C Cambridge University Press European Review of Economic History , –. Printed in the United Kingdom Path dependence, time lags and the birth of globalisation: A critique of O’Rourke and Williamson D E N N I S O. F LY N N A N D A RT U R O G I R Á L D E Z ∗ Economics Department, University of the Pacific, Pacific Avenue, Stockton, California , USA In a recent issue of the European Review of Economic History (vol. , , pp. –), Kevin O’Rourke and Jeffrey Williamson dismiss claims by ‘World historians . . . [who] argue that globalisation is a phenomenon which stretches back several centuries, or even several millennia’ (p. ). Rather, O’Rourke and Williamson insist that ‘[g]lobalisation did not begin , years ago, or even years ago. It began in the early nineteenth century. In that sense, it is a very modern phenomenon’ (p. ). O’Rourke and Williamson offer an explicit model of world trade that predicts specific outcomes; and they marshal empirical evidence to support their contention that there was no global economy until the early decades of the nineteenth century. If we are correct in our assertion that sustained globalisation only began in the early nineteenth century, then the autarkic model should fit the pre-nineteenth century facts, while the open economy model should fit the post-eighteenth century facts . . . Can we show with econometrics that while the closed economy model is the relevant one before the s, the open economy model is the relevant one thereafter? . . . If the world historian is looking for a globalisation big bang, she will find it in the s, not in the s (pp. –, ). O’Rourke and Williamson define the key term ‘globalisation [as] . . . the integration of international commodity markets’ (p. ); and they conclude that ‘the only irrefutable evidence that globalisation is taking place is a decline in the international dispersion of commodity prices or what might be called commodity price convergence’ (p. ; italics in original). We see no evidence documenting significant pre-nineteenth century global price convergence for the (competing) commodities that really mattered to the economic lives of the vast majority. Nor do we see any evidence of significant commodity price convergence even for those (non-competing) commodities that mattered little to the vast majority. The implications for world history are, we think, revisionist and profound (p. ). ∗ Anonymous referees offered useful suggestions on earlier versions of this essay, as did Leandro Prados de la Escosura and his colleagues at the Universidad de Carlos III de Madrid. Special thanks to George Souza, who suggested literatures and connections that had eluded us earlier. Helpful comments by James Flynn, Robert Marks, Sucheta Mazumdar, and John Wills must be acknowledged. The authors alone are responsible for remaining errors. European Review of Economic History We are unconvinced by the authors’ argument and propose to discuss our disagreement in five sections. Generally speaking, evolutionary thinking based upon Path Dependence tells us that seemingly unimportant events can sometimes cause transformations of epic proportions. We maintain that econometric analyses, such as that proposed by O’Rourke and Williamson, are unable to account for the global transformations described in this essay. A more complete discussion of Path Dependence appears in the concluding section of this essay. The nature and sources of the economic forces that led to globalisation will be discussed in Section . Section outlines the role of silver and argues against the O’Rourke and Williamson claim that monetary flows can be excluded from discussion of globalisation. The role of luxury goods in longdistance trade – as opposed to everyday items – is analysed in Section . Section integrates broad ecological and demographic components with the history of trade. Concluding remarks comprise Section . . Conceptualising globalisation’s dynamic origins .. Competing definitions and globalisation’s birth date The discovery of America, and that of the passage to the East Indies by the Cape of Good Hope, are the two greatest and most important events recorded in the history of mankind . . . Two new worlds have been opened to their [European] industry, each of them much greater and more extensive than the old one, and the market for one of them growing still greater and greater every day (Smith [], pp. –). Adam Smith insisted that contemporary economic conditions of his time (the late eighteenth century) must be viewed within the context of unique events that had emerged since the age of new European discoveries. The Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (Eatwell et al. ) contains no definition for ‘globalisation’ at all, and other sources offer cultural and political definitions that cannot be made operational in terms of dating the origin of globalisation (Flynn and Giráldez a, p. ). ‘Globalisation’ is a ubiquitous and ‘imprecise term, its sources, direction, antiquity, and inevitability all subject to dispute’ (Grew , p. ). We propose that globalisation began when the Old World became directly connected with the Americas in via Manila. The Pacific Ocean comprises one-third of the surface area of the earth. The American landmasses and the Atlantic Ocean together account for approximately another one-third of the globe, and the Afro-Eurasian complex – ‘the Old World’ – comprises the remaining one-third of the surface area of the earth. It is inappropriate to label connections limited to sub-regions of the Old World See Resnick and Wolff (, p. ) for criticism of econometric approaches to sweeping economic change. The birth of globalisation: a critique as ‘global’. Global trade emerged when all heavily populated continents began to exchange products continuously – both with each other directly and indirectly via other continents – and on a scale that generated deep and lasting impacts on all trading partners. Intercontinental trade existed prior to the sixteenth century, but there was no direct trade link between America and Asia before the founding of Manila as a Spanish entrepôt in . After more than , years of isolation, continuous contacts between the Old World and the New World altered the trajectory of human evolution in profound ways. For example, Old World diseases decimated the indigenous population of the Americas because New World inhabitants lacked immunity to Afro-Eurasian germs, which helps to explain why importation of African slaves became a necessity for exploitation of the vast resources of the New World. Europeans also introduced large domestic animals (such as horses and cattle) and numerous plants (such as wheat, sugarcane, and oranges) previously unknown in the Americas, permanently altering New World landscapes in the process. It is difficult to imagine the economies of Argentina, Brazil, Mexico and the United States in the absence of horses, cattle, sugar, coffee, and wheat, yet these building blocks of agrarian production were entirely absent prior to contact with Europeans. Environments throughout the Americas were redirected along entirely different trajectories as a result of new linkages with the Old World. Many powerful forces which led to globalisation were established soon after the Europeans arrived in the Americas. But the New World was not merely an importer of plants, animals and people. On the contrary, the export of American plants and seeds altered Old World landscapes fundamentally and permanently. Something ‘like one third of the plant food raised to feed man and his animals in the world today comes from plants of American Note that the birth of ‘global trade’ coincided with the birth of ‘globalisation’ generally. For more extensive treatment of the interrelationships among economic, ecological, demographic, and other non-economic factors, see Flynn and Giráldez (b). There is debate about the extent of indigenous depopulation in the Americas. For example, Borah (, p. ) placed aboriginal shrinkage at – per cent, and asserts that it has taken around four centuries for the tropical American population to recover to its pre-European stock. Another author offers the more conservative estimate of a per cent loss of American population (in some regions) within a century of the European intrusion (Nabhan , p. ). Nor should we gloss over the loss of biodiversity as a result of new contacts: ‘Seed conservationist John Carr hazarded the first guess more than a decade ago, estimating that per cent of the crop varieties grown in the Americas prior to Columbus are now extinct. In the US Southwest, my own comparisons of native crop varieties cultivated by prehistoric farmers with those now grown by their descendants suggest that to per cent of the region’s diversity has been extirpated . . . Columbus, Cortes, and the conquistadors ushered in the first major decline in New World agricultural diversity.’ (Nabhan , pp. , ). European Review of Economic History origin’ (Crosby , pp. –), including corn, potatoes, sweet potatoes, the peanut, many beans, and scores of other plants, including tobacco. . The global market for silver After they explored the west coast of Africa, Europeans crossed the Atlantic to the Americas (), sailed around the Cape of Good Hope (), and crossed the Pacific (), all within thirty years. These events have been depicted by historians as products of European causation, and that representation has been applied to the history of a global market for precious metals as well. Specifically, sixteenth-, seventeenth-, and eighteenth-century monetary relations between Europe and Asia have been couched in terms of European dynamism vis-à-vis the rest of the world. Traditional interpretations can be summarised as follows. There was strong European demand for certain indigenous Asian products, including spices, ceramics, silks, cottons, and tea. Asian imports of European wares were paltry by comparison, partly because the propensity of Asian consumers to purchase European goods was low. Europeans responded to their persistent balanceof-payments deficit by exporting precious metals to Asia as ‘balancing items’. We question the assertion that monetary metals flowed from Europe to Asia as a passive item used for balancing trade between the continents. For if that had been the case, then various monies would have been expected to flow from Europe to Asia. Several monetary substances served as monies at that time, including silver, gold, copper, and cowry shells. Thus, Asian merchants should have been indifferent about the particular mix of monies sent as payments by European purchasers. Gold monies should have been as welcome as silver monies. What actually happened is that American silver flowed through (not ‘from’) Europe and mainly to China (not to ‘Asia’ as a whole), while substantial volumes of gold flowed in the opposite direction simultaneously – from China to Europe – between the s and s. Scholars have documented the history of these global linkages, making clear that ecological and demographic consequences