniel T. 1993. “Gaining Ground: Poverty in the Postwar United States.” Journal of Political Economy 1901(1): 1-38. Slesnick, Daniel T. 2001. Consumption and Social Welfare: Living Standard and Their Distribution in the United States, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. 19 0 .2 Fair or Poor Health .4 .6 .8 1 Fair or Poor Health Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 .2 Fair or Poor Health .4 .6 .8 1 Fair or Poor Health Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption bandwidth = .4 Figure 1. Proportion in Fair or Poor Health 20 80 100 0 .2 Food Security .4 .6 .8 1 Food Security Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 .2 Food Security .4 .6 .8 1 Food Security Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption bandwidth = .4 Figure 2. Proportion Food Secure 21 80 100 0 .2 Happy Last Week .4 .6 .8 1 Happiness Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 .2 Happy Last Week .4 .6 .8 1 Happiness Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption 80 bandwidth = .4 Figure 3. Proportion Not Unhappy in the Past Week 22 100 0 Felt Depressed Last Week .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Depression Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 Felt Depressed Last Week .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Depression Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption 80 bandwidth = .4 Figure 4. Proportion Who Felt Depressed in the Last Week 23 100 0 Fair or Poor Home Condition .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Fair or Poor Home Condition Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 Fair or Poor Home Condition .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Fair or Poor Home Condition Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption 80 100 bandwidth = .4 Figure 5. Proportion Who Rated The Condition of Their Home Fair or Poor 24 0 .2 Enjoyed Life Last Week .4 .6 .8 1 Life Enjoyment Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 .2 Enjoyed Life Last Week .4 .6 .8 1 Life Enjoyment Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption 80 bandwidth = .4 Figure 6. Proportion Who Were Enjoying Life in the Past Week 25 100 0 Number of ADLs Difficult 2 4 6 ADL Difficulty Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 Number of ADLs Difficult 2 4 6 ADL Difficulty Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption 80 bandwidth = .4 Figure 7. Number of ADLs Have Difficulty With 26 100 0 Number of IADLs Difficult 1 2 3 4 5 IADL Difficulty Across the Income Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Income 80 100 bandwidth = .4 0 Number of IADLs Difficult 1 2 3 4 5 IADL Difficulty Across the Consumption Distribution 0 20 40 60 Percentiles of Consumption 80 bandwidth = .4 Figure 8. Number of IADLs Have Difficulty With 27 100 Table 1. Overlap Between Income and Consumption Poverty Income Poverty Consumption Poverty Poor Near Poor* Non-Poor Total Poor Near Poor* 4.2% 3.1% 6.6% 13.9% 1.2% 2.2% 7.8% 11.2% Non-Poor 1.5% 3.5% 70.0% 74.9% *Near Poor= 101-150% of poverty; Non-Poor=>150% of poverty. Notes: 1. For homeowners, actual expenditure on mortgage, property tax, and home insurance is replaced with imputed rental equivalence. 