Trade and Labor Market Dynamics Lorenzo Caliendo Yale University, NBER Maximiliano Dvorkin St Louis Fed Fernando Parro Federal Reserve Board March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24 Introduction Aggregate trade shocks can have di¤erent disaggregate e¤ects (across locations, sectors, locations-sectors) depending on I degree of exposure to foreign trade I indirect linkages through internal trade, sectoral trade I labor reallocation process We develop a model of trade and labor market dynamics that explicitly recognizes the role of labor mobility frictions, goods mobility frictions, I-O linkages, geographic factors, and international trade Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24 This paper Models with large # of unknown fundamentals: productivity, mobility frictions, trade frictions, and more... Propose a new method to solve dynamic discrete choice models I Solve the model and perform large scale counterfactuals without estimating level of fundamentals I By expressing the equilibrium conditions of the model in relative time di¤erences Study how China’s import competition impacted U.S. labor markets I I 38 countries, 50 U.S. regions, and 22 sectors version of the model Employment and welfare e¤ects across more than 1000 labor markets F F Employment: approx. 0.8 MM manuf. jobs lost, reallocation to services Welfare: aggregate gains; very heterogeneous e¤ects across labor markets; transition costs re‡ect the importance of dynamics Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 2 / 24 Literature Substantial progress in recent quantitative trade models, including Eaton and Kortum (2002) and its extensions: multiple sectors Caliendo and Parro (2015), spatial economics Caliendo et al. (2015), and other extensions Monte (2015), Tombe et al. (2015), Fajgelbaum et.al. (2015), much more I One limitation is their stylized treatment of the labor market (static models, labor moves costessly or does not move) We build on advances that underscore the importance of trade and labor market dynamics: Artuç and McLaren (2010), Artuç Chaudhuri and McLaren (2010), Dix-Carneiro (2014) Relates to dynamic discrete choice models in IO, labor, macro literature Hotz and Miller (1993), Berry (1994), Kennan and Walker (2011), Dvorkin (2014) Relates to recent research on the labor market e¤ects of trade I Because of direct import exposure: Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2013), and sectoral linkages: Acemoglu, Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2015), other channels Handley and Limao (2015) Pierce and Schott (2015) Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 3 / 24 Road map Model I Households’dynamic problem I Production structure I Equilibrium Solution method Application: calibration and results Conclusion Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 4 / 24 Model Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 5 / 24 Households’problem N locations (index n and i) and each has J sectors (index j and k) The value of a household in market nj at time t given by n h i o nj ik nj ,ik ik vnj = u ( c ) + max βE v τ + ν e , t t t +1 t fi ,k giN=,J1,k =0 s.t. u (ctnj ) I I I log(b n ) i f j = 0, nj n log(wt /Pt ) otherwise, β 2 (0, 1) discount factor τ nj ,ik additive, time invariant migration costs to ik from nj eik t are stochastic i.i.d idiosyncratic taste shocks F F e Type-I Extreme Value distribution with zero mean ν > 0 is the dispersion of taste shocks Unemployed obtain home production b n Employed households supply a unit of labor inelastically I I Receive the competitive market wage w nj t k Consume ctnj = ∏Jk =1 (ctnj ,k )α , where P nt is the local price index Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 6 / 24 Households’problem - Dynamic discrete choice Using properties of Type-I Extreme Value distributions one obtains: The expected (expectation over e) lifetime utility of a worker at nj h i J ik nj ,ik 1/ν Vtnj = u (ctnj ) + ν log ∑N exp βV τ i =1 ∑ k =0 t +1 Fraction of workers that reallocate from market nj to ik ,ik µnj t = exp