reverberated in multiple directions across the planet once the Americas were brought into the mix. See the path-breaking books of Alfred Crosby (, ), as well as his website [www.nhc.rtp. nc.us:/tserve/ nattrans/ntecoindian/essays/columbian.htm] for updated information on these topics. See Flynn (). In terms of gold flows, Supple (, pp. –) devotes an entire chapter to discussion of whether England’s silver exports (–) were equal in value to its imports of gold, focusing on the question of whether England’s money supply may thereby have been stable. In a detailed study of the English East India Company, K. N. Chaudhuri (, p. ) concludes: ‘The East India Company was aware of the true reason for the export of English silver coins and the Deputy Governor’s reference to the import of gold for East India commodities sold in Europe is another example which bears out Dr. Supple’s conclusion that the outflow of silver was matched by an inflow of gold’. Another example of gold flowing in the opposite direction of silver, for instance, involves Asian gold flowing via the Acapulco-Manila galleons to America: ‘Cavendish found the The birth of globalisation: a critique Furthermore, this exchange of silver for gold was not a uniquely Europe– China transaction. Japan produced perhaps half as much silver as did all of Spanish America during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Virtually all Japanese output was exported to the Chinese marketplace, and Japan (like Europe) simultaneously imported gold from China. Moreover, throughout the seventeenth century the Acapulco-Manila galleons carried tons of American silver to China annually via the Pacific Ocean, while gold flowed out of China and back to the Americas simultaneously. These historical facts contradict the dominant trade-deficit hypothesis found in the historical literature today. Europeans operated as intermediaries in the trans-shipment of American (and Japanese) silver to China. Historical evidence also contradicts trade-imbalance reasoning when we look at the other two main monetary substances in the world during this time period, copper and cowry shells. Sweden was the most important source of copper within Europe, but Japan produced perhaps twice as much copper as Sweden by the late-seventeenth century. Again, China presented the largest end-market for Japanese copper, but substantial shipments of Japanese copper also found their way to Europe. That is, Japanese copper flowed from Asian mines during a time when American silver continued to flow through Europe to Chinese markets. Copper and silver monies never flowed systematically together. The world’s leading producer of cowries was the Maldive Islands in the Indian Ocean. Maldivian cowries were exported to Asian markets, but European merchants also imported up to a million pounds weight in cowry shells (as ballast) for the purpose of re-exporting them to end-markets in West Africa at huge profit. Our central conclusion with respect to the world’s four leading monies is that monetary substances never flowed in tandem anywhere in the world during these centuries. Modern economic theory, which teaches us all to aggregate together various monetary substances (including silver coins, gold coins, copper coins, and cowry shells), has inadvertently precluded understanding of global monetary events during our time period. On the contrary, historical evidence forces us to conceptually disaggregate individual monies; each monetary substance must be treated separately, including silver. Doing so at a global level reveals immediately that it is a mistake to couch things in ‘EastWest’ terms. There was no imbalance of trade – East-West, North-South, Europe-Asia, or otherwise – for which monetary resources had to flow in compensation. There was just trade. Monetary substances were commodities value of , livres of it [gold] upon the galleon that was sailing toward Mexico’ (Raynal [], p. ). See Chuan () and Flynn and Giráldez (). See Flynn and Giráldez () for discussion of the most important monetary substances – silver, gold, copper, and cowries – in a global context. See Doherty and Flynn () for a microeconomic theory of money that permits this level of disaggregation. European Review of Economic History traded for the same reasons that explain trade in non-monetary items. The single market most responsible for the birth of globalisation was the silver trade. The most dynamic end-markets for silver in the world resided in China. Many contemporary Europeans were aware of this fact, including Pedro de Baeza (), a Portuguese merchant with years of business experience in Asia: Commonly a peso of gold is worth five and a half silver pesos, and if there is a shortage of silver [in China], it is brought from the other parts and the price rises to six or six and a half silver pesos for one peso of gold; and the most expensive that I have seen and bought gold in the city of Canton was seven pesos of silver for one of gold, and I never saw it go beyond this price, and here in Spain a peso of gold is commonly worth twelve of silver; therefore it is easy to see that bringing gold from China means a gain of more than seventy-five or eighty per cent (Quoted in Boxer , p. ). During the eighteenth century, Adam Smith ( [], p. ) recognised both the importance of silver in stimulating world trade, as well as the central role of China: The silver of the new continent seems in this manner to be one of the principal commodities by which the commerce between the two extremities of the old one [Europe and China] is carried on, and it is by means of it, in great measure, that those distant parts of the world are connected to one another. Nor have these facts been forgotten by eminent historians of the twentieth century. According to Herman Van der Wee (, p. ): In the Far East, silver was valued much more highly than gold in comparison with western Europe, so the western merchant had everything to gain from paying for his purchases in the east in silver. K. N. Chaudhuri echoed similar sentiments in his classic The Trading World K. N. Chaudhuri has long recognised the need to conceptually separate intercontinental movements of gold from intercontinental movements of silver. Chaudhuri urged return to the reasoning of Classical economists like David Ricardo. See, for example, Chaudhuri (, pp. –). Ricardo argued essentially that each precious metal must be analysed independently, focusing on the cost of producing each metal and the price of each one separately. When one of the metals – say, silver – experienced a drastic drop in production costs, its price would gradually fall in the region surrounding production. The resulting low price of silver (in the West and Japan, during our period) relative to its price elsewhere (China) would lead to opportunities for profit from arbitrage; this was a driving force behind intercontinental trade. This type of Ricardian logic has guided Chaudhuri (, ) and Flynn (), both of whom view disequilibrium in the silver market as a primary cause – rather than effect – of East-West trade in the early-modern period. China’s paper-money system fell apart in the mid-fifteenth century, whereupon private-sector forces led to a protracted ‘silverisation’ of the Chinese monetary system. The ‘single-whip’ tax reform of the s consolidated many taxes throughout the empire into silver payments, so China’s fiscal system also ‘silverised’. These are the forces that raised Chinese silver prices vis-à-vis the rest of the world. The definitive work on Chinese monetary history from to is von Glahn (). Flynn and Giráldez () attempt to locate China’s silverisation within a global context. The birth of globalisation: a critique of Asia: With the deepening experience of Asian trade, both the Dutch and English learnt that the American silver was indispensable for its full development, and in contemporaneous economic literature Spain appeared as the universal fountain-head through which the precious metals of the New World were distributed throughout Asia (Chaudhuri , p. ). It is important to draw attention to O’Rourke and Williamson’s (b, p. ) explicit avoidance of discussion of monetary aspects of intercontinental trade: The focus is on commodities other than silver and gold, since these precious metals played a monetary role as well as a more standard commodity role, and different factors thus explain their large and growing importance in international trade during the period. We are interested solely in the growth of non-monetary commodity trade, and the large literature on the impact of intercontinental silver flows on aggregate price levels, while fascinating and important, is not relevant here. But the outline we provided immediately above is inconsistent with their claims. One simply cannot understand the growth of non-monetary commodity trade without recognising that non-monetary trade was directly connected to monetary-commodity exchange at a global level. One reason why the global silver market cannot be left out of the debate is the fact that silver prices did in fact converge worldwide, not once but twice prior to the nineteenth century – by , then again around . (Recall that O’Rourke and Williamson argue that there was no price convergence prior to the s; thus, their conclusion that globalisation must not have existed previously.) That is, price convergence was a central characteristic of the most significant commodity traded at a global level – silver. In the early sixteenth century, for example, the gold/silver ratio hovered around : in Europe, : in Persia, and : in India (Von Glahn , p. ). Later in the s, the gold/silver ratio was :. or : in Canton, while in Spain at that time the exchange ratio was :. or :, ‘thus indicating that the value of silver was twice as high in China as in Spain’ (Chuan , p. ). Bimetallic ratios were about : in Japan and : in Moghul India at that time (Boxer , p. ). The point is that silver was valued more highly the closer one approached end-market China. We refer to this as an ‘arbitrage phase’ in the global silver market, since merchants simply purchased silver where it was cheap (for example, near production centres in Japan and Spanish America) and trans-shipped it to where silver was dear (especially in China). Spectacular profits existed throughout the worldwide supply chain, in other words, which resulted in the unprecedented shipment of thousands of tons of silver to the Chinese marketplace. Even the massive Chinese marketplace could be glutted after a century of relentless imports of silver, however, and by bimetallic ratios around the world had converged. For example, see Yamamura and Kamiki (, p. ). Atwell (, p. ) also indicates that bimetallic ratios in China, Japan, and Spain converged by . European Review of Economic History Silver continued to flow to China during much of the remainder of the seventeenth century, but this trade yielded only normal profits during what we call a ‘non-arbitrage’ phase in the global silver market (Flynn ). As will be shown in Section , global exchanges contributed to dramatic Chinese population growth by the beginning of the eighteenth century, which in turn caused another upswing in Chinese demand for silver. Silver in China once again became more valuable than elsewhere, eliciting a second ‘arbitrage phase’ in the global marketplace. According to Richard von Glahn: ‘In the first half of the eighteenth century the gold:silver ratio in China remained fairly constant at :–, in contrast to a ratio of : in Europe, but from onward the gold:silver ratio in China leapt above :, while in Europe it declined to :.