2. Consumption includes imputed flow value for owned vehicles. 3. Consumption does not include either actual expenditure or flow value for small durables such as washing machines, refridgerators, or computers. 4. Sample is restricted to households that report at least $500 in total spending and that remain in the HRS sample for the 2002 core survey. 28 Total 6.9% 8.8% 84.3% 100.0% Table 2. Conditional Distribution of Income Poverty and Consumption Poverty by Decile Consumption Decile 1 (lowest) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 (lowest) 39 18 10 9 4 7 5 3 2 5 2 3 27 23 15 8 8 7 4 4 2 2 14 17 18 10 14 7 8 4 6 3 Income Decile 4 5 6 6 18 11 14 13 13 10 6 6 5 29 5 8 14 16 11 11 12 11 7 6 2 5 11 14 13 9 11 12 11 12 7 8 9 10 3 4 11 12 13 13 14 11 11 9 3 4 7 12 11 8 13 18 13 10 1 1 3 7 8 19 14 15 19 13 1 1 1 1 5 8 9 16 24 34 Table 3. Measures of Well-Being & Demographics, by Income & Consumption Bottom Decile Income Consumption Difference Physical health Percent Reporting: Fair or poor health 46.8% 47.8% -1.0% Any major health condition 89.5% 91.9% -2.4% Hypertension 57.4% 60.5% -3.1% Diabetes 27.9% 27.3% 0.6% Cancer 12.2% 13.8% -1.6% Lung disease 16.2% 18.1% -1.9% Heart disease 27.5% 32.2% -4.7% Arthritis 65.4% 72.3% -6.9% Stroke 9.2% 8.6% 0.6% Mean Values of: ADL difficulty (max 6) 0.67 0.68 -0.01 ADL get help (max 6) 0.23 0.22 0.01 IADL difficulty (max 5) 0.53 0.52 0.02 Mental health Percent Reporting: Not enjoying life in past week 13.6% 8.3% 5.3% Not happy in past week 24.8% 18.7% 6.1% Depressed in past week 30.9% 28.9% 2.0% Activities an effort past week 45.5% 41.1% 4.4% Psych. health condition 30.6% 28.2% 2.4% Housing & neighborhood Percent Reporting: Own home 50.6% 25.1% 25.5% Home condition fair/poor 23.3% 19.8% 3.5% Neighborhood fair/poor 24.7% 16.6% 8.1% Single family home 60.2% 44.5% 15.7% Mobile home 7.6% 12.2% -4.6% Own 2nd home 4.1% 2.1% 2.0% Own vehicle 56.6% 55.2% 1.4% Mean Values of: Rooms in house 5.1 4.6 0.50 Home condition (range=1-5, 1=excellent) 2.7 2.6 0.10 Food Food Insecure 18.1% 14.9% 3.2% Wealth Mean wealth: all assets $88,400 $52,800 $35,600 Mean wealth: non-housing $44,300 $36,900 $7,400 Median Wealth: all assets $10,000 $4,000 $6,000 Median Wealth: non-housing $800 $1,500 -$700 Demographics Black 24.5% 21.2% 3.3% Hispanic 22.1% 20.0% 2.1% Married 18.7% 24.8% -6.1% Widowed 32.2% 34.8% -2.6% High school or less education 80.3% 80.8% -0.5% More than high school education 18.9% 19.2% -0.3% Age of head 64.9 68.2 -3.3 Household size 2.41 2.42 -0.01 * (**) indicates statistically significant difference at the 0.10 (0.05) level. 