βVtik+1 τ nj ,ik J mh ∑N m =1 ∑h =0 exp βVt +1 1/ν τ nj ,mh 1/ν . Evolution of the distribution of labor across markets ik ,nj ik N J Lnj Lt t +1 = ∑ i =1 ∑ k =0 µ t Frechet and Multiplicative costs Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 7 / 24 Production - Static sub-problem Notice that at each t, labor supply across markets is fully determined I We can then solve for wages such that labor markets clear, using a very rich static spatial structure (CPRHS 2015) In each nj there is a continuum of intermediate good producers with technology as in Eaton and Kortum (2002) I Perfect competition, CRS technology, idiosyncratic productivity z nj Fréchet(1, θ j ), deterministic sectoral regional TFP Anj h n qtnj (z nj ) = z nj Anj [ltnj ]ξ [htnj ]1 ξn iγnj J ∏ [ Mt nj ,nk γnj ,nk ] k =1 Each n, j produces a …nal good (for …nal consumption and materials) I CES (elasticity η) aggregator of sector j goods from the lowest cost supplier in the world subject to κ nj ,ij 1 “iceberg” bilateral trade cost Intermediate goods Final goods Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 8 / 24 Production - Static sub-problem - Equilibrium conditions Sectoral price index, Ptnj (wt ) = Γnj h ∑ N i =1 Aij [xtij (wt )κ nj ,ij ] θj i 1/θ j Let Xtij (wt ) be total expenditure. Expenditure shares given by j ,ij π nj (wt ) = t [xtij (wt )κ nj ,ij ] θ Aij , mj nj ,mj ] θ j Amj ∑N m =1 [xt (wt )κ where xtij (wt ) is the unit cost of an input bundle Labor Market clearing Lnj t = where γnj (1 γnj (1 ξn ) wtnj ∑i =1 πijt ,nj (wt )Xtij (wt ), N ξ n ) labor share Input bundle Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 9 / 24 Sequential and temporary equilibrium N ,J State of the economy = distribution of labor Lt = fLnj t gn =1,j =0 I Let Θ fAnj g, fκ nj ,ij g, fτ nj ,ik g, H nj , fbn g N ,J ,J ,N n =1,j =0,i =1,k =0 De…nition Given (Lt , Θ) , a temporary equilibrium is a vector of wt (Lt , Θ) that satis…es the equilibrium conditions of the static sub-problem De…nition Given (L0 , Θ) , a sequential competitive equilibrium of the model is a sequence of fLt , µt , Vt , wt (Lt , Θ)gt∞=0 that solves HH dynamic problem and the temporary equilibrium at each t ,ik N ,J ,J ,N With µt = fµnj gn =1,j =0,i =1,k =0 , and Vt = fVtnj gNn =,J1,j =0 t Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24 Solution Method Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 11 / 24 Solving the model Solving for an equilibrium of the model requires information on Θ I I Large # of unknowns N + 2NJ + N 2 J + N 2 J 2 Productivity, endowments of local structures, labor mobility costs, home production, and trade costs As we increase the dimension of the problem— adding countries, regions, or sectors— the number of parameters grows geometrically We solve this problem by computing the equilibrium dynamics of the model in time di¤erences Why is this progress? I As in DEK (2008), Caliendo and Parro (2015), by conditioning on observables one can solve the model without knowing the levels of Θ F I We apply this idea to a dynamic economy Condition on last period migration ‡ows, trade ‡ows, and production F Solve for the value function in time di¤erences Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 12 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Expected lifetime utility N nj J Vtnj = log( wPtn ) + ν log ∑ ∑ exp βVtik+1 t τ nj ,ik 1/ν i =1 k =0 Transition matrix (migration ‡ows) ,ik µnj t = exp βVtik+1 N J ∑ ∑ m =1 h =0 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) τ nj ,ik exp βVtmh +1 Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics 1/ν τ nj ,mh 1/ν March, 2016 13 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Transition matrix (migration ‡ows) at t = µnj1,ik = exp βV0ik N J ∑ ∑ m =1 h =0 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) 1, Data τ nj ,ik exp βV0mh 1/ν τ nj ,mh Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics 1/ν March, 2016 9 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Transition matrix (migration ‡ows) at t = µnj1,ik = 1, Data exp βV0ik N J ∑ ∑ m =1 h =0 τ nj ,ik exp