Lecture 3: Early Agriculture ECON 451 Fall 2012 Professor David Jacks For hundreds—if not thousands—of years, agriculture remained the predominant occupation in the European economy. Thus, anything which encouraged or impeded agricultural productivity was to have huge implications for the performance of the “macroeconomy”. Introduction Apart from the sheer monotony of everyday life, there a few other aspects which are puzzling from a modern day perspective. The main issue we will be exploring is what explains the development, persistence, and eventual demise of: 1.) the open-fields system 2.) and serfdom (or the manorial system) Introduction A little background, starting with the Romans. Establishing a time-line Economically, the Roman Empire reached its peak from the late 1st Century to the early 3rd Century (roughly 90-215 AD). One of the most important aspects of the Roman economy was the degree of geographical specialization it was able to achieve. A common market centered on the The Roman Economy A fully developed inter-regional division of labor, much more extensive than any thing seen before and not to be rivaled until 1650 AD. Italy: wines, craftwares, and services Egypt: grain, jewelry, and perfumes Syria: glassware and textile France/Spain: olive oil, pottery, and wines North Africa, Sicily, and Russia: grain England: slaves and wool The Roman Economy Much of this achievement was explainable by the Roman insistence on: 1.) well-defined (physical) property rights, 2.) the enforceability of contracts, 3.) freedom of enterprise, and 4.) few constraints on commercial activity. The Roman Economy The Roman economy was also notable for its consistent, light and stable tariff system with ad valorem rates ranging from 2.5% to 25%. Additional roles for: 1.) the Pax Romana, 2.) the development of transport infrastructure, 3.) and the suppression of piracy in the Mediterranean and Black Seas. The Roman Economy But an important distinction must be made between the spread and role of commerce and its place in society. The Romans were originally small-scale farmers, but as they turned to more martial and administrative tasks, they tended to celebrate their agricultural roots. Commerce was suspect and left in the hands of The Roman Economy This gave rise to an agricultural system based on small landholdings owned by citizens and on immense plantations (latifundia) owned by the upper classes and worked by slaves. Surpluses generated in agriculture, however, were only mobilized (and taxed) by the commercial system. A failure on its part, and the The Roman Economy A familiar story: the fall of Rome, barbarian hordes, and the Dark Ages (500-1000 AD). Collapse only in the western part of the Empire—roughly from England in the north, Italy in the south, Hungary in the east, and Spain in the west. The disruption caused by the invasions led to an Collapse Collapse Rather than produce surpluses for the market, output became centered around large estates. In many cases, these coincided with the old latifundia. Lords offered protection from outsiders, but former slaves, small landowners, and artisans had to bond themselves to the lords, i.e. they Collapse Organization of agricultural labor became centered not only around the manor but also the open-fields system. Origins of open-fields unknown, but the pattern is very widespread. Persists into the present day around the world. A common phenomena = a common solution? The open-fields system Most important aspects: 1.) long strips of land with no physical barriers between plots, 2.) communal decisions on output mix, and 3.) communal access to The open-fields system The open-fields system The open-fields system The open-fields system One interpretation has is that the open-fields system was developed and adopted as a form of risk-sharing (or insurance) for peasants. Rationale: 1.) open fields persisted for a long time; 2.) peasants were rational; 3.) so, the benefits of open fields must have outweighed the costs. A very standard line of thought in economics… The open-fields system Costs: lower agricultural productivity and output. Benefits: lower variance of agricultural output. Why? Open fields allowed peasants to spread their exposure to micro-climatic and other shocks. Given how close they were to the threshold of starvation, The open-fields system Output necessary for survival Average harvest (open fields) Average harvest (consolidated fields) The open-fields system After the Magyar/Norse invasions of the 9th century, things settle down and commerce was on the upswing by around 1000 AD. But the fall of Rome had produced extreme political fragmentation, meaning more barriers to trade. Production was still geared around selfsufficiency and Europe at the dawn of the second millenium Europe at the dawn of the second millenium This is where we pick up the story… The outcome of the manorialism and open-fields system in Western Europe was extremely low agricultural productivity. Seed-yield ratios were probably 3 on average with a maximum range of 2 to 6. Europe at the dawn of the second millenium But alternatives existed... 1.) Free labor: more expensive to hire, but more productive. 2.) Enclosed lands: limiting access to lands and avoiding the tragedy of the commons. All of which took centuries to take hold. The feasible set