MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 11.433J / 15.021J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms. MIT Center for Real Estate Week 9: Housing Markets • Sales, mobility and turnover: the market for for housing services. Gross demand. • Vacancy, sales time and prices: the “large” impact of small net changes. • The net demand for housing. • The full annual cost of housing ownership: consumption and investment motives. • Housing demand “bubbles”. • New Development and the behavior of housing supply. MIT Center for Real Estate Gross annual flows in the US housing market (2000) Annual Growth: .81% Population: 275m Household size: 2.62 Annual Growth: .83%=.832M Households: 105.48m 2.5m HH 7.4m HH Renters: 35.6m HH NET: +.21M Owners: 69.8m HH 2.5m HH NET: +.62m 2.6m HH MIT Center for Real Estate As income increases so does housing expenditure: what is the income elasticity (∂E/E)/(∂y/y)? Average Value of Home Owned by Married Couples As a Function of Income, 1989 AHS Age of Head of Household With Children Without Children Household Income 25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 65+ Less than $20,000 43,822 70,817 65,407 72,928 81,514 $20,000 - $29,999 51,145 73,206 77,353 76,427 100,750 $30,000 - $39,999 61,964 75,588 77,720 87,030* 101,464* $40,000 - $49,999 93,814 98,544 111,975 102,495* 113,643* $50,000 - $74,999 109,679 122,282 114,804 117,287 152,532* $75,000+ 182,377 190,244 196,848 171,571 160,292* adapted from DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) Values reported by home owners *small sample size MIT Center for Real Estate Is there a housing consumption elasticity with respect to household size? Average House Value for Homeowners by Income and Household Size for Households with Head Aged 35-44, 1989 AHS Household Size Income 1 Person 2 People 3-4 People 5+ People All Less than $25,000 52,506 51,438 69,840 57,516 60,648 $25,000 - $39,999 79,327 80,365 75,599 81,564 77,868 $40,000 - $59,999 113,421 106,365 104,897 107,873 106,247 $60,000 + 150,791 161,205 162,889 165,728 163,023 All 83,840 104,787 109,993 111,307 107,519 adapted from DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) Values reported by home owners MIT Center for Real Estate Housing Tenure: Younger households and poorer households are most likely to rent. Is renting a “lifestyle choice” or are some “constrained” to rent? Homeownership Rates by Age and Income, 1990 CPS Income (thousands) Age of Head of Household <20 20-29 30-39 40-49 50+ All Incomes 25-34 21.7% 37.3% 53.4% 58.9% 68.5% 44.3% 35-44 36.6 55.2 68.3 77.6 85.4 66.5 45-64 59.4 73.1 81.5 85.6 90.5 78.1 65+ 67.5 84.9 87.6 89.6 91.7 75.5 All Ages 48.3 58.3 68.0 74.9 84.3 64.1 adapted from DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) MIT Center for Real Estate Most households move because the current home or location they live in has become “inadequate”. Reasons for Moving, 1999*, AHS % of Total Responses** Total Owner Renter Housing related reasons 56.4 56.4 42.3 Job related reasons 23.6 15.1 24.3 Family changes (marriage, divorce, etc.) 22.6 14.1 16.2 Miscellaneous other 15.3 11.4 11.3 Displacement by government or private sector 5.2 2.7 5.4 Disaster loss (fire, flood, etc.) 0.6 0.3 0.5 * Reasons for moving cited by households who had moved within the last 12 months. ** Respondents could cite reasons in more than one category. adapted from DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) MIT Center for Real Estate Renters Move More: Lower Transaction costs, less