–.’ (Von Glahn , p. ). Von Glahn’s figures are consistent with those reported in the classic work of Dermigny (, vol. I, p. ). Contemporary observers were well aware of these bimetallic trends. In Representation to the Lords of the Treasury in , Sir Isaac Newton stated that ‘in China . . . the (silver:gold) ratio is or to and in India to , and this carries away the silver from all Europe’; Magens’ notations to Newton’s passage states that ‘such quantities of silver went to China to fetch back gold that the price of gold in China rose and it became no longer profitable to send silver there’. Indeed, between and bimetallic ratios indicate that silver eventually came to be valued lower in China than in Europe (Carriere , p. ). In sum, a follow-up eighteenth-century arbitrage phase in the silver market lasted from around until . Or to rephrase: global silver prices had converged a second time by . Leaving aside Japanese production of silver (which some scholars claim totalled half as much as Spanish American silver production in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries), American mines produced more than four billion pesos worth of silver (over thousand tons of silver) during the sixteenth, seventeenth, and eighteenth centuries (Garner ; Barrett ). It is likely that two-thirds or more of the billion pesos in silver ultimately settled in the Chinese marketplace. The salient point is that it was overwhelmingly Both statements can be found in Edwin Cannan’s note in Adam Smith ( [], p. ). As the price of silver fell toward its cost of production by around , profits from trading silver long-distance slumped: ‘over the long run, the trend was unmistakable: profits as recorded in the Netherlands fell steadily from a peak of nearly million guilders per year in the s to a loss of , guilders per year in the s. The same downward course of profits characterized the EIC . . . The return to invested capital, by Chaudhuri’s reckoning, fell from . per cent per annum in the s to . per cent in the decade –’ (De Vries, , p. ). For the most up-to-date estimates for Latin American silver production, see Richard Garner’s website at www.laceh.com, which currently lists total New World silver production at about . bn pesos up to . The birth of globalisation: a critique silver that was swapped for Chinese exports (silks, ceramics, tea, and so on). It is as simple as this: Chinese exports were exchanged for silver from America and from Japan. That is, commodities were exchanged for commodities. Textbook international financial accounting instructs us that a current account deficit (a trade deficit) necessarily implies a capital account surplus (that is, international borrowing). But there was no systematic Chinese ‘capital account surplus’ during the early-modern period. That is, the Chinese did not sustain Chinese exports from the sixteenth through to the eighteenth century by providing loans to Europeans. Since there was no lending pattern that can justify description of EurAsian trade in terms of a ‘capital account imbalance’, there could not have been EurAsian ‘current account imbalances’ either. In other words, Europeans did not ‘have to’ send silver to China as a (trade-deficit) balancing item any more than Chinese ‘had to’ export silks, porcelains, and tea as (trade-deficit) balancing items to the outside world in order to compensate for the importation of nonChinese silver. Trade was balanced, since international lending did not finance China’s trade with the rest of the world. Systematic sixteentheighteenth century intercontinental trade imbalances between Europe and ‘Asia’ are imagined constructs that result from confusion of monetary flows with international debt. But intercontinental monetary flows need not (and in this case, did not) imply intercontinental credit arrangements. Monetary flows and credit purchases are distinct phenomena. Monetary commodities were systematically exchanged for non-monetary commodities throughout the early-modern world, but this has nothing to do with trade imbalances. Misunderstandings surrounding global monetary flows underlie our unwillingness to accept the O’Rourke and Williamson claim that silver flows can be excluded from analysis of non-monetary markets at the global level. Silver was unquestionably the most significant trade item in the world from the sixteenth through to the eighteenth century. And we believe historians are justified in emphasising the central role of end-market China, aptly described by Magalhaes Godinho (, p. ) as a ‘suction pump’ (bomba aspirante), a ‘vacuum cleaner’ attracting silver globally for centuries. Historians are well aware of the global nature of the silver market and the place occupied by China in it. As early as , Antonio Dominguez Ortiz wrote: Asia as ever was the sponge which soaked up the precious metals of the West: only now it was not Roman denarii but Potosı́ silver which streamed into Turkey, Persia and There were Chinese commercial loans, of course, just as there were European commercial loans, but this is not the issue we are addressing. Our point is that China exported goods in exchange for American and Japanese silver; the Chinese did not systematically lend to Europeans for centuries in order to finance a purported Chinese trade surplus. There was no trade surplus in need of financing, although loans were involved in the (balanced) trade along the way. For further discussion of theoretical issues in this literature, see Flynn and Giráldez (c). European Review of Economic History Sumatra – ‘the Spanish dollars are everywhere current’, remarked a traveler there – and finished its long odyssey in China, where the king of Spain was known as the ‘Silver King’ and Spanish duros circulated until the last century. In this way American silver created a sort of economic unity in the world (Dominguez Ortiz , p. ). Carlo Cipolla also recognised the global character of the American trade with Europe: With the exception of the exchanges between Acapulco and the Philippines, international commerce in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries could be described summarily in this way: A mass of silver in coins or ingots moved from Mexico and Peru to Spain, from where it spread to all European countries. From Europe a big part of this silver moved toward the Orient to finish in India and China. In the opposite direction a mass of European products moved toward America (Cipolla, , p. ). In the absence of silver supplies from the Americas and Japan, Europeans would not (and could not) have bought such vast quantities of Asian products throughout the sixteenth to eighteenth centuries; likewise, vast Chinese exports would have been impossible in the absence of unprecedented silver discoveries in Japan and the Americas. In short, the history of silver cannot be divorced from discussion of international trade, nor from the birth of a global economy. In their Journal of Economic History article, an explicit O’Rourke and Williamson (b, pp. –) model restricts ‘import demand’ to the European side of the equation, while ‘export supply’ rests exclusively on the Asian side of the ledger. As stated above, however, demand-side forces emanating from within China were a sine qua non in terms of the birth of global trade. Chinese exports were impossible without the simultaneous Chinese importation of non-Chinese silver, so we cannot accept any characterisation Richards (, p. ) elucidates the role of the Dutch East India Company in global perspective: ‘From one perspective at least, the Dutch East India simply acted as a European way station for the flow of New World silver and pumped this out to its trading stations in the east as a commodity. More often than not reales valued by weight remained in their original boxes packed at the Mexican or Peruvian mints set up adjacent to the mines. Only after arrival at Batavia or any of the other Dutch trading stations did the reales pass into circulation or bullion enter the local mints. In other words, at least part of the copious New World treasure flow was a direct transfer from the point of production and working to its eventual, far distant, point of monetary circulation in Asia.’ Robert Marks stresses the crucial role of New World silver in stimulating trade between Europe and Asia, as well as Africa and the Americas: ‘Even Columbus’s “discovery” of the Americas and Vasco da Gama’s sailing around Africa to get to the Indian Ocean would not have done much for European fortunes had they not found both vast quantities of silver in the New World with which to buy Asian goods and a supply of African slaves to work the New World plantations after European diseases killed off most of the Native American population’ (Marks , p. ). See Marks (, p. ) for similar sentiments. Incidentally, most of the silver sent to India during the first silver cycle (s–) was forwarded to China: ‘There is ample evidence that American silver flowing into India was re-exported to China and Southeast Asia in exchange for exports from these regions’ (Chaudhuri , p. ). For extensive discussion of the Chinese marketplace, see Deng (). The birth of globalisation: a critique of China (or ‘Asia’) or America exclusively in supply-side terms. It is essential to recognise that all trading parties participated simultaneously as export suppliers and import demanders. Similarly, we object to characterisation of European markets exclusively in demand-side terms. The swap of products requires both import demand and export supply, but the O’Rourke and Williamson model assigns nations, regions, and continents to either the demand or supply side of the equation exclusively. . Luxuries versus non-luxuries in long-distance trade O’Rourke and Williamson state that long-distance trade was dominated by luxury goods, a commonplace claim in the economic history literature: Long-distance trade in the pre-eighteenth century period was largely limited to what might be called non-competing goods . . . By definition, these non-competing goods were very expensive luxuries in importing markets, and thus could bear the high cost of transportation from their (cheap) sources. Also by definition, their presence or absence in Europe had little impact on domestic production since they were largely non-competing. Again, by definition, their presence or absence in Europe had an impact on the living standards of the very rich who could afford these expensive luxuries (O’Rourke and Williamson a, pp. –). We find two problems with this statement. First, pre-eighteenth century global trade was not restricted to luxury items. It is misleading to label cowries, copper, low-quality silks, teas, sugar, rhubarb, and many other Asian exports as luxury items throughout the period. In addition to wealthy customers, Chinese exports were destined for consumers of modest means. A case in point is China’s sugar industry. China’s immense domestic market absorbed the bulk of Chinese sugar production, but the small percentage exported was significant in absolute terms: ‘A conservative estimate, based upon the scattered figures we have, suggest that China produced approximately –m pounds of sugar for export annually in the s. By way of comparison, the total output of Brazilian sugar in , when the Portuguese supplied nearly all of Europe with sugar from Brazil, was around m pounds’ (Mazumdar , p. ). Indeed, when events in Brazil disrupted European supplies beginning in the s, this led to European imports of Chinese sugar: ‘Six English ships carried back a total of tons of Chinese sugar in ’ (Mazumdar , p. ). ‘China’s major imports in the late Ming were divided into three categories: precious metals, textiles, and ballast goods. Gold bullion . . . was exported in significant quantities to Japan, India and the Philippines. Textiles, especially raw silk . . . were in increasing demand for export within Asia and to Europe. Ballast cargoes were supplied primarily from expanding export-oriented agricultural production, sugar in particular, and other commodities, such as alum, porcelain and zinc’ (Souza , p. ). Also see Souza (, pp. , , and ) for discussion of the role of Chinese sugar exports. Pre-s trade in seemingly minor products sometimes involved serious economic implications. Rhubarb, with supposed medicinal properties, was exported from Tibet to European Review of Economic History Sugar was a crucial import for areas that initiated industrialisation; the English, for example, consumed pounds of sugar per person annually by , an amount that increased to pounds/person per year by the s (Walvin , p. ). According to Pomeranz (, p. ), replacement of calories from American sugar in England would have required up to .m acres of average-yielding English farmland annually in , and as many as .m acres by . Much of that slave-produced sugar was used to sweeten tea, of course, an import from China that began as a luxury item, but evolved over the decades into a mass-consumption beverage for commoners: The spread of the tea-drinking habit in Europe during the early years of the eighteenth century was an astonishingly rapid process in the assimilation of a new economic product . . . The greater availability of sugar supplies from the West Indian plantations and the decline in its cost provided the context in which the mass consumption of tea could become a reality. For people in the lower income groups, tea as a beverage was appealing not only for its intrinsic taste and quality but also as a means of taking sugar (Chaudhuri , p. ). Some , Africans were imported into the British West Indies during the seventeenth century, but millions of plantation workers were to follow: In the broad history of the Atlantic slave trade, the British carried some three million Africans into the New World. And all for what? The sole purpose of that African presence in the Americas was to produce crops to satisfy the tastes and needs of the western world (Walvin , pp. –). China (among other places): ‘By the late s profits from the rhubarb trade had grown so huge that in , not long after the Qing dynasty formed, tsarist Russia established a monopoly supervised by its ministry of war. By the end of the seventeenth century Russia had secured most of the rhubarb market. As a result, trade between Russia and China expanded tenfold, from , rubles in to ,, rubles in ’ (Feigon , p. ). ‘The East India Company papers show that tea “took off” as a major commodity in England in the years to . Thereafter the Company’s imports from China registered extraordinary growth. The bare figures tell the remarkable story. In the s almost million pounds of tea were landed. The following decade it grew to . million, rising to more than million in the s. By the s more than million pounds of tea came to Britain. Over that -year period, importations of tea had increased fivefold’. Impressive as official figures may seem, however, they underestimate the flows of Chinese teas into Europe: ‘The smugglers sometimes provided better qualities and wider assortment than the legal sales of the [English] East India Company, and contributed to the development of a genuinely national market by distributing their imports from all coasts of England and Scotland rather than just from London. The tea destined to be smuggled into Great Britain was bought in China by the agents of various European East India Companies, and found its way into smuggling channels from their home ports, most importantly Copenhagen, Amsterdam, Ostend and the ports of Normandy and Brittany’ (Wills , p. ). And Africans were end-market customers as well. Europeans imported a third of a million pieces of Asian and European textiles into Africa by the early nineteenth century (Walvin , p. ). The birth of globalisation: a critique Necessary for brewing and drinking tea, porcelain wares were imported on the tea-carrying ships themselves. Much of the blue-and-white porcelain sold in Canton came from the great ceramic centre Ching-te-Chen (near Nanking), a city of nearly one million people and , kilns in the early eighteenth century (Chaudhuri , p. ). Ceramics were ideal ballast goods because they furnished protection from condensation and rain for valuable cargo such as tea and silk (in the middle of the ship) (Hobhouse , p. ). Perhaps , tons of ceramics (that is, million pieces of Chinese porcelain) were imported by the British East India Company between and : [Importation of Chinese porcelain] only amounts to about five pieces for every Briton who lived beyond the age of ten in the same period. The vast majority would not have used ceramics at the time, but of people who used china at all in the eighteenth century, most would have used Chinese porcelain, because before about it was cheaper than ordinary pottery (Hobhouse , p. ). The point is that luxury goods often evolved into everyday necessities over time: Before , the new items of tableware were unusual among lower income groups. Perhaps only one person in ten owned the crockery needed to make and serve the exotic drinks so fashionable in upper reaches of English life. By mid-eighteenth century, all this had changed (on both sides of the Atlantic), as ever more people were able to buy the new tableware and more and more people made tea in their homes (Walvin , p. ). Our point is that distinctions between luxury and non-luxury products are time-sensitive; luxury imports frequently became commonplace imports over time. The world monetary system was silver-based prior to the nineteenth century; and even poor peasants in China were required to pay taxes in silver. In addition, hundreds of thousands of people worked in silver mines, and even these large numbers were but a fraction of the ordinary individuals who participated in silver commerce worldwide. Moreover, China’s main export – silk – was not exclusively a luxury. Perhaps a Spanish official in Lima exaggerated in his letter to King Philip II when asserting that Spanish silks were eight times more expensive than comparable Chinese silks (Borah , p. ), but imports from China did indeed ruin the American market for finished Spanish silks. Mexican silk guilds benefited, on the other hand, due to large supplies of Chinese silk yarn that arrived via the Philippines: ‘With the expansion that resulted from this new supply, silk manufacturers in Mexico City, Puebla, and Oaxaca gave work to more than , people’ (Borah , p. ). Native Americans wore Chinese silks: According to the report of the Viceroy of New Spain in , in Peru ‘the silks of China are much used also in the churches of the Indians, which are thus adorned and made decent, while before, the churches were very bare. As long as goods come in greater abundance, the kingdom will fear less anxiety, and the cheaper will be the goods.’ The European Review of Economic History Indians in other tropical areas of America also all welcomed the cheap Chinese silk cloths, because Spanish law made them wear clothes (Chuan , p. ). So robust was the Pacific trade that as late as the government of Mexico City built permanent facilities in its central plaza for a market named the ‘Parian’, after the famous Chinese parians in Manila: ‘It contained many stores selling all kinds of oriental goods which came from Manila. From these stores, the city government obtained substantial income in the form of rentals which the store owners paid to the city treasury’ (Zaide , p. ). In two Spanish naval officers, Jorge Juan y Santacilla and Antonio de Ulloa, visited Central and South America and secretly reported on the prevalence of illicit Pacific trade: ‘Juan and Ulloa saw Chinese porcelain for sale in shops of Lima and Chinese silks were sold and worn quite openly from Chile to Panama, where Oriental stuffs predominated on the garb of the Spanish population, from the vestments of the priests to the mantos and silk stockings of the Limenas’ (Schurz , p. ). And we should not forget that monetary ballast items played a central role in the preIndustrial Revolution global trade matrix. For example, millions of poundsweight in monetary substances – specifically, copper from Japan and cowry shells from the Maldive Islands in the Indian Ocean – were shipped as ballast from Asian waters into European ports. Before dismissing the significance of such shipments, consider that the one million pounds of ballast-cowries shipped from Asian waters, through European ports, and on to West Africa annually equalled approximately one-third the value of the , slaves exported from Africa during the peak year (Johnson , p. ). China and India were the early-modern world’s dominant textile producers. The exportation of raw and finished silks was the main vehicle through which China accumulated silver from the rest of the world. Low and medium quality Indian cotton exports flooded Indonesia and were also exported for sale to slave-owners in West Africa and the Caribbean. The purchase price of English Company imports of Asian textiles occasionally rose to , pounds sterling in the s, then sustained ,+ levels between – (quantities matched by Dutch Company cargoes). By the s, English imports from India reached , pounds sterling per year (Wills , p. ). Jan de Vries has investigated the magnitude of direct Europe-Asia trade by all of the European trading companies combined. He calculates that the European companies sent , European ships to Asia between and , but only , ships ever returned to Europe. Perhaps two million Europeans ventured to Asian waters during this period, probably