βV0mh 1/ν τ nj ,mh 1/ν Transition matrix (migration ‡ows) at t = 0, Model ,ik µnj 0 = exp βV1ik N J ∑ ∑ m =1 h =0 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) τ nj ,ik exp βV1mh 1/ν τ nj ,mh Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics 1/ν March, 2016 9 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Transition matrix (migration ‡ows) at t = µnj1,ik = 1, Data exp βV0ik N J ∑ ∑ m =1 h =0 τ nj ,ik exp βV0mh 1/ν τ nj ,mh 1/ν Transition matrix (migration ‡ows) at t = 0, Model ,ik µnj 0 = exp βV1ik N J ∑ ∑ m =1 h =0 τ nj ,ik exp βV1mh 1/ν τ nj ,mh 1/ν Take the time di¤erence ,ik µnj 0 µnj1,ik = Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 exp ( βV 1ik τ nj ,ik ) 1/ν exp ( βV 0ik τ nj ,ik ) 1/ν exp ( βV 1mh τ nj ,mh ) ∑N m 0 =1 ∑Jh 0 =0 exp ( 0 0 βV 0m h Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics 1/ν τ nj ,m 0 h 0 1/ν ) March, 2016 9 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Take the time di¤erence ,ik µnj 0 nj ,ik µ 1 = Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 exp ( βV 1ik τ nj ,ik ) 1/ν exp ( 1/ν βV 0ik τ nj ,ik exp ( ∑N m 0 =1 ∑Jh 0 =0 ) βV 1mh exp ( τ nj ,mh ) 0 0 βV 0m h Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics 1/ν τ nj ,m 0 h 0 1/ν ) March, 2016 10 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Take the time di¤erence ,ik µnj 0 nj ,ik µ 1 = J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 exp ( βV 1ik τ nj ,ik ) 1/ν exp ( 1/ν βV 0ik τ nj ,ik exp ( ∑N m 0 =1 ∑Jh 0 =0 ) βV 1mh exp ( τ nj ,mh ) 0 0 βV 0m h 1/ν τ nj ,m 0 h 0 1/ν ) Simplify ,ik µnj 0 µnj1,ik exp V1ik = Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 V0ik β/ν exp ( βV 1mh τ nj ,mh ) ∑N m 0 =1 ∑Jh 0 =0 exp ( 0 0 βV 0m h Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics 1/ν τ nj ,m 0 h 0 1/ν ) March, 2016 10 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Take the time di¤erence ,ik µnj 0 nj ,ik µ 1 = J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 exp ( βV 1ik τ nj ,ik ) 1/ν exp ( 1/ν βV 0ik τ nj ,ik exp ( ∑N m 0 =1 ∑Jh 0 =0 ) τ nj ,mh ) βV 1mh exp ( 1/ν 0 0 βV 0m h τ nj ,m 0 h 0 1/ν ) Simplify ,ik µnj 0 µnj1,ik exp V1ik = J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 V0ik β/ν exp ( βV 1mh τ nj ,mh ) ∑N m 0 =1 ∑Jh 0 =0 exp ( 1/ν 0 0 βV 0m h τ nj ,m 0 h 0 1/ν ) Use µnj1,mh once again ,ik µnj = 0 µnj1,ik exp V1ik N J nj ,mh ∑ ∑ µ 1 exp V1mh m =1 h =0 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) V0ik β/ν V0mh Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics β/ν March, 2016 10 / 24 Equilibrium conditions Expected lifetime utility N nj J Vtnj = log( wPtn ) + ν log ∑ ∑ exp βVtik+1 t τ nj ,ik 1/ν i =1 k =0 Transition matrix ,ik µnj t = exp βVtik+1 N J ∑ ∑ m =1 h =0 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) τ nj ,ik exp βVtmh +1 Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics 1/ν τ nj ,mh 1/ν March, 2016 10 / 24 Equilibrium conditions - Time di¤erences Expected lifetime utility N w nj /w nj Vtnj+1 J ,ik Vtnj = log( Ptn+1 /Ptn ) + ν log ∑ ∑ µnj exp Vtik+2 t t t +1 Vtik+1 i =1 k =0 β/ν Transition matrix ,ik µnj t +1 ,ik µnj t = exp Vtik+2 N Vtik+1 J nj ,mh exp Vtmh ∑ ∑ µt +2 m =1 h =0 where w tnj+1 /w tnj P tn+1 /P tn β/ν Vtmh +1 β/ν is the solution to the temporary equilibrium in time di¤erences Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24 Temporary equilibrium conditions How to solve for the temporary equilibrium in time di¤erences? Price index Ptnj (wt ) =Γ nj h ∑ N i =1 A ij j [xtij (wt )κ nj ,ij ] θ i 1/θ j , Trade shares j ,ij π nj (wt ) = t Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) [xtij (wt )κ nj ,ij ] θ Aij , mj nj ,mj ] θ j Amj ∑N m =1 [xt (wt )κ Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 11 / 24 Temporary equilibrium - Time di¤erences How to solve for the temporary equilibrium in time di¤erences? Price index P̂tnj+1 (w ^ t +1 ) = h ∑ N i =1 j ,ij ij π nj [x̂t +1 (w ^t +1 )] θ t i 1/θ j , Trade shares ,ij π nj ^ t +1 ) t +1 (w = ,ij ij π nj [x̂t +1 (w ^t +1 )] t nj ,mj ∑N m =1 π t θj [x̂tmj ^t +1 )] +1 (w θj , Where P̂tnj+1 = Ptnj+1 /Ptnj , x̂tij+1 = xtij+1 /xtij , w ^t +1 = wt +1 /wt Same “hat trick” applies to all equilibrium conditions Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 11 / 24 Solving the model Proposition Given L0 , µ 1 , π 0 , VA0 , GO0 , (ν, θ, β), solving the equilibrium in time di¤erences does not require the level of Θ, and solves nj ,ik J [Ytik+2 ] β , Ytnj+1 = (ŵtnj+1 /P̂tn+1 )1/ν ∑N i =1 ∑ k =0 µ t ,ik µnj t +1 = ,ik µnj [Ytik+2 ] β t nj ,mh J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 µ t β [Ytmh +2 ] , ik ,nj ik N J Lnj Lt , t +1 = ∑ i =1 ∑ k =0 µ t where ŵtnj+1 /P̂tn+1 solves the temporary equilibrium given L̂t +1 , where Ytik+1 exp(Vtik+1 Vtik )1/ν . Example Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 12 / 24 Solving for counterfactuals Want to study the e¤ects of changes in fundamentals Θ̂ = Θ0 /Θ I Recall that Θ I fAnj g, fκ nj ,ij g, fτ nj ,ik g, H nj , fbn g N ,J ,J ,N n =1,j =0,i =1,k =0 TFP, trade costs, labor migration costs, endowments of local structures, home production We can use our solution method to study the e¤ects of changes in Θ I One by one or jointly I Changes across time and space Proposition Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 13 / 24 Appplication: The Rise of China Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 14 / 24 The rise of China U.S. imports from China almost doubled from 2000 to 2007 I At the same time, manufacturing employment fell while employment in other sectors, such as construction and services, grew Several studies document that an important part of the employment loss in manufactures was a consequence of China’s trade expansion I e.g., Pierce and Schott (2012); Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013), Acemoglu, Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2014) We use our model, and apply our method, to quantify and understand the e¤ects of the rise of China’s trade expansion, “China shock” I I Initial period is the year 2000 We calculate the sectoral, regional, and aggregate employment and welfare e¤ects of the China shock Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 15 / 24 Identifying the China shock Follow Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013) I We estimate ∆MUSA,j = a1 + a2 ∆Mother ,j + uj , where j is a NAICS sector, ∆MUSA,j and ∆Mother ,j are changes in U.S. and other adv. countries, imports from China from 2000 to 2007 Obtain predicted changes in U.S. imports with this speci…cation Use the model to solve for the change in China’s 12 manufacturing 12 industries TFP ÂChina,j j =1 such that model’s imports match predicted imports from China from 2000 to 2007 I We feed in to our model n ÂChina,j to study the e¤ects of the shock o12 j =1 by quarter from 2000 to 2007 Figure: shock and predicted imports Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 16 / 24 Taking the model to the data (quarterly) Model with 50 U.S. states, 22 sectors + unempl. and 38 countries I More than 1000 labor markets Need data for L0 , µ I I I I 1 , π 0 , VA0 , GO0 L0 : PUMS of the U.S. Census for the year 2000 µ 1 : Use CPS to compute intersectoral mobility and ACS to compute Table interstate mobility Details π 0 : CFS and WIOD year 2000 VA0 and GO0 : BEA VA shares and U.S. IO, WIOD for other countries Need values for parameters (ν, θ, β) I I I θ : We use Caliendo and Parro (2015) β = 0.99 Implies approximately a 4% annual interest rate υ = 5.34 (implied elasticity of 0.2) Using ACM’s data and speci…cation, adapted to our model Estimation Need to deal with trade de…cits. Do so similar to CPRHS Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics Imbalances March, 2016 17 / 24 Employment e¤ects Manufacturing - No China Shock Manufacturing - China Shock 16.00 15.50 15.00 Employment share (%) 14.50 0 10 20 30 40 Time (quarters) 50 15 W & Retail - No China Shock W & Retail - China Shock 14.9 14.8 14.7 0 10 20 30 40 Time (quarters) 50 Employment share (%) 16.50 63.00 62.50 62.00 61.50 Services - No China Shock Services - China Shock 61.00 60.50 Employment share (%) Employment share (%) Figure: The Evolution of