30 Second Lowest Decile Income Consumption Difference 42.2% 91.7% 59.7% 24.3% 14.0% 17.0% 34.6% 71.0% 8.0% 38.8% 88.7% 52.6% 22.3% 15.7% 15.0% 26.1% 65.6% 8.4% 3.4% 3.0% 7.1% ** 2.0% -1.7% 2.0% 8.5% ** 5.4% * -0.4% 0.73 0.26 0.52 0.55 0.20 0.32 0.19 ** 0.06 0.20 ** ** * 7.0% 16.2% 24.1% 37.1% 24.2% 9.4% 19.0% 20.1% 34.6% 24.6% -2.4% -2.8% 4.0% 2.5% -0.4% ** 55.1% 17.1% 9.8% 57.3% 9.0% 1.9% 67.0% 58.8% 15.2% 12.4% 57.9% 13.5% 4.0% 74.4% -3.7% 1.9% -2.6% -0.6% -4.5% * -2.1% * -7.4% * 4.9 2.6 5.0 2.6 -0.1 0.0 10.3% 8.4% 1.9% $91,000 $42,700 $28,400 $4,700 $94,700 $58,800 $36,600 $7,400 -$3,700 -$16,100 -$8,200 -$2,700 14.6% 10.2% 19.0% 49.9% 78.8% 21.2% 71.7 1.95 16.9% 8.6% 33.9% 35.9% 77.4% 22.6% 68.2 2.23 -2.3% 1.6% -14.9% 14.0% 1.4% -1.4% 3.5 -0.28 ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** Table 4. Well-Being & Demographics, by Income and Consumption: Subgroubs (Difference: Income minus Consumption) All Bottom Decile Retired Widows Physical health Percent Reporting: Fair or poor health -1.0% -0.9% 2.9% Any major health condition -2.4% -4.0% -2.8% Hypertension -3.1% -3.4% 7.7% Diabetes 0.6% 4.3% 4.4% Cancer -1.6% -0.7% -2.9% Lung disease -1.9% 0.1% 3.8% Heart disease -4.7% -2.3% -3.4% Arthritis -6.9% ** -8.2% ** 2.7% Stroke 0.6% 0.3% 3.8% Mean Values of: ADL difficulty (max 6) -0.01 0.09 0.04 ADL get help (max 6) 0.01 0.09 0.08 IADL difficulty (max 5) 0.02 0.11 -0.16 Mental health Percent Reporting: Not enjoying life in past week 5.3% ** 2.5% 5.3% Not happy in past week 6.1% * 6.4% -2.5% Depressed in past week 2.0% 2.3% 7.5% Activities an effort past week 4.4% 6.8% 11.0% Psych. health condition 2.4% 1.6% 4.3% Housing Percent Reporting: Home condition fair/poor 3.5% 5.6% 10.0% Neighborhood fair/poor 8.1% ** 5.2% 6.7% Single family home 15.7% ** 18.7% ** 27.2% Mobile home -4.6% ** -0.1% -0.4% Own 2nd home 2.0% 0.6% 1.6% Mean Values of: Rooms in house 0.50 ** 0.47 ** 0.71 Home condition (range=1-5, 1=excellent) 0.10 0.21 * 0.49 Food Food insecure 3.2% 5.2% 5.0% Wealth Mean wealth: all assets $35,600 ** $22,900 $1,000 Mean wealth: non-housing $7,400 -$800 -$17,400 Median Wealth: all assets $6,000 Median Wealth: non-housing -$700 Demographics Black 3.3% 6.8% 2.3% Hispanic 2.1% 0.7% 3.0% Married -6.1% -9.3% 0.0% Widowed -2.6% -0.5% 0.0% High school or less education -0.5% 0.6% -1.9% More than high school education -0.3% -1.1% 1.9% Age of head -3.3 ** -4.6 ** -4.8 Household size -0.01 0.27 0.38 * (**) indicates statistically significant difference at the 0.10 (0.05) level. 31 No MOOP -2.5% -3.3% -0.7% -0.9% -2.7% -1.1% -4.1% -8.2% ** -0.2% 0.03 0.06 0.04 * * ** 4.1% 6.5% ** 2.5% 5.5% 0.3% ** 5.4% * 7.2% ** 20.1% ** -5.3% 1.1% ** ** 0.61 ** 0.15 * 4.0% ** Second Lowest Decile Retired Widows All 3.4% 3.0% 7.1% ** 2.0% -1.7% 2.0% 8.5% ** 5.4% * -0.4% 0.19 ** 0.06 0.20 ** -5.0% -2.4% -3.1% -0.7% 1.3% 7.5% -5.0% -2.1% -8.9% ** -10.7% ** -1.5% -5.7% -4.3% -8.7% 0.7% 2.9% -1.8% -1.9% -0.12 -0.07 0.02 -0.07 0.04 0.16 No MOOP 3.2% 0.9% 1.7% 