maintenance… Older people move less: because they own, or do they own because they move less? Mobility Rates* by Age and Tenure, 1989, AHS Tenure % Age Owner Renter All Under 25 24.6 56.8 49.9 24-34 18.7 44.6 33.4 34-44 8.5 32.8 16.7 45-54 5.7 28.4 11.3 55-64 4.0 19.6 7.2 65+ 2.2 12.2 4.6 All 7.6 35.7 17.8 •Heads of household in each category who had moved withing the last 12 months, as a percent of total households per category. •adapted from DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) MIT Center for Real Estate Vacancy = a spell (length of time) Rental: Vacancy rate = Incidence rate x Duration Incidence rate = % of units loosing tenant per month. Duration = # months necessary to lease up Owner: Average Sales time = Vacant Inventory/ Sales (units/month) [or # movers/month] [Empirics: see Gabriel-Nothaft] MIT Center for Real Estate The relative role of Incidence and Duration: which changes most across time, across markets? Metropolitan Area New York City Los Angeles-Long Beach Chicago, IL-IN-WI Washington, DCMD-VA Houston, TX Duration Proportion continuously occupied Time period Vacancy rate Incidence Percent of period Months Sample size 1/87-6/88 2.3 34.1 6.6 0.9 72.3 1070 1/90-6/91 2.7 41.4 6.4 0.8 68.4 1245 1/93-6/94 3.6 30.9 11.7 1.5 74.5 1231 1/87-6/88 4.6 44.9 10.1 1.3 64.1 1146 1/90-6/91 5.7 48.8 11.7 1.5 59.5 1336 1/93-6/94 9.9 57.1 17.4 2.3 53.0 1490 1/87-6/88 5.9 41.4 14.1 1.8 64.6 1284 1/90-6/91 7.1 43.1 16.6 2.2 61.4 1191 1/93-6/94 7.1 40.0 17.7 2.3 64.4 1208 1/87-6/88 3.2 42.3 7.5 1.0 64.6 531 1/90-6/91 7.8 51.1 15.2 2.0 59.0 542 1/93-6/94 6.6 49.7 13.2 1.7 59.9 528 1/87-6/88 20.4 74.8 27.3 3.5 41.2 567 1/90-6/91 16.8 64.1 26.2 3.4 44.9 629 1/93-6/94 12.0 61.9 19.4 2.5 49.0 599 Decomposition of Vacancy Rate into Incidence and Duration Figure by MIT OpenCourseWare. MIT Center for Real Estate Are there “structural” differences in vacancy, mobility and sales time between markets? Homeowner Vacancy and Mobility Rates by Metropolitan Area, 1989 AHS Vacancy Rate Annual Mobility Rate Incidence Ratio (years to sale) Duration Minneapolis/St.Paul 0.6 8.9 0.067 Los Angeles 0.9 9.1 0.099 San Francisco 0.9 8.6 0.104 Detroit 1.0 6.9 0.145 Boston 1.0 5.5 0.181 Washington, D.C. 1.1 10.6 0.104 Philadelphia 1.2 5.8 0.208 Phoenix 2.8 12.0 0.234 Dallas 3.9 10.1 0.386 adapted from DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) MIT Center for Real Estate US Single Family: Sales, Inventory, Sales time (Duration) Exis ting and new as % of s tock 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 SF Sales Rate Source: NAR For Sale Inventory duration 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 2 MIT Center for Real Estate How owners transition from one house to another: lateral moves or “churn” The risk of owning two homes (bridge financing). What happens when there is no such mechanism? Matched Household One house Sale of previous home Household “change” Mismatched Household Searching for home Matched Household Owning two homes Successful search MIT Center for Real Estate Buyer strategy: once new house found, will have to own a second home. Maximum Buyer Offer would be such that this cost negated the advantage of move to new house L: expected sales time i : interest rate, opportunity cost of time iLP: holding cost of owning 2nd home during sale process at price P. Buyer Max Offer (BMO): BMO x iL = Net gain from moving. BMO = Net gain/ iL MIT Center for Real Estate Seller strategy: What minimum (certain) price (SMA) would be as profitable as putting the house back on