Employment Shares 0 10 20 30 40 Time (quarters) 50 7.65 Construction - No China Shock Construction - China Shock 7.60 7.55 7.50 7.45 0 10 20 30 40 Time (quarters) 50 Chinese competition reduced the share of manufacturing employment by 0.5% in the long run, 0.8 million employment loss I Proposition About 50% of the change not explained by a secular trend Validation Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 18 / 24 Manufacturing employment e¤ects Sectors most exposed to Chinese import competition contribute more I 1/2 of the decline in manuf. employment originated in the Computer & Electronics and Furniture sectors Sectoral contributions F I 1/4 of the total decline comes from the Metal and Textiles sectors Food, Beverage and Tobacco, gained employment F Less exposed to China, bene…ted from cheaper intermediate goods, other sectors, like Services, demanded more of them (I-O linkages) Unequal regional e¤ects I Spatial distribution Regions with a larger concentration of sectors that are more exposed to China lose more jobs Regional contributions F California, the region with largest share of employment in Computer & Electronics, contributed to about 12% of the decline Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 19 / 24 Welfare e¤ects across labor markets Figure: Welfare changes across labor markets 80 70 60 Density 50 40 30 20 10 0 0.3 0.4 Note: Largest and smallest 5 percentile are excluded 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 Percentage change Very heterogeneous response to the same aggregate shock I I welfare Most labor markets gain as a consequence of cheaper imports from China Unequal regional e¤ects welfare reg Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 20 / 24 Transition cost to the steady state Figure: Transition cost to the steady state across labor markets 80 70 60 Density 50 40 30 20 10 0 -8 -6 -4 Note: Largest and smallest 5 percentile are excluded -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 Percentage change Adjustment costs re‡ect the importance of labor market dynamics I With free labor mobility AC=0 Heterogeneity shaped by trade and migration frictions as well as geographic factors. AC Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 21 / 24 0 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics United Kingdom Turkey Taiwan Sweden Spain Slovenia Slovakia Russia Romania Rest of the World Portugal Poland Netherlands Mexico Lithuania Korea Japan Italy Ireland Indonesia India Hungary Greece Germany France Finland Estonia Denmark Czech Republic Cyprus Canada Bulgaria Brazil Belgium Austria Australia Percentage change Welfare e¤ects across countries Figure: Welfare e¤ects across countries 0.9 1 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 March, 2016 22 / 24 Conclusion Develop a dynamic and spatial model to quantify the disaggregate e¤ects of aggregate shocks Show how to perform counterfactual analysis in a very rich spatial model without having to estimate a large set of unobservables Dynamics and realistic structure matters for capturing very heterogenous e¤ects at the disaggregate level Our model can be applied to answer a broader set of questions: changes in productivity or trade costs in any location in the world, commercial policies, and more... Where we go from here: 1- Migration crisis in Europe. 2- Human capital accumulation Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 23 / 24 This is the END Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 24 / 24 Results with Fréchet and Multiplicative Costs Expected lifetime utility Vtn,j =u ctn,j + ∑ N i =1 ∑ J k =0 ,k βVti+ 1 τ n,j ;i ,k 1/ν ν , Measure of workers that reallocate (Choice equation) ;i ,k µn,j = t ,k n,j ;i ,k βVti+ 1τ ∑N m =1 ∑Jh =0 βVtm,h +1 1/ν τ n,j ;m,h 1/ν . Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 25 / 24 State B State A Information in CPS and ACS Ind 1 Ind 2 ... Ind J Total Ind 1 Ind 2 ... Ind J Total Ind 1 x x ... x y y State A Ind 2 . . . x ... x ... ... ... x y ... y ... Ind J x x ... x y y Ind 1 y x x ... x y State B Ind 2 . . . y x x ... x y Ind J ... ... ... ... ... y x x ... x y Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 26 / 24 Model - Intermediate goods Representative …rms in each region n and sector j produce a continuum of intermediate goods with idiosyncratic productivities z nj I I Drawn independently across goods, sectors, and regions from a Fréchet distribution with shape parameter θ j Productivity of all …rms is also determined by a deterministic productivity level Anj The production function of a variety with z nj and Anj is given by h n qtnj (z nj ) = z nj Anj [ltnj ]ξ [htnj ]1 with ∑Jk =1 γnj ,nk = 1 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ξn iγnj J ∏ [Mtnj ,nk ]γ nj ,nk , k =1 γnj Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 27 / 24 Model - Intermediate good prices The cost of the input bundle needed to produce varieties in (nj ) is xtnj =B nj rtnj ξn wtnj nj 1 ξn γ J ∏ [Ptnk ]γ nj ,nk k =1 The unit cost of a good of a variety with draw z nj in (nj ) is xtnj nj [A ] z nj γnj and so its price under competition is given by ( ) κ nj ,ij xtij nj j pt (z ) = min , ij i z ij [Aij ]γ with κ nj ,ij Back 1 are “iceberg” bilateral trade cost Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 28 / 24 Model - Final goods The production of …nal goods is given by Qtnj = Z RN ++ nj [q̃tnj (z j )]1 1/η φj (z j )dz j η nj /(η nj 1 ) , where z j = (z 1j , z 2j , ...z Nj ) denotes the vector of productivity draws for a given variety received by the di¤erent n The resulting price index in sector j and region n, given our distributional assumptions, is given by Ptnj = $ where $ is a constant h ∑ j j ij N [x ij κ nj ,ij ] θ [Aij ]θ γ i =1 t i 1/θ j , Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 29 / 24 Data - Quarterly gross ‡ows Current Population Survey (CPS) monthly frequency I I I Information on intersectoral mobility Source of o¢ cial labor market statistics We match individuals surveyed three months apart and compute their employment (industry) or unemployment status F Our 3-month match rate is close to 90% American Community Survey (ACS) to compute interstate mobility I I I I Table Representative sample (0.5 percent) of the U.S. population for 2000 Mandatory and is a complement to the decennial Census Information on current state and industry (or unemployment) and state they lived during previous year Limitation: no information on workers past employment status or industry Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 30 / 24 Data - Quarterly gross ‡ows Table: U.S. interstate and intersectoral labor mobility Probability Changing j in same n Changing n but not j Changing j and n Staying in same j and n p25 3.74% 0.04% 0.03% 91.1% p50 5.77% 0.42% 0.04% 93.6% p75 8.19% 0.73% 0.06% 95.2% Note: Quarterly transitions. Data sources: ACS and CPS Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 31 / 24 Identifying the China shock Predicted change in U.S. imports from China Estimated change in measured TFP (quarterly, percent) 0.0 Furniture Mtg 1 Transport Mtg 1.0 Computer, Elect 10 Machinery 2.0 Metal 100 NonMetallic 3.0 Plastics, Rubber 1000 Chemicals 4.0 Petroleum, Coal 10000 Wood, Paper 5.0 Textiles 100000 Food, Bev, Tob Prediceted change in U.S. imports (millions, log sclae) Figure: Predicted change in imports vs. model-based Chinese TFP change Change in measured TFP in China Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 32 / 24 Identifying the China shock 1.2 10000 1.15 1000 1.1 100 1.05 1 10 Estimated China change in TFP (Quarterly) 100000 0.95 Predicted change in U.S. imports from China Furniture Mfg Transport Mfg Computer, Elect Machinery Metal Nonmetallic Plastics, Rubber Chemicals Petroleum, Coal Wood, Paper Textiles 1 Food, Bev, Tob Predicted change in U.S. imports (millions, log scale) Figure: Predicted change in imports vs. model-based Chinese TFP change Change in TFP in China Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 33 / 24 Manufacturing Employment E¤ects Figure: Sectoral contribution to the change in manuf. employment 30 Percentage change 25 20 15 10 5 0 