4.2% -2.1% 0.2% 3.7% 4.9% -0.9% 0.09 0.00 0.11 -2.4% -2.8% 4.0% 2.5% -0.4% -0.8% -6.7% * -1.3% -1.3% -1.2% -3.5% -8.8% ** -4.6% 6.7% -4.7% -1.9% -2.4% 3.0% 1.2% 2.2% 1.9% -2.6% -0.6% -4.5% * -2.1% * 2.6% 3.8% 7.4% -7.4% -0.9% 7.4% * 4.5% 9.4% * -8.6% ** 0.7% 1.4% 0.0% -1.0% -5.0% ** -1.6% 0.31 * 0.15 0.0 0.0 -0.1 0.0 0.32 * 0.04 1.9% -0.9% 2.3% 0.4% $35,600 ** $3,400 -$3,700 -$16,100 -$8,200 -$2,700 $1,700 -$18,300 $20,700 $3,900 -$7,200 -$18,300 5.2% 6.6% -1.5% -7.4% 1.4% -2.2% -4.7 ** 0.1 -2.3% 1.6% -14.9% 14.0% 1.4% -1.4% 3.5 -0.28 ** ** ** ** 1.3% -0.7% -10.9% ** 7.0% -1.6% -1.1% 0.9 -0.16 -3.1% 1.2% 0.0% 0.0% 4.4% -4.4% 0.9 0.01 -3.0% -2.4% -20.0% ** 16.8% ** -0.6% 0.8% 3.1 -0.3 ** Table 5. Logit and OLS Coefficients for Predicting Well-Being Measures: Coefficient on Percentile of Income-to-Needs and Consumption-to-Needs Well-being indicator/dependent variable Physical health Fair or poor health Any major health condition Hypertension Diabetes Cancer Lung Heart disease Arthritis Stroke ADL difficulty+ (max 6) Income-to-needs percentile Marginal effect Coefficient of decile change++ [1] [2] -0.242 -0.082 -0.071 -0.168 0.037 -0.132 -0.098 -0.065 -0.177 Consumption-to-needs percentile Difference Marginal effect Coefficient of decile change++ in effect: [2]-[4] [3] [4] [5] ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** -0.045 -0.009 -0.018 -0.023 0.005 -0.013 -0.017 -0.015 -0.008 -0.155 -0.040 -0.038 -0.108 0.031 -0.102 -0.051 -0.050 -0.100 ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** -0.029 -0.006 -0.010 -0.015 0.004 -0.010 -0.009 -0.012 -0.005 -0.016 -0.003 -0.008 -0.008 0.001 -0.003 -0.008 -0.004 -0.003 ** -0.061 ** -0.610 -0.034 ** -0.340 -0.270 ** * ** ** * ADL help+ (max 6) -0.021 ** -0.210 -0.013 ** -0.130 -0.080 * IADL difficulty+ (max 5) Mental health Not enjoying life last week Not happy last week Feel depressed last week Activities an effort last week Psychological disorder Housing Home fair or poor Neighborhood fair or poor Own 2nd home -0.042 ** -0.420 -0.024 ** -0.240 -0.180 ** -0.119 -0.142 -0.190 -0.224 -0.166 ** ** ** ** ** -0.007 -0.015 -0.023 -0.040 -0.020 -0.051 -0.077 -0.112 -0.129 -0.124 ** ** ** ** ** -0.003 -0.008 -0.014 -0.023 -0.015 -0.004 -0.007 -0.009 -0.016 -0.005 -0.299 ** -0.324 ** 0.248 ** -0.020 -0.018 0.021 -0.201 ** -0.177 ** 0.218 ** -0.015 -0.011 0.019 -0.006 ** -0.007 ** 0.002 0.014 ** -0.011 ** 0.142 -0.110 0.015 ** -0.009 ** 0.151 -0.088 -0.009 -0.022 ** -0.306 ** -0.011 -0.023 ** -0.009 -0.002 ** Number of rooms+ Home condition (range=1-5, 1=excellent)+ Food Food insecure + OLS regressions. ++Derivative of logits evaluated at sample means. *Significant at the 90% level **Significant at the 95% level Note: All regressions include age & gender as covariates. 