fewer than half of whom ever returned to Europe: ‘Throughout three centuries, the European companies were prepared to lose one life for every . tons of Asian cargo’ (De Vries , p. ). Considering the fact that Portugal and Spain only contained perhaps one million and seven million inhabitants respectively in the sixteenth century, two million sailors seems to us a The birth of globalisation: a critique significant number. While De Vries (, p. ) emphasises the point that Cape shipping comprised only or per cent of all European shipping capacity, we argue in Section below that intercontinental trade can wield impacts far greater than suggested by such percentages. . Trade, ecology, and demography: China’s second agricultural revolution One reason globalisation could not have resulted from pre-s European trade with Asia, according O’Rourke and Williamson, is that East–West trade simply comprised an insignificant percentage of any European country’s Gross Domestic Product: ‘As far as trade booms are concerned, Ralph Davis (, p. ) points out that even by only a tiny per cent of the total tonnage of ships engaged in English external trade was involved with east Asia’ (O’Rourke and Williamson a, p. ). A number of scholars maintain that foreign trade was such a small percentage of England’s GDP that the foreign sector was incapable of exerting much influence on British economic development. American plants and seeds comprised a miniscule percentage of any country’s GDP. We are unconvinced by antiearly-globalisation arguments that are based upon trade- and/or GDP-ratio evidence alone. Evaluation of trade’s impact requires consideration of the broad environmental and demographic context in which trade is conducted. Direct, continuous trade linkages between the Americas and Asia date from the foundation of the city of Manila as a Spanish entrepôt in . Trans-Pacific trade was dominated by the highly-profitable swap of American silver for Chinese silks. In addition to silver cargoes, Manila-bound galleons also carried items that were of little trade value, but were of immense global significance – namely, American plants. New World crops spread throughout the Old World beginning in the sixteenth century, of course, yet nowhere did New World plants have a greater impact than within China. And Manila Bay provided one of the main vectors through which American crops were spread throughout China. Consequences resulting from this ‘Magellan Exchange’ of American biota into Asia were immense. No large group of the human race in the Old World was quicker to adopt American food plants than the Chinese. While men who stormed Tenochtitlan with Cortes still lived, peanuts were swelling in the sandy loams near Shanghai; maize was turning fields green Among notable contributions on this issue, see O’Brien (, ), O’Brien and Prados de la Escosura (), and O’Brien (). ‘The Spanish and Portuguese were the more important sources for bringing the plants into southeastern coastal Mainland China via the Philippines, while the Portuguese and Dutch made most of the introductions to India’ (Mazumdar , p. ). See McNeill (, p. ) for application of the term ‘Magellan Exchange’ to biological/ecological transfers across the Pacific Ocean, a complement to Crosby’s ‘Columbian Exchange’ terminology in reference to biological/ecological transfers across the Atlantic Ocean. European Review of Economic History in south China and the sweet potato was on its way to becoming the poor man’s staple in Fukien (Crosby , p. ). In terms of American crops generally, most were initially introduced to China’s eastern provinces by Chinese intermediaries in the Philippines and other Pacific islands during the sixteenth century; another route was overland through Burma (Bray , pp. –). The full effects of the American plants involved ‘time lags’ that lasted centuries from the time of their initial introduction. New World crops played a central role in eighteenth-century China’s population explosion and doubling of land area, yet these facts alone fail to do justice to the extent to which Chinese society was reorganised in the process. Introduction of maize, the sweet potato, and peanut became what Mazumdar (, p. ) calls ‘China’s second agricultural revolution’ of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries (the first agricultural revolution, involving cultivation of rice, having occurred between the tenth and twelfth centuries). Not only could an additional million mouths be fed as a result, but production of new American foods also required far less labour than did cultivation of traditional Chinese crops. Consequently, freed-up labour and land led to massive increases in Chinese exports: The intensification of non-food crop agriculture in the Qing and the expanded production of silk, tea, and sugar for the world market that began expanding with the seventeenth century in China was thus based on a subsistence food [i.e. the sweet potato] which required much less labor than rice and other cereals (Mazumdar , p. ). Awareness of the spread of American crops centuries ago also provides historical perspective for conceptualising tensions in seemingly remote regions such as Tibet today: Another point of contention is that of Chinese settlement on the Tibetan plateau. Originally the Chinese immigrated due to changes in trade, not because of deliberate Similarly, Fairbank (, p. ) states: ‘Three changes occurred in the eighteenth century that set the course of China’s subsequent history. The change that has received the most scholarly attention is the solid establishment of Europe’s presence. But two other changes may prove to have been of greater significance in the long run. One of these was a doubling of the territorial size of the Chinese empire. The other was a doubling of the Han Chinese population. The interplay of these three factors has set the direction of Chinese history in modern times.’ According to Spence (, p. ), much of China’s ‘population growth in the eighteenth century was speeded up by a massive ecological change: the introduction of new crops into China from the New World’ (sweet potatoes, peanuts, and maize). Bray (, p. ) stresses the ‘rapidity with which the sweet potato spread throughout China in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries . . . By the eighteenth century it was grown in all the Yangzi provinces, and Sichuan had become the leading producer; by it accounted for almost half the year’s food supply of poor Shantung.’ American crops had a huge impact on agriculture in India too, but later on in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries (Mazumdar , p. ). Feigon (, p. ) helps us place Tibet into geographical perspective: ‘Tibet is . . . vast, about the size as the whole of Western Europe. All told, the Tibetan highlands occupy approximately one-fifth of the total land mass of China, extending over , square miles through the Asian heartland.’ The birth of globalisation: a critique government policy (which actually discouraged it). The introduction into China of New World crops such as corn, sweet potatoes, and peanuts created a population explosion that propelled the Chinese into Kham and especially Amdo (Feigon , p. ). So it is known that American crops – at least partly introduced through the Philippines trade vector – helped create a demographic boom in eighteenthcentury China. This population surge involved inter-regional migration on a grand scale, spurred by cultivation of new regions like Sichuan, the Yangzi highlands, the Han River region, and elsewhere (Ho , p. ). Population dynamics were also related to increased commercialisation of China’s economy and large-scale ecological changes within Chinese society. It is widely recognised, of course, that introduction of New World plants generated consequences beyond Chinese borders. The white potato alone generated huge impacts throughout Europe, including Ireland, Poland, and Russia. American plants also fundamentally transformed agricultural systems in numerous locations throughout the globe including New Guinea and Africa: The importance of American foods in Africa is more obvious than in any other continent of the Old World, for in no other continent, except the Americas themselves, is so great a proportion of the population so dependent on American foods (Crosby , p. ). And cultivation of American plants in Japan, among other places, reverberated well beyond the economic sphere alone: A number of new foods were introduced into Japan in the sixteenth century and throughout the Tokugawa period . . . , most of which originated in the Americas, including potatoes, green beans, corn, red peppers, pumpkins, watermelon, spinach and very late in the Tokugawa period peanuts. For the Japanese, the most important of the new food was the potato, which arrived in both Asia and Europe from South America in the sixteenth century . . . It is the sweet potato that is credited with reducing the deathrate from famine in Japan . . . Sweet potatoes may well be an important factor not only in the maintenance of a dense population in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, but also in explaining why the population in western Japan grew faster than that of the rest of the country, particularly in the four domains most instrumental in overthrowing the Bakufu-Satsuma, Choshu, Tosa, and Hizen (Hanley , p. ). For discussion of population in China during the Late Ming and eighteenth century, see Mote (, pp. – and pp. –). Mote compares figures and trends provided by Heijdra () with the work of Bielenstein () and the classic study of Ping-ti Ho (). For discussion of reorganisation of production by region within China in response to long-distance trade – including environmental consequences – see Marks ( and ). ‘Many centuries ago, however, a new root crop of ultimately South American origin, the sweet potato, reached New Guinea, probably by way of the Philippines, where it had been introduced by the Spaniards. Compared with taro and other presumably New Guinea root crops, the sweet potato can be grown up to higher elevations, grew more quickly, and gives higher yields per acre cultivated and per hour of labor. The result of the sweet potato’s arrival was a highland population explosion’ (Diamond , p. ). European Review of Economic History We tend to emphasise the role of China, as opposed to other areas fundamentally impacted by New World plants, simply because China contained the world’s dominant economy throughout the early-modern period, and because Chinese demand for silver played a pivotal role in the birth of globalisation. Examples of complex global linkages – interactions among trade, ecology, demography, and back to trade again – existed throughout the early modern world. The market value of the horses and cattle shipped from Europe into the New World was an infinitesimal percentage of anyone’s GDP, to cite another example, yet introduction of these beasts transformed American economies. Our point is that we must recognise linkages