Furniture Mfg. Transport Mfg. Computer, Elect. Machinery Metal Nonmetallic Plastics, Rubber Chemicals Petroleum, Coal Wood, Paper Textiles Food, Bev., Tob. -5 Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 34 / 24 Sectoral concentration across regions Computers an Electronics (shares) Wood and Paper (shares) NI NI 229 261 AL OR NE EN 2222 2213 222 EI SE 122 2222 TT OI 2227 IL 222 AO 2273 2224 122 2294 LZ NE 323 OK LR 2224 2211 SE NV 2617 AL 666 122 NA LZ 427 NE 267 AL SA LK 2222 2252 2222 2622 2666 VL KY 2666 261 AV 261 OK LR 2691 161 EE EE 2 2667 TN 166 NA 6 2619 LL AL SA 666 669 6 TX 1121 661 II 22223 169 662 169 IN EO 261 LL TX IL 161 261 NJ AL OI 166 KS 2667 AT 266 IL AO 2662 2611 NY 2611 2621 TT AV 161 RI 262 2622 AY EL 169 2626 761 NE EE EI AI 2224 124 2221 162 2627 122 TN LK EN 2616 2666 EE 2214 2232 EE NE 2611 IE 222 VL KY EO 122 124 IN 121 KS 222 1 VT ET NJ AL IL NE 2212 OR 2212 2224 2221 NV RI AT 322 2217 AY 2222 NY 2 1 227 2225 225 AI IE EL 2212 VT ET 1122 AL AL EE 123 LL ES LL II 2219 322 2626 2211 LL ES LL 161 266 266 Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 35 / 24 0 Alabama Alaska Arizona Arkansas California Colorado Connecticut Delaware Florida Georgia Hawaii Idaho Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Louisiana Maine Maryland Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota Mississippi Missouri Montana Nebraska Nevada New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York North Carolina North Dakota Ohio Oklahoma Oregon Pennsylvania Rhode Island South Carolina South Dakota Tennessee Texas Utah Vermont Virginia Washington West Virginia Wisconsin Wyoming Percentage change Manufacturing employment e¤ects Figure: Regional contribution to the change in manuf. employment 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 36 / 24 Regional welfare e¤ects NI 6665 AL EE 6665 OR NE EN 6695 6642 6662 EI 6665 SE 6625 6654 6646 6649 TT OI 665 IL 6669 AO 6692 6652 6655 NJ 666 6646 2662 6662 666 AV 666 666 6645 TN LZ NE 6655 OK LR 6699 6669 6665 NA 6666 6652 LK 6699 EE EE VL KY EO AL 6664 IN 666 KS 6646 AT 6659 IL NE NV 6644 NY 6699 2662 AL RI 6625 AY 6666 6664 666 AI IE EL 6652 VT ET LL AL SA 6666 664 6695 TX 6652 II 6669 LL ES LL 6665 6665 6659 Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 37 / 24 Sectoral and regional welfare e¤ects Sectoral e¤ects very di¤erent in the long run than in the short run I Services and Construction gain the most F I Sectoral e¤ects Reasons: no direct exposure, bene…t from cheaper intermediate inputs, increased in‡ow of workers from manufacturing Welfare gains are more uniform in the long run F Workers reallocate from depressed industries U.S. regions fare better in the short and the long run I Regions bene…t directly from cheaper intermediate goods from China F I Regional e¤ects and indirectly from the e¤ect of imports on the cost of inputs purchased from other U.S. regions The regional welfare distribution is more uniform in the long run F workers reallocate from regions with lower real income Worst o¤ individual labor markets I F Wood and Paper in Nevada, Transport and Equip. in Louisiana, and Wholesale and Retail in Alaska Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 38 / 24 Solving the model Proposition Given L0 , µ 1 , π 0 , VA0 , GO0 , (ν, θ, β), and Θ̂ = fΘ̂t gt∞=1 , solving the equilibrium in time di¤erences does not require Θ, and solves nj ,ik J [Ytik+2 ] β , Ytnj+1 = (w̃tnj+1 /P̃tn+1 )1/ν ∑N i =1 ∑ k =0 µ t ,ik µnj t +1 = ,ik µnj [Ytik+2 ] β t nj ,mh J ∑N m =1 ∑ h =0 µ t β [Ytmh +2 ] , ik ,nj ik N J Lnj Lt , t +1 = ∑ i =1 ∑ k =0 µ t where w̃tnj+1 /P̃tn+1 solves the temporary equilibrium at L̃t +1 given Θ̂t +1 , and Ytik+1 exp(Vtik+1 Vtik )1/ν Back Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 39 / 24 How to perform counterfactuals? Solve the model conditioning on observed data at an initial period I Value added, Trade shares, Gross production, all consistent with observed labor allocation across labor market at t = 0 I Use the labor mobility matrix µ 1 . For this, we we need to specify agents expectations at t = 1 about future policies Assumption: Policy changes are unanticipated at t = I I I 1 Allows us to condition on observed data and solve for the sequential equilibrium with no policy changes Let fVt gt∞=0 be the equilibrium sequence of values with constant ,J policies, where Vt = fVti ,k gN i =1,k =1 . The assumption implies that the initial observed labor mobility matrix µ 1 is the outcome of forward looking behavior under fVt gt∞=0 . Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 40 / 24 Solving the model (example) Figure: Equilibrium Value Functions in Time Di¤erences 1.6 1.4 Ynj t 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 Time (quarters) Proposition Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 41 / 24 Taking the model to the data (quarterly) υ = 5.34 (implied elasticity of 0.2) Using ACM’s data and speci…cation, adapted to our model I I Data: migration ‡ows and real wages for 26 years between 1975-2000, using March CPS We deal with two issues: functional forms, and timing Estimating equation ,ik ,nj log µnj /µnj =C+ t t I I I β ,ik nj ,nj log wtik+1 /wtnj+1 + β log µnj t +1 /µt +1 + v t +1 , υ We transform migration ‡ows from …ve-month to quarterly frequency GMM estimation, past ‡ows and wages used as instruments ACM estimate υ = 1.88 (annual), υ = 2.89 (…ve-month frequency) Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 42 / 24 Model validation Compare reduced-form evidence with model’s predictions I I First run second-stage regression in ADH with our level of aggregation Then, run same regression with model generated data Table: Reduced-form regression results ∆Lm it ∆IPWuit Obs R2 ∆ūit data (1) model (2) data (3) model (4) -1.718 (0.194) -1.124 (0.368) 0.461 (0.138) 0.873 (0.252) 49 0.51 50 0.16 49 0.13 50 0.20 Results are largely aligned with those in ADH Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 43 / 24 Adjustment costs We follow Dix-Carneiro (2014)’s measure of adjustment cost The steady-state change in the value function due changes in nj nj fundamentals is given by VSS (Θ̂) VSS Therefore, the transition cost for market nj to the new long-run equilibrium, AC nj (Θ̂), is given by 0 AC nj (Θ̂) = log @ nj VSS (Θ̂) 1 1 β ∑t∞=0 β t Vtnj+1 (Θ̂) nj VSS Vtnj+1 1 A, Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 44 / 24 Imbalances Assume that in each region there is a mass of one of Rentiers I I I Owners of local structures, obtain rents ∑Jk =1 rtik H ik Send all their local rents to a global portfolio n Receive a constant share ιi from the global portfolio, with ∑N n =1 ι = 1 Imbalances in region i given by J ∑ rtik H ik ιi χt , k =1 J ik ik where χt = ∑N i =1 ∑k =1 rt H are the total revenues in the global portfolio Rentier uses her income to purchase local goods I Same preferences as workers Back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 45 / 24 Welfare e¤ects from changes in fundamentals Let Wtnj (Θ̂) be the welfare e¤ect of change in Θ̂ = Θ0 /Θ ∞ nj Wtnj (Θ̂) = ∑ βs log (µ̂njĉs,nj )ν , s =t I I s Note that this is a consumption equivalent measure of welfare ,nj )ν is the change in the option value of migration (µ̂nj s In our model, ĉtnj = ŵtnj /P̂tn is shaped by several mechanisms, ĉtnj = I I ŵ tnj k J ∏k =1 (ŵ tnk )α ∏Jk =1 ŵ tnk P̂ tnk αk , First component re‡ects the unequal e¤ects within a region Second component is common to all HH residing in region n, given by ! J L̂nk nk ,nk t n k γnk /θ k ξ log nk . ∑ α log(π̂t ) Ĥ k =1 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 46 / 24 Welfare e¤ects from changes in fundamentals Let Wtnj (Θ̂) be the welfare e¤ect of change in Θ̂ = Θ0 /Θ ∞ nj Wtnj (Θ̂) = ∑ βs log (µ̂njĉs,nj )ν , s =t I I s Note that this is a consumption equivalent measure of welfare ,nj )ν is the change in the option value of migration (µ̂nj s In a one sector model with no materials and structures, ĉtn = ŵtn /P̂tn Wtn (Θ̂) = ∞ ∑ s =t βs log 1/θ (π̂ n,n s ) , ν (µ̂n,n s ) Similar to a ACM (2010) + ACR (2012) back Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor () Markets Dynamics March, 2016 47 / 24