32 * ** ** ** * Table 6. Logit and OLS Coefficients for Predicting Well-Being Measures Coefficient on Income-to-Needs and Consumption-to-Needs Income-to-needs Coefficient [1] Well-being indicator/dependent variable Physical health Fair or poor health Any major health condition Hypertension Diabetes Cancer Lung Heart disease Arthritis Stroke -0.175 -0.023 -0.030 -0.084 0.011 -0.101 -0.035 -0.027 -0.171 Derivative [2] Coefficient [3] ** ** ** ** -0.032 -0.003 -0.007 -0.012 0.001 -0.009 -0.006 -0.006 -0.007 -0.060 -0.012 -0.025 -0.053 0.004 -0.050 -0.005 -0.028 -0.079 ADL difficulty+ (max 6) -0.017 ** ADL help+ (max 6) -0.006 ** IADL difficulty+ (max 5) Mental health Not enjoying life last week Not happy last week Feel depressed last week Activities an effort last week Psychological disorder Housing Home fair or poor Neighborhood fair or poor Own 2nd home Number of rooms+ Home condition (range=1-5, 1=excellent) Food Food insecure + ** ** ** ** Consumption-to-needs ++ Difference in effect: [2]-[4] [5] ** ** -0.012 -0.002 -0.006 -0.007 0.000 -0.005 -0.001 -0.007 -0.004 -0.020 ** -0.001 -0.001 -0.004 0.001 -0.005 -0.005 * 0.000 -0.004 * -0.170 -0.013 ** -0.130 -0.040 -0.060 -0.007 ** -0.070 0.010 -0.011 ** -0.110 -0.013 ** -0.130 0.020 -0.098 -0.090 -0.150 -0.165 -0.092 ** ** ** ** -0.006 -0.009 -0.018 -0.029 -0.011 -0.098 -0.082 -0.104 -0.106 -0.105 ** ** ** ** ** -0.006 -0.009 -0.013 -0.019 -0.013 0.000 -0.001 -0.005 -0.009 ** 0.002 -0.302 ** -0.413 ** 0.063 ** -0.018 -0.017 0.006 -0.140 ** -0.162 ** 0.107 ** -0.011 -0.011 0.010 -0.007 ** -0.007 ** -0.004 ** 0.056 ** 0.560 0.094 ** 0.940 -0.380 ** -0.036 ** -0.360 -0.044 ** -0.440 0.080 -0.129 ** -0.006 -0.324 ** -0.013 0.007 ** + OLS regressions. ++Derivative of logits evaluated at sample means. *Significant at the 90% level **Significant at the 95% level Note. All regressions include age & gender as covariates 33 ** Derivative [4] ++ ** ** ** Table 7. Well-Being, Demographics, & MOOP, by Groups Defined by Poverty Status Income & Consumption Poor (N=173) Group 1 Income Poor, Consumption Non-Poor (N=346) Group 2 Income Non-Poor Consumption Poor (N=123) Group 3 Physical health Percent Reporting: Fair or poor health 56.9% 41.5% Any major health condition 93.2% 88.1% Hypertension 59.7% 56.6% Diabetes 25.2% 29.1% Cancer 11.1% 11.9% Lung disease 19.5% 15.3% Heart disease 36.6% 24.9% Arthritis 76.9% 64.1% Stroke 9.2% 8.4% Mean Values of: ADL difficulty (max 6) 0.643 0.704 ADL get help (max 6) 0.137 0.282 IADL difficulty (max 5) 0.623 0.495 Mental health Percent Reporting: Not enjoying life in past week 13.6% 11.4% Not happy in past week 21.1% 23.4% Depressed in past week 37.8% 26.6% Activities an effort past week 48.5% 41.0% Psych. health condition 37.7% 26.4% Housing Percent Reporting: Own Home 11.4% 66.9% Home condition fair/poor 24.5% 21.9% Neighborhood fair/poor 27.3% 18.1% Single family home 39.0% 67.1% Mobile home 7.9% 8.0% Own 2nd home 0.8% 5.2% Own Vehicle 38.5% 64.0% Mean Values of: Rooms in house 4.3 5.4 Home condition (1=excellent) 2.6 2.7 Food Food Insecure 20.2% 14.2% Wealth 2000 mean wealth: all assets $10,500 $134,400 2000 mean