among trade, ecology, epidemiology, demography, and other aspects of the global system as an organic whole. . Conclusion This essay offers three propositions. First, globalisation was born in the year . Second, a Path Dependent process – one originating with the overissue of paper money causing hyperinflation in fifteenth-century China (see fn. ) – led to the birth of globalisation. Third, the shape of globalisation today has been influenced by processes that have evolved for centuries. Paul David (, pp. , ) links path dependence and history as follows: [T]he expression that ‘history matters’ does carry a quite precise set of connotations, namely those associated with the concept of path dependence. The latter refers to a property of contingent, non-reversible dynamic process, including a wide array of processes that can properly be described as ‘evolutionary’ . . . The core content of the concept of path dependency as a dynamic property refers to the idea of history as an irreversible branching process. Hakansson and Lundgren (, p. ) connect history with path dependence in a manner consistent with the work of David: The dynamics of a system are not only governed by where it is, but also by where it is coming from. In path dependent dynamics, history is transmitted through a series of positive feedbacks through which the system gains momentum: pushing us forward in a direction set by the past, thus carrying the past into the future . . . The issue most often addressed is how change travels through time. The initial change is often random and what is shown is how a certain process is reinforced through different types of positive feedbacks. What then are the carriers of history? Paul David (, pp. –) identifies two major classes of variables carrying history, institutions and technology. In addition to institutions and technology, this essay suggests that ecological factors and consumption patterns can also be viewed as classes of variables that have carried history at the global level. The body of this essay alluded to four categories of historical effects – () economic, See Jolink and Vromen (, p. ) for additional discussion of the relationship between path dependence and history. The birth of globalisation: a critique () ecological/environmental, () demographic, and () alteration of consumer preferences – that interacted over time with noteworthy pathdependent consequences. It is perhaps worth discussing how these economic, environmental, demographic, and consumer preference categories relate to the three historical cycles highlighted in this essay – (a) the first cycle of silver (s–), (b) the second cycle of silver (–), and (c) the post-s tea and opium cycle. Globalisation was born in with establishment of direct and permanent linkages between the Americas and East Asia. Since profits from the American silver and Chinese silk industries motivated trans-Pacific commerce, globalisation’s birth is best conceptualised within the context of the First Cycle of Silver (s–), itself a product of extraordinarilyhigh silver prices within China. And elevated silver prices in China stemmed from a mid-fifteenth century collapse of China’s prior monetary system. In other words, centuries of global trends were set in motion by monetary/fiscal events occurring within fifteenth-century China. Indeed, vestiges of this fifteenth-century phenomenon have maintained visibility into recent times. A few examples illustrate the point. The nineteenth-century US Trade Dollar (denied legal tender status domestically) was unable to displace Mexican Peso dominance in the Chinese marketplace, for example, despite American efforts to do so. More than half of the silver exported from San Francisco during this period [–] was re-exported Mexican silver dollars. Nevada mines provided the United States with a supply of silver, but Comstock silver did not automatically displace Mexican silver dollars in America’s trade with China. Efforts to increase the circulation of American silver coins in Chinese commerce led to the creation of the American Trade Dollar in . However, these efforts were soon abandoned with the passage of the Allison-Brand Act and the Sherman Purchase Act that promoted domestic silver coinage. The large number of Mexican silver coins in San Francisco exports during this period is testament to their importance in American trade with China (St. Clair , p. ). Supporters of Mao Zedong in the s also confronted centuries of Chinese silverisation history. The communists in Shanxi avoided Japanese units in ; instead, they engaged Guomindang troops ‘where they raised , silver dollars by expropriating landlords . . . ’ (Short , p. ). Twentieth-century Tibetan history also contains numerous references to silver’s multi-century legacy. When the new Dalai Lama was chosen in the late s, the area’s dominant Chinese Muslim warlord and Tibetan monks both demanded payoffs: ‘After more than a year of negotiations, officials from Lhasa had to dole out , silver coins to the warlord Ma Bufeng . . . [indicating] the huge amount of bullion once stored in the central treasury [of the Tibetan government]’ (Feigon , p. ). In over twenty thousand Chinese troops entered central Tibet, creating a temporary It is worth noting that China finally came off the silver standard in the s, when China commenced printing paper money once again. See McMaster (, p. ). European Review of Economic History food shortage: ‘The Chinese exacerbated the situation by distributing silver dollars to the monasteries and the old elite to win them over to their side. The resulting inflationary spiral led to both popular and governmental protests . . . (Feigon , p. ). This sample of nineteenth and twentieth century examples could be multiplied indefinitely, but it illustrates that important socioeconomic phenomena are traceable to fifteenth-century origins. Nor is this essay’s tale of path dependency confined to the economic sphere alone, since important ecological and demographic effects also reverberated across several centuries. We confined discussion of ecological impacts to the revolutionary spread of New World plants as a sort of ‘single jolt’ felt worldwide during the sixteenth century, but environmental factors played out over subsequent centuries. Economic profit motivated initial oceanic connections, to be sure, but ships simultaneously carried American plants and seeds of little immediate commercial importance. These foodstuffs nonetheless generated unintended and profound ecological consequences at a global level over time. Even our restriction of attention to environmental impacts within China illustrates a considerable time lag between introduction of the American sweet potato, corn, and peanut during the sixteenth century and initiation of full countrywide ecological and demographic consequences in the eighteenth century. The spread of crops originating in the Americas facilitated a more than doubling of population and geographic area in eighteenth-century China. China’s eighteenth-century population surge, in turn, stimulated demand for countless commercial products, including silver (coming mainly from Mexican mines this time around). When ecological and demographic consequences are taken into account, the global story of path dependence becomes more complicated indeed! Fifteenth-century events within China are connected to a complex series of global economic, ecological, and demographic interactions that were unforeseeable in advance. Yet we contend that path-dependent evolutionary views of world history permit more complete understanding of events today. ‘The actual economic world is one of constant transformation and change. It is a messy, organic, complicated world. If I have had a constant purpose it is to show that transformation, change, and messiness are natural in the economy. These are not at odds with theory; they can be upheld by theory. The increasing-returns world in economics is a world where dynamics, not statics, are natural; a world of evolution rather than equilibrium; a world of probability and chance events. Above all, it is a world of process and pattern change. It is not an anomalous world, nor a miniscule one – a set of measure zero in the landscape of economics. It is a vast and exciting territory of its own’ (Arthur , p. xx). The silverisation of China – and the course of world history – would have taken a far different trajectory, of course, without the discovery of the prodigious silver mines of Peru, Mexico, and Japan. Our emphasis on the importance of end-market China is not intended to distract attention from the global system (including supply-side dynamics) with which all regions of the world were intimately interconnected. The birth of globalisation: a critique We can identify a post-s Tea and Opium era as a third global cycle that followed the silver cycles of s– and –. An inevitable worldwide commercial crisis arose by (similar to its predecessor) when profits associated with the silver trade dwindled once again. British response in Asia included seizure of control of the opium and tea trades centred in India and China. A noteworthy aspect of the Tea and Opium cycle, however, is the degree to which long-distance trade patterns depended upon changing European tastes and preferences this time around. There were interlocking demand-side surges for tea, sugar, and ceramics (all complementary goods) within Europe. European producers were able to pursue import-substitution policies during the eighteenth century due to mastery of ceramic production techniques, a matter of considerable cultural/artistic importance. Geographic and climatic conditions precluded European production of sugar and tea, on the other hand, so European powers had to depend upon military power to gain control (or at least access) to these commodities. Sugar production involved slave societies and China eventually lost its tea monopoly, but these consequences also depended upon historical paths best conceptualised in a global context. We label the s– period the ‘Potosı́-Japan silver cycle’ because unprecedented silver mining in Spanish America (especially Upper Peru) and Japan erupted at this time, contributing powerfully to the rise of the Spanish Empire and to the unification of Japan. The bulk of the Japanese and American silver gravitated toward Chinese markets, where extraordinarily high silver prices implied global arbitrage opportunities. The crucial role of monetary and fiscal developments within China as causal factors leading to the birth of global trade in cannot be overemphasised. China’s paper money system (partly backed by silver) dates back to at least the eleventh century, and fell apart during the middle of the fifteenth century. Forces emanating from the private sector subsequently increased the demand for silver, leading to a protracted ‘silverisation’ of Chinese society. As the silverisation movement picked up speed, the price of silver in China rose to double its price in the rest of the world. Profits associated