the market and eventually getting a price of P – but discounting that price by the expected sales time. Seller Min. Accept (SMA) = P/ (1+ iL) MIT Center for Real Estate Bargaining theory: Negotiated price lies between BMO and SMA, assuming that BMO>SMA P = BMO - ½[BMO – SMA] (Solving for P – which is also part of the formula for SMA) = Net Gain x 1 + iL iL 1 + 2iL Outcome: price moves almost inversely to sales time: hence proportionately to sales and inverse to vacancy = a High elasticity MIT Center for Real Estate US Single Family Market: Prices move closely with Sales, Inverse to Duration Single-fam ily s ales as % of s tock / Duration 10 Change in real sf price, 12 9 7 8 7 2 6 -3 5 4 -8 3 SF Sales Rate Source: NAR Duration 2006 2008 2000 2002 2004 1996 1998 1990 1992 1994 1986 1988 1980 1982 1984 1974 1976 1978 1970 1972 -13 1968 2 Real Hous e Price change MIT Center for Real Estate Predicting Prices involves predicting Sales, Vacancy and Duration. 1). Sales are complicated: new households, marriages and divorces, lateral mobility, tenure changes.. 2). Some evidence that sales are pro-cyclic: mobility is helped by income security, but much is un-researched. 3). Vacancy is much easier = housing stock – occupied units (also called households) 4). Construction adds to the housing stock. 5). Changes in “ex ante demand” (growth in population, household split ups….) impact household formation and hence occupied units. 6). Households (“ex post demand”) is different from “exp ante demand” which is the number of potential households. MIT Center for Real Estate Residential vacancy rates move remarkably little (in comparison to commercial. Supply seems quite disciplined relative to demand. U S R e n ta l M u lti-F a m ily v s . H o m e o w n e r V a c a n c y R a te s 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 R e n ta l Mu lti-F a m ily (2 o r M o re U n its in S tru c tu re ) H o m e o w n e r S in g le -F a m ily (1 U n it in S tru c tu re ) H o m e o w n e r S in g le -F a m ily (1 o r Mo re U n its in S tru c tu re ) 2002.1 2001.1 2000.1 1999.1 1998.1 1997.1 1996.1 1995.1 1994.1 1993.1 1992.1 1991.1 1990.1 1989.1 1988.1 1987.1 1986.1 1985.1 1984.1 1983.1 1982.1 1981.1 1980.1 1979.1 1978.1 1977.1 1976.1 1975.1 1974.1 1973.1 1972.1 1971.1 1970.1 1969.1 1968.1 0 MIT Center for Real Estate 3.2 4 2.8 3 2.4 2 2.0 1 1.6 0 1.2 -1 0.8 -2 0.4 -3 0.0 New Jobs (L) Sources: BLS, BOC, TWR. Total Housing Starts (R) Total housing starts, millions of units 5 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year-over-year change in total employment, millions Vacancy moves little because of near Prefect Historic correlation between job growth (demand) and Housing Production – except for 2000-2006 MIT Center for Real Estate Theories of Vacancy and Prices (or rents). 1). If vacancy is always “constant”, at some “structural” rate V*, prices must be adjusting quickly so that ex ante = ex post = stock(1-V*). Implication: ex ante and ex post “demand” are difficult to distinguish. This is the Theory of “structural” Vacancy 2). With large systematic vacancy movements, prices or rents must be “sticky” and not adjusting quickly. Implication: ex ante can be measured and distinguished from ex post. This characterizes commercial real estate (next). 