Capital and Investment 2009 NIPA • Recall income-expenditure identity ≡ + + + • Saving is defined generally as income less expenditure on current needs (consumption) • So, if represents government consumption, then domestic saving is ≡ − − • Combining this identity with IE identity yields ≡ + • In the model economy studied so far, we abstracted from investment; so that domestic saving could only take the form of net exports • In reality, however, domestic saving may also be used to finance domestic investment spending (contributions to the domestic physical stock of capital) • Basic question: what determines the demand for domestic investment? • We begin by assuming a small open economy (exogenous ) • Later, we will consider a theory of the real interest rate (endogenous ) The Aggregate Production Function • Assume that output is produced with two primary factors, capital () and labor (); i.e., = ( ) where is TFP (total factor productivity) and is a function • Assume that is increasing and concave in and ; and that is linearly homogeneous in ( ) • Linear homogeneity implies ( ) = ( ) for any 0 (constant returns to scale or CRS) • In simple terms: doubling all factor inputs results in a doubling of output • Let = 1; so CRS implies ( ) = ( ) µ ¶ ( ) 1 = = • Output per worker ≡ ( ) will depend on capital-labor ratio ≡ () • Define () ≡ ( 1); so we can write = () Example: Cobb-Douglas Production Function = ( ) = 1−; where ∈ [0 1] • Note: in earlier chapter, I (implicitly) used this function and assumed = 0; i.e., = • Sometimes, it is useful to consider the opposite extreme, so that = • But more generally, = 1−; so µ ¶ = = Capital Accumulation • Bathtub equation is +1 = − + where is depreciation (capital consumption) and is gross investment • Net investment is given by +1 − = − • For no good reason, it is frequently assumed that capital depreciates at a constant rate; i.e., = for some 0 ≤ ≤ 1 (exogenous) • If this is the case, then +1 = (1 − ) + • In per worker terms, +1 +1 = (1 − ) + +1 µ ¶ 1 +1 = [(1 − ) + ] 1+ where is employment growth rate and ≡ • So, if we ignore (for the moment), the path of future capital (+1) depends on the path of current investment () — what determines ? Investment Demand • Assume that employment is fixed at some level; i.e., = (so = 0); this implies +1 = (1 − ) + • Initial capital stock 1 is exogenous; thus 1 ≡ 1 is exogenous • Since 1 is exogenous, this implies current (per capita) GDP 1 = 1 (1) is exogenous • Assume 2-period model; so 1 = 1 (1) 2 = 2 (2) = 2 ((1 − )1 + 1) • So, investment demand today 1 same as desired capital stock tomorrow 2 • Assume (for simplicity only) that capital depreciates fully; so +1 = • Let 1 denote expected present value of domestic business sector; (1) 1 = 1 − 1 + 2 • where is gross real interest rate • Note: future value is 2 = (1 − 1) + 2 (1) • Question: given 1 and 2 which value of 1 maximizes 1 (or 2)? • Answer: 1 determined by 2 0(1 ) = • Prediction: domestic investment demand depends positively on “good news” (2) and negatively on real interest rate (); moreover, does not depend on 1 (why?) • Intuition: think of equation above as a “no-arbitrage-condition” (NAC) — LHS is return on domestic investment; RHS is return on bond — to eliminate arbitrage (riskless profit), LHS = RHS Saving, Investment, and the Trade Balance • Now, imagine that domestic agents own the domestic business sector • Business sector chooses 1 such that 2 0(1 ) = ; which generates wealth 1 = 1 − 1 + −12 0(1 ) for household sector • Question: given this wealth, how should households formulate their consumption/saving plan? Easy (we’ve already done it)... ½ 2 max (1 2) : 1 + ≤ 1 12 ¾ • Solution is characterized in the usual way (1 2 ) = 1 + 2 = 1 • Desired domestic saving is then recovered by 1 = 1 − 1 • Trade balance is given by 1 = 1 − 1 ; where 1 denotes net claims against foreigners (can be positive or negative) • Several possibilities arise, depending on exogenous parameters (1 1 2 ) • Exercise: list all the endogenous variables Business Cycle Facts (Mendoza, AER 1991) [F1] Domestic saving does not fluctuate as much as domestic investment: () () [F2] Trade balance is countercyclical: ( ) 0 [F3] Positive correlation between domestic saving and investment: ( ) 0 • These facts consistent with our neoclassical model if productivity shocks are persistent Saving and Investment in a Closed Economy • To this point, we have assumed a small open economy with exogenous • In a closed economy (e.g., the world economy), cannot be exogenous — more precisely, individuals will regard as exogenous when formulating their choice problems — but will ultimately be determined endogenously by market-clearing conditions • In particular, note that 1 = 0 in a closed economy (so that 1 = 1 ); the real interest rate will adjust to ensure that this condition holds The Neoclassical Model • In our neoclassical model, ∗ is determined by 1 (∗ 1 2∗) = 1 (∗ 2) where 1 = 1 (1) and 2∗ = 2 (1 (∗ 2)) • In this version, I assumed 1 exogenous. But now, drawing on an earlier chapter, imagine that 1 is determined, in part, by current period employment • What determines current period employment? Usual optimality conditions. • None of the basic conclusions are changed A New-Keynesian Model • Assume 1 is endogenous (determined by current employment) • But unlike neoclassical view, imagine that employment is not determined by usual optimality conditions (owing to some “friction,” which we need not get into here) • To simplify matters, assume that desired saving does not depend on future income; hence we can write 1 ( 1) = 1 ( 2) • This constitutes one equation in the two unknowns ( 1); the combinations of ( 1) that satisfy the restriction above is called an “IS Curve” • In fact, one can interpret the IS Curve 1( 2) as an “aggregate demand” function • In the neoclassical model, 1 is determined by optimality conditions; with 1 so determined, interest rate is determined by 1 = 1(∗ 2) • In New-Keynesian model, assume instead that is determined by government policy (e.g., monetary policy) • So “equilibrium” output is determined by 1∗ = 1( 2) • That is, real GDP is “demand determined” • Note how fluctuations in 2 (news about the future) can induce changes in 1∗ • If these “aggregate demand shocks” are viewed as a “bad” thing, then monetary policy may, in principle try to change to stabilize the cycle • In fact, this basic idea is a part of current “conventional wisdom” in central banking circles