with the global trade in silver are what prompted European settlements in maritime Asian locations (and persuaded Asian powers to tolerate the European intrusion). The global production and spread of tens of thousands of tons of silver eventually caused global silver prices to converge by , by which date the price of silver had also finally descended to its cost of production. Between and , or about , the effect of the discovery of the mines of America in reducing the value of silver, appears to have been completed, and the value of that metal seems never to have sunk lower in proportion to that of corn than it was about that time (Smith [], p. ). See Flynn () for a comparison of Hapsburg Spain and Tokugawa Japan, two silver-based powers in a global setting. European Review of Economic History It was during this first silver cycle that a global economy was born. During this s– cycle the ‘Columbian Exchange’ and the ‘Magellan Exchange’ led to staggering ecological consequences that unfolded over multiple generations. The intense profit motive – centred on the global trade in silver and manufactured items – had unleashed unintended ecological consequences throughout planet earth. In turn, ecological and demographic time lags impacted back upon international trade via fundamental alteration of both factor markets and end-markets throughout the world. A central feature of the interactive feedback mechanisms described above is Path Dependence. Thousands of tons of silver flowed relentlessly through traditional trade routes such as the silk roads, for example, while transforming the routes themselves in the process. We focus upon pathdependent characteristics of the – ‘Mexican Silver Cycle’. Mexico yielded more silver during the eighteenth century than did all of Spanish America during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries combined. The early-eighteenth century boom market subsided when world silver prices converged globally around , by which time the world price of silver itself had (again) descended to its cost of production (yielding a worldwide commercial crisis). British forces subsequently conquered Bengal in the late s, during a ‘tea and opium cycle’ within a third phase in globalisation history. Connection of the Americas to the rest of the world yielded ecological and social transformations of sufficient profundity that Alfred Crosby (, p. ) has depicted the post-fifteenth century global exchange of flora, fauna and diseases as ‘a revolution more extreme than any seen on this planet since the extinction at the end of the Pleistocene’. In sharp contrast, O’Rourke and Williamson (a, p. ) maintain that extra-European forces failed to affect domestic fundamentals prior to the s: For globalisation to have an independent influence on an economy, two conditions must be fulfilled. First, trade-creating forces must change domestic commodity prices before anything else can happen. Second, the changes in domestic commodity prices must induce a reshuffling of resources in order for trade to influence things that really matter, like the scale of output, the distribution of income, absolute living standards or the quality of life. Our analysis of the world silver market utilises the insights of Alfred Crosby and other world historians who focus on environmental and demographic ‘The spatial economy is, self-evidently, a self-organizing system characterized by path dependence; it is a domain in which the interaction of individual decisions produces unexpected emergent behavior at the aggregate level; its dynamic landscapes are typically rugged, and the evolution of the spatial economy typically involves “punctuated equilibria”, in which gradual change in the driving variables leads to occasional discontinuous change in the resulting behavior’ (Krugman , p. ). Copious quantities of silver flowed through traditional Islamic trade routes that spanned Asia. For discussion of the Ottoman Empire’s role as transit route for American silver’s journey toward East Asia, see Flynn and Giráldez (c). The birth of globalisation: a critique connections at the global level. Adoption of a global perspective – one that sees the worldwide trade in goods as one (crucial) aspect of an interactive global environment – reveals powerful seminal forces, where non-global points of view perceive insignificant events. We remain unconvinced by arguments based upon the fact that long-distance trade may have comprised a small percentage of this or that country’s GDP (or that Asia-Europe trade was relatively small in comparison with intra-European or intra-Asian trade). The import of petroleum products into the United States in comprised a fraction of per cent of US GDP (. per cent), yet who is prepared to argue that oil imports are insignificant to the health of the US economy? Some products have special properties, and others can be linked to largescale epidemiological, environmental, and/or demographic ramifications. In other words, restricting inquiry to trade as a ‘ratio to GDP’ (or to some other specific variable) can obscure perception of critical, systemic interactions. Our emphasis upon silver’s role in initiating globalisation, and upon demand-side forces emanating from China, is consistent with the notion that evolving tastes within Europe played critical roles as well. Our goal is to place European demand-side considerations into global perspective, and to acknowledge their crucial significance. Our inability to accept O’Rourke and Williamson’s claim of an s birth date for globalisation does not diminish the importance of their work. Their focus on a unique early nineteenthcentury period of international price convergence is sensible. They identify an important phase in globalisation history that coincides with the Industrial Revolution, itself a turning point in world history that is undergoing vigorous debate in recent years. Perhaps the work of O’Rourke and Williamson can contribute to a synthesis of literatures on price history and the Industrial Revolution. Our intent is to insert their important contribution into a broad globalisation history context with a birth date (itself dependent upon fifteenth-century events within China). This essay set three goals. First, to define globalisation in a manner that permits identification of precise historical origins. Second, to discuss interactive, path-dependent linkages among economic, ecological, demographic, epidemiological, and other facets of history that are normally examined independently. Third, to explain how our views on the birth of globalisation US crude petroleum imports in were valued at $. bn (http://www.census.gov/ foreign-trade/statistics/historical/pet-.pdf), while US GDP was $. trillion (http://www.bea.gov/bea/dn/gdplev.xls). See, for example, Pomeranz (), Mokyr (), and Goldstone (forthcoming). As W. Brian Arthur et al. (, p. ) put it: ‘The argument of this paper suggests that the interpretation of economic history should be different in the three regimes. Under constant and diminishing returns, the evolution of the market is ergotic – ultimate market shares are built in a priori to the endowments, preferences, and transformation possibilities that describe the economy and small events cannot sway the outcome. Here the dynamics of the market reveal the superior choice. But while this is comforting, it European Review of Economic History differ from those of O’Rourke and Williamson, and to attempt to conceptualise their research in the context of the multi-century foundations from which today’s global system has evolved. References ARTHUR, W. B. (). Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. ARTHUR, W. B., DURLAUF, S. N. and LANE, D. A. (eds) (). The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, vol II. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. ATWELL, W. S. (). International bullion flows and the Chinese economy circa –. Past and Present , pp. –. BARRETT, W. (). World bullion flows, –. In James D. Tracy (ed.), The Rise of Merchant Empires: Long-distance Trade in the Early Modern World, –. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. BIELENSTEIN, H. (). Chinese historical demography, AD –. Museum of Far Eastern Antiquities: Bulletin (Stockholm) , no. , pp. –. BORAH, W. (). Silk Raising in Colonial Mexico. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. BORAH, W. (). Early Colonial Trade and Navigation between Mexico and Peru. Berkeley and Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press. BORAH, W. ([]). America as a model: the demographic impact of European expansion upon the non-European world. Proceedings of the XXXV Congreso Internacional de Americanistas (Mexico), pp. –. [Reprinted in Ursula Lamb (ed.), The Globe Encircled and the World Revealed, vol. . Aldershot, UK: Variorium, ]. BOXER, C. R. (). Plata es sangre: sidelights on the drain of Spanish-American silver in the Far East, –. Philippine Studies , pp. –. BRAY, FRANCESCA (ed.) (). Agriculture, vol. . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. CARRIERE, C. (). Reflexions sur le probleme des monnaies et des mètaux precieux en Mediterranee orientale, au XVIIIe siecle. In Commerce de gros commerce de detail dans les pays mediterraneens (XVIe–XIXe siecles). Cahiers de la Mediterranée. Actes des Journées D’Etudes, Bendor – Avril . CHAUDHURI, K. N. (). The English East India Company: The Study of an Early Joint-Stock Company, –. London: Frank Cass. CHAUDHURI, K. N. (). The Trading World of Asia and the English East India Company, –. London: Cambridge University Press. CHAUDHURI, K. N. (). World Silver Flows and Monetary Factors as a Force of International Economic Intergration –. In W. Fischer, R.W. McInnis reduces history to the status of mere carrier – the deliverer of the inevitable. Under increasing returns, by contrast, the process becomes path-dependent. It is nonergotic – many outcomes are possible, and heterogeneities, small indivisibilities, or chance meetings become magnified by positive feedbacks to “tip” the system into the actual outcome “selected”. History becomes all-important.’ The birth of globalisation: a critique and J. Schneider (eds), The Emergence of a World Economy –, vol. . Stuttgart: Franz Steiner. CHUAN, H.-S. (). The inflow of American silver into China from the Late Ming to the Mid-Ch’ing period. The Journal of the Institute of Chinese Studies of the Chinese University of Hong Kong , pp. –. CHUAN, H.-S. (). The Chinese silk trade with Spanish America from the Late Ming to the Mid-Ch’ing period. In Laurence G. Thompson (ed.), Studia Asiatica Assays in Asian Studies in Felicitation of the Seventy-fifth Anniversary of Professor Ch’en Shou-yi. [Reprinted in Dennis O. Flynn, World Silver and Monetary History in the th and th Centuries. Aldershot: Variorum, ]. San Francisco, CA: Chinese Materials Center. CHUAN, H.