3). What determines ex ante housing demand? Demographics? Income? MIT Center for Real Estate Sticky versus Adjusting Prices Households ex post Ex Ante Demand D (in reaction to shift in ex ante demand) D’ V* (structural vacancy) Reduction in Vacancy S(1-V*) Increase in Price Price MIT Center for Real Estate Vacancy may be constant but House Prices move perfectly in response to ex ante demand changes (job growth) – except for 2000-2006 6% 12% 5% 10% 4% 8% 6% job growth 3% 4% 2% 2% 1% 0% 0% -2% -1% based on 4-qtr moving averages -2% -6% -8% 19 69 19 Q3 71 19 Q1 72 19 Q3 74 19 Q1 75 19 Q3 77 19 Q1 78 19 Q3 80 19 Q1 81 19 Q3 83 19 Q1 84 19 Q3 86 19 Q1 87 19 Q3 89 19 Q1 90 19 Q3 92 19 Q1 93 19 Q3 95 19 Q1 96 19 Q3 98 19 Q1 99 20 Q3 01 20 Q1 02 20 Q3 04 20 Q1 05 20 Q3 07 Q 1 -3% -4% Job Grow th Real Median Home Price Grow th (lagged) real median home prices Housing and U.S. Job Growth MIT Center for Real Estate Ex Ante Demand: The Baby Boom makes its way through the age distribution: [see Eppli-Childs] Distribution of households by age of household head, 1960-2000 Millions of Households 30.0 25.0 1961 - 1970 20.0 1971 - 1980 15.0 1981 - 1990 1991 - 2000 10.0 2001 - 2010 5.0 0.0 Under 25 25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 Age of Household Head 65-74 75+ MIT Center for Real Estate Household Structure matters as well. Single rental propensity = 56%. Married rental propensity = 22% 80.0 Households by Type % 60.0 40.0 Married 20.0 Single 0.0 1960 1990 2000 Figure by MIT OpenCourseWare. MIT Center for Real Estate The importance of correctly measuring “Price” 1). Prices versus Quantity versus Expenditure P: price of the same thing over time (OHHEO index) Q: Physical quantity and quality of space (how to measure). E = PQ: how much you spend (NAR average price of house that sells) 2). For new houses (1.2m SFU annually) ΔP/P = 4%, ΔQ/Q = 4%, ΔE/E = 8% (1965-1990). 3). For all houses (6m Sales annually) ΔP/P = 7%, ΔQ/Q = .5%, ΔE/E = 7.5% ΔQ/Q >0: new homes better than old + remodeling MIT Center for Real Estate 4). Measuring ΔE/E is easy, how to measure ΔP/P? 5). Hedonic equation (again) with time variables for the period each home sells in [D1=1 if sold in period 1, =0 otherwise]. The coefficients on these variables, βi measure the price level in that period relative to the first period in the sample P = [X1α1X2α2...] eβ1D1+β2D2+... βTDT Estimation technique: convert to linear regression . log(P) = α1log(X1)+ α2log(X2)+... + β1D1+ β2D2+... βTDT MIT Center for Real Estate 6). Repeat sale price index. Look only at homes that sell more than once over the time period. Dependent variable is price change between sale dates. Independent variable is again a set of dummy [0,1] variables for each period. Suppose an observation has the first sale in period i, the next was n periods earlier. T log(Pi)-log(Pi-n) = Σ βtIt t=1 For this observation, It is zero for all years except for those in the i to i-n interval. The coefficients βt are then the inflation rate in prices in that year. Sources: OFHEO, CSW MIT Center for Real Estate US Average Housing prices (OFHEO): Price levels in line with income growth until 2001+ 1 9 7 5 =1 0 0 ( Co n s ta n t 180 170 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 1975 1980 1985 In c o me p e r W o r ke r 1990 1995 In c o me p e r Pe r s o n 2000 2005 Ho me Pr ic e MIT Center for Real Estate But the growth varies enormously by market. Demand depends not just on price levels but the “annual cost of owning” 1 9 8 0 = 1 0 0 (C o n s ta n t $ 2 0 0 5 ) 350 300 Bos ton 250 Los A ngele s Chic ag o 200 150 Nation 100 Dallas 50 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 MIT Center for Real Estate 7). What does it cost to own one unit measure of Q? This obviously influences how many measures