wealth: non-housing $4,800 $83,400 2000 median wealth: all assets $300 $35,500 2000 median wealth: non-housing $60 $2,500 2002 mean wealth: all assets $12,500 $109,100 2002 mean wealth: non-housing $9,700 $49,300 2002 median wealth: all assets $200 $35,000 2002 median wealth: non-housing $60 $2,000 Change in median wealth: non-housing 0% -20% Work and income Disabled^ 57% 42% Unemployed (2000-2001)^ 1% 15% Median income 2001^ $6,600 $6,600 Change in median income^ -8% -56% MOOP & Demographics MOOP $700 $4,300 Share of consumption on MOOP 6.9% 12.2% Black 24% 22% Hispanic 25% 16% Married 11% 23% Widowed 38% 34% Divorced 26% 21% High School or Less Educ 86% 78% More Than HS Educ 14% 22% Age Head 68.0 66.1 Household Size 2.59 2.21 ^Analysis restricted to sample ages 53-64. *=significant at the 90% level and **=significant at the 95% level for the test between groups 2 and 3. 34 36.5% 88.8% 51.6% 23.3% 19.7% 16.1% 24.6% 63.9% 9.2% Income & Consumption Non-Poor (N=3059) Group 4 21.3% 82.8% 48.4% 14.1% 14.0% 9.7% 21.2% 58.0% 4.5% 0.441 0.121 * 0.345 0.28 0.084 0.159 2.1% ** 9.6% ** 14.9% ** 32.9% 18.8% 7.0% 12.9% 13.5% 20.7% 13.9% 36.1% 12.7% 5.2% 51.8% 14.0% 5.5% 73.0% ** ** ** ** * 83.5% 6.6% 5.3% 75.4% 6.2% 13.7% 92.5% 4.8 ** 2.3 ** 5.8 2.1 7.4% * $138,400 $112,400 $30,400 $9,500 $117,000 $87,200 $29,300 $12,000 26% 3.4% $386,300 $286,100 $175,500 $77,800 $382,400 $262,600 $191,000 $79,100 2% 22% ** 7% * $26,200 6% 9% 5% $56,300 -5% $800 ** 10.0% 16% 11% 32% 37% 16% 77% 23% 71.5 ** 2.17 $4,400 10.3% 7% 5% 57% 24% 13% 52% 48% 66.9 1.96 Table A1. Regression to Impute Vehicle Consumption Using Consumer Expenditure Survey Dependent Variable: Vehicle Consumption Total vehicle expenditures Total vehicle expenditures squared Pretax income Age of reference person Family size Male Education Less than high school High school Some college College (omitted group) Intercept R-Squared *Significant at the 90% level Coefficient 0.052 ** -1.76xE-9 0.005 -43 ** 386 ** -11 Std. Error 0.0086 5.18xE-9 0.0039 14 126 267 249 956 ** 332 416 342 400 2287 1106 0.215 **Significant at the 95% level 35 Table A2. Regression to Impute Housing Consumption Using Consumer Expenditure Survey Dependent Variable: Rental Equivalence Coefficient 0.0037 ** -1.7xE-9 ** Property value Property value squared Census divisions (New England omitted) Mid-Atlantic South Atlantic East North Central West North Central East South Central West South Central Mountain Pacific Urban Urban*Mid-Atlantic Urban*West North Central Urban*Mountain Number of rooms in house Housing type Duplex Apartment Mobile home Other housing Single family home (omitted) Intercept R-Squared *Significant at the 90% level -408 -247 -505 -122 -459 -267 -467 -22 16 300 261 259 28 ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** ** 60 29 47 29 35 32 59 31 31 57 47 58 3 -144 ** 114 ** -31 53 46 39 30 81 542 ** 46 0.397 **Significant at the 95% level 36 Std. Error 0.0001 9.4xE-11