-S. (). Trade between China, the Philippines and the Americas during the th–th centuries. Academia Sinica, October, pp. –. CIPOLLA, C. M. (). Conquistadores, pirati, mercantati: La saga dell’argento spagnuolo. Bologna: il Mulino. CROSBY, A. W. (). The Columbian Exchange: Biological and Cultural Consequences of . Westport, CT: Greenwood Press. CROSBY, A. W. (). Ecological Imperialism: The Biological Expansion of Europe, –. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press. DAVID, P. A. (). Path dependence, its critics and the quest for ‘historical economics’. In Garrouste, Pierre and Stavros Ioannides (eds.), Evolution and Path Dependence in Economic Ideas Past and Present. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. DAVIS, R. (). The Rise of the English Shipping Industry in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries. London: Macmillan. DENG, G. (). Chinese Maritime Activities and Socioeconomic Development, c. BC– AD. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press. DERMIGNY, L. (). La Chine et l’occident: le commerce a Canton au XVIIIe siecle, –. Paris: SVEPN. DE VRIES, JAN (). Connecting Europe and Asia: a quantitative analysis of the Cape-route trade, –. In D. O. Flynn, A. Giráldez and Richard von Glahn (eds), Global Connections and Monetary History, –. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate, . DIAMOND, J. (). Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. New York and London: W.W. Norton. DOHERTY, K. W. and FLYNN, D. O. (). A microeconomic quantity theory of money and the price revolution. In Eddy H. G. van Cauwenberghe (ed.), Precious Metals, Coinage and the Changing Structures in Latin America, Europe and Asia, pp. –. Leuven: University of Leuven Press. [Reprinted in Dennis O. Flynn, World Silver and Monetary History in the th and th Centuries. Aldershot, UK: Variorum, ]). DOMINGUEZ ORTIZ, A. (). The Golden Age of Spain: –. New York: Basic Books. EATWELL, J., MILGATE, M. and NEWMAN, O. (eds). (). The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London: Macmillan. FAIRBANK, J. K. (). Late Ch’ing, –. The Cambridge History of China part I, vol. . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. European Review of Economic History FEIGON, L. (). Demystifying Tibet: Unlocking the Secrets of the Land of the Snows. Chicago, IL: Ivan R. Dee. FLYNN, D. O. (). The microeconomics of silver and East-West trade in the early modern period. In W. Fischer, R.W. McInnis and J. Schneider (eds), The Emergence of a World Economy, –. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner. FLYNN, D. O. (). Comparing the Tokugawa Shogunate with Hapsburg Spain: two silver-based empires in a global setting. In James D. Tracy (ed.), The Political Economy of the Merchant Empires State Power and World Trade –. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Reprinted in D. O. Flynn, World Silver and Monetary History in the th and th Centuries. Aldershot, UK: Variorum, ]. FLYNN, D. O. and GIRÁLDEZ, A. (). Born with a ‘silver spoon’: the origin of world trade in . Journal of World History , pp. –. FLYNN, D. O. and GIRÁLDEZ, A. (). Silk for silver: Manila-Macao trade in the th century. Philippine Studies , pp. –. FLYNN, D. O. and GIRÁLDEZ, A. (). Introduction: monetary substances in global perspective. In D. O. Flynn and A. Giráldez (eds), Metals and Monies in an Emerging Global Economy. Aldershot, UK: Variorum. FLYNN, D. O. and GIRÁLDEZ, A. (a). Cycles of silver: globalization as historical process. World Economics , pp. –. FLYNN, D. O. and GIRÁLDEZ, A. (b). Cycles of silver: global economic unity through the mid-th century. Journal of World History , pp. – . FLYNN, D. O. and GIRÁLDEZ, A. (c). Conceptualizing global economic history: the role of silver. In Rainer Gömmel and Markus Denzel (eds), Weltwirtscharft und Wirtschaftsordnung: Festschrift für Jürgen Schneider. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner. GARNER, R. L. (). Long-term silver mining trends in Spanish America: a comparative analysis of Peru and Mexico. The American Historical Review , pp. –. GODINHO, M. V. (). Os Descobrimentos e a Economia Mundial. Lisboa: Editorial Presenca. GOLDSTONE, J. (Forthcoming). The Happy Change: The Rise of the West in Global Context, –. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. GREW, R. (). Food and global history. In Raymond Grew (ed.), Food and Global History. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. HAKANSSON, H. and LUNDGREN, A. (). Paths in time and space: path dependence in industrial networks. In L. Magnusson and J. Ottosson (eds), Evolutionary Economics and Path Dependence. Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield, US: Edward Elgar. HANLEY, S. (). Everyday Things in Premodern Japan: The Hidden Legacy of Material Culture. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. HEIJDRA, M. (). The socio-economic development of Ming rural China (–). Ph.D thesis, Princeton University, NJ. HO, P.-T. (). Studies in the Population of China, –. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. HOBHOUSE, H. (). Seeds of Change: Five Plants that Transformed Mankind. New York: Harper & Row. The birth of globalisation: a critique JOHNSON, M. (). The Cowrie currencies of West Africa. Journal of African History , pp. –. [Reprinted in D. O. Flynn and A. Giráldez, Metals and Monies in an Emerging Global Economy. Aldershot, UK: Variorum, ]. JOLINK, A. and VROMEN, J. (). Path dependence in scientific evolution. In P. Garrouste and S. Ioannidis (eds), Evolution and Path Dependence. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. KRUGMAN, P. (). How the economy organizes itself in space: a survey of the new economic geography. In W. B. Arthur, S. N. Durlauf and D. A. Lane (eds), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, vol. II. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. MARKS, R. (). Tigers, Rice, Silk, and Silt: Environment and Economy in Late Imperial South China. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. MARKS, R. (). Maritime trade and the agro-ecology of South China, –. In L. Frost, A. J. H. Latham and D. O. Flynn (eds), Pacific Centuries: Pacific and Pacific Rim History since the Sixteenth Century, vol. . London and New York: Routledge. MARKS, R. (). The Origins of the Modern World: A Global and Ecological Narrative. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield. MAZUMDAR, S. (). Sugar and Society in China: Peasants, Technology and the World Market. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. MAZUMDAR, S. (). The impact of New World food crops on the diet and economy of China and India, –. In Raymond Grew (ed.), Food in Global History. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. MCMASTER, J. (). Aventuras asiaticas del peso mexicano, Historia Mexicana , pp. – [Reprinted in D. O. Flynn and A. Giráldez (eds), European Entry into the Pacific. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate Variorum, ]. MCNEILL, J. R. (). From Magellan to Miti: Pacific Rim economies and Pacific Island ecologies since . In S. M. Miller, A. J. H. Latham, and D. O. Flynn (eds), Studies in the Economic History of the Pacific Rim. London and New York: Routledge. MOKYR, J. (). The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. MOTE, F. W. (). Imperial China, –. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press. NABHAN, G. P. (). Native crops of the Americas: passing novelties or lasting contributions to diversity? In F. Nelson and S. Linda (eds), Chillies to Chocolate Food the Americas Gave the World. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press. O’BRIEN, P. (). European economic development: the contribution of the periphery. Economic History Review, nd series , pp. –. O’BRIEN, P. (). Intercontinental trade and the development of the Third World since the Industrial Revolution. Journal of World History , pp. –. O’BRIEN, P. and PRADOS DE LA ESCOSURA, L. (). Balance sheets for the acquisition, retention and loss of European empires overseas. Itinerario , pp. –. O’BRIEN, P. (). Review article: metanarratives in global histories of material progress. The International History Review , pp. –. O’ROURKE, K. and WILLIAMSON, J. G. (a). When did globalisation begin? European Review of Economic History , pp. –. European Review of Economic History O’ROURKE, K. and WILLIAMSON, J. G. (b). After Columbus: explaining Europe’s overseas trade boom, –. The Journal of Economic History , pp. –. POMERANZ, K. (). The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. RAYNAL, G. ( []). Histoire Philosophique et Politique des Establissements et du Commerce des Europeens dans les deux Indes. Travel Accounts of the Islands (–). Manila: Filipiniana Book Guild. RESNICK, S. and WOLFF, R. (). Rethinking complexity in economic theory: the challenge of overdetermination. In R. England (ed.), Evolutionary Concepts in Contemporary Economics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. RICHARDS, J. F. (ed.) (). Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern Worlds. Durham, NC: Carolina Press. SCHURZ, L. W. (). The Manila Galleon. New York: E.P. Dutton. SHORT, P. (). Mao: A Life. New York: Henry Holt. SMITH, A. ( []). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York: Random House (Modern Library Edn). SOUZA, G. B. (). The Survival of the Empire Portuguese Trade and Society in China and the South China Sea, –. Cambridge. New York: Cambridge University Press. SPENCE, J. D. (). The Search for Modern China. New York: Norton. ST. CLAIR, D. J. (). San Francisco’s Pacific exports, –. In D. O. Flynn, A. Giráldez, and J. Sobredo (eds), Studies in Pacific History: Economics, Politics, and Migration. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate. SUPPLE, B. E. (). Commercial Crisis and Change in England: –. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. VAN DER WEE, H. (). Monetary credit and banking systems, ch. . In E. E. Rich and C. H. Wilson (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe: The Economic Organization of Early Modern Europe, vol. V. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. VON GLAHN, R. (). Fountain of Fortune: Money and Monetary Policy in China, –. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. VON GLAHN, R. (). Money-use in China and the changing patterns of global trade in monetary metals, –. In C. E. Núñez (ed.), Monetary History in Global Perspective, –. Proceedings of the Twelfth International Economic History Congress, Madrid. WALVIN, J. (). Fruits of Empire: Exotic Produce and British Taste, –. Basingstoke and London: Macmillan. WILLS, J. E. (). European consumption and Asian production in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. In J. Brewer and R. Porter (eds), Consumption and the World of Goods. London and New York: Routledge. YAMAMURA, K. and KAMIKI, T. (). Silver mines and Sung coins: a monetary history of medieval and modern Japan in international perspective. In J. F. Richards (ed.), Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern Worlds. Durham, NC: Carolina Academic Press. ZAIDE, G. F. (). The Pageant of Philippines History, Political, Economic and Socio-Cultural. Manila: Philippine Education Company.