you want. 8). Sometimes it can cost you nothing to own a home. [example: 100k property, 100% LTV, 8% interest, 6% appreciation, 25% marginal tax rate: After Tax Loan Interest appreciation net Year 1 100 6 6 0 Year 2 106 6.36 6.36 0 Year 3 112.36 6.72 6.72 0 9). Assumes that you use the additional borrowing each year to offset the interest you just paid. Also assumes no transaction costs [Fleet’s instant Home Equity program]. MIT Center for Real Estate 10). At the end, you have no equity, but were able to enjoy extra consumption of 6% each year. [this is the choice of someone with a high “rate of time preference”] 11). Alternatively, you could not borrow, have 6% less consumption each period and at the end have housing equity to finance your retirement = saving through housing. [choice of someone with a low “rate of time preference”]. How do you finance retirement with housing equity? Reverse mortgage? Downsize? Sell and Rent? 12). The discounted value of these two strategies is identical, so the annual total cost (in either case) for 100k is : u = 100k x [ i (1- t) - ΔP/P] t = income tax rate MIT Center for Real Estate 14). IF the annual cost of owning Q “units” of housing quality (PQ=100k in previous example) is: u = PQ [ i (1- t) - ΔP/P] What is Impact of: P (level) – versus - ΔP/P (price appreciation) 15). And households are freely able to move and buy at different locations (different values of Q) within the market then should not the annual cost of owning one unit of Q (U=u/Q) be constant across locations? Then: P = [ΔP + U]/i(1-t) 16). Or Price levels for (comparable) housing should be positively correlation with price appreciation. The cost of owning for 1st time MIT Center for Real Estate homebuyers in the lowest marginal tax bracket. [deducting inflation is key] Cost Components of Home Ownership 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 House Price (1990 dollars) 79666 $79,983 $75,602 $75,076 $76,069 $77,357 $73,706 Mortgage Rate 9.40% 12.53% 14.78% 12.00% 9.80% 9.01% 9.74% Marginal Tax Rate 22% 21% 19% 18% 18% 15% 15% Mortgage Amount $63,733 $63,986 $60,481 $60,061 $60,855 $61,885 $58,965 Down mayment (20%) $15,933 $15,997 $15,120 $15,015 $15,214 $15,471 $14,741 Closing Costs + $1358 $1,363 $1,288 $1,279 $1,296 $1,318 $1,256 Total: $17,291 $17,359 $16,409 $16,295 $16,510 $16,790 $15,997 $6,375 $8,213 $9,049 $7,414 $6,301 $5,981 $6,076 + $3,214 $3,223 $3,268 $3,298 $3,212 $3,107 $2,988 Before-Tax Cash Costs $9,589 $11,435 $12,318 $10,711 $9,513 $9,088 $9,064 Less Tax Savings - $435 $979 $1,201 $899 $655 $266 $308 After-Tax Cash Costs $9,155 $10,456 $11,117 $9,813 $8,848 $8,822 $8,756 - $8,393 $8,206 $3,810 $2,430 $2,705 $3,274 $1,815 $761 $2,250 $7,307 $7,383 $6,143 $55,48 $6,940 + $1,233 $1,742 $1,674 $1,490 $923 $1,103 $1,083 $1,995 $3,992 $8,981 $8,873 $7,067 $6,651 $8,024 Upfront Cash Required: Annual Cash Costs: Mortgage Payment* Plus Other Costs** Less Nominal Equity Buildup Subtotal: Plus Opportunity Cost Total Annual Costs: *30-yr, fixed rate mortgage. ** Include insurance, maintenance, taxes, fuel, and utilities. adapted from DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) MIT Center for Real Estate Are there Housing “Bubbles”? • Bubble: Housing demand is rising-because prices are rising-because housing demand is rising! No reason to buy other than the fact that others are buying. u ⇒ Demand ⇒ Vacancy ⇑ Expectations • • • • ⇓ ⇐ Prices ⇐ Sales time Watch out if everything has “positive feedback” and is reinforcing everything else. What stops a bubble? Marginal buyers who are very sensitive to the price level and not just price inflation and the reduction in u. New supply, new supply, new supply! Were we in a price bubble from 2000-2006? Demographics, low interest rates and greater credit say make fundamental sense, but…. MIT Center for Real Estate “Uncharted waters”: restoring historic “P/R Balance” requires 20% price decline and 20% rent increase! 1975=100 Const $ 2004 170 160 150 140 130 ? 120 110 100 90 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 80 Home Price Rent MIT Center for Real Estate A totally unprecedented rise in Home ownership. Rising ownership share fueled house prices. Why did ownership soar? Homeow nership Rate, % Renter Households, Mil. 70 40 38 68 36 34 66 32 30 64 28 26 62 24 22 60 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 Hom eowners hip Rate, % 1990 1995 2000 2005 20 2010 Renter Hous eholds, Mil. MIT Center for Real Estate Credit “availability” matters as much as interest rates. Recent Subprime market offers credit to all. $ Billions Percent 700 28 600 24 500 20 400 16 300 12 200 8 100 4 0 0 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Subprime Loan Origiations Subprime as % of Total Originations Subprime Originations as % Total Mortgage Debt Outstanding MIT Center for Real Estate Subprime Market will implode! [Wheaton, 2005] Cumulativ e Share of Loans With Rate Res ets , % 80 60 40 20 0 2002 2004 Subprime 2006 2008 Jumbo 2010 2012 A lt-A 2014 PCC MIT Center for Real Estate Mortgage Delinquencies and rising foreclosures mean a return to renting. How long will it continue? Mortgage delinquency rate, percent past due 2.0 Sub-prime (L) Source: MBA. Prime (R) 2007Q3 10 2007Q2 2.2 2007Q1 11 2006Q4 2.4 2006Q3 12 2006Q2 2.6 2006Q1 13 2005 2.8 2004 14 2003 3.0 2002 15 2001 3.2 2000 16 1999 3.4 1998 17 MIT Center for Real Estate In addition, housing production has outstripped household formation by more than at any time previously Housing Starts Less New Households Millions 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 1997-2007 6.0 Mil 1983-1989 3.5 Mil 1964-1973 4.4 Mil 0.0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 Sources: Bureau of the Census, Moody’s Economy.com, Torto Wheaton Research. 2004 2000 1996 1992 1988 1984 1980 1976 1972 1968 1964 1960 -0.8 MIT Center for Real Estate Individuals “Discover” Real Estate and Gobble up the Excess Supply as Investment and 2nd Homes Investment and 2nd Home Loans as Share of New Loans, % 0 10 20 30 40 50 Nation San Diego Sacramento Riverside Miami 1999 2005 Tampa Phoenix Orlando Las Vegas Fort Myers Atlantic City Source: Loan Performance, Torto Wheaton Research MIT Center for Real Estate Phoenix Prices 1998-2006 cannot be explained by Phoenix area economic fundamentals PHOENI (#43) 5.5 5.4 RHPI FO RC1 FO RC3 FO RC4 FO RC6 5.3 5.2 5.1 5.0 4.9 4.8 4.7 4.6 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 Econom ic data 1.044 1.032 DEMP DPO P DRINCE 1.020 1.008 0.996 0.984 0.972 0.960 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 MIT Center for Real Estate The simple statistics are suggestive: prices appreciate more where second home buying is on the rise. 2002-2005 C u m u lative ch an g e in HPI, % 100 y = 0.0273x + 14.536 R2 = 0.4201 80 60 40 20 0 -1,000 0 1,000 2,000 2002-2005 cu m u lative ch an g e in s h ar e s o f in ve s tm e n t an d 2n d h o m e lo an s , BPS 3,000 MIT Center for Real Estate MIT Study: Investors/2nd Homes also are Prevalent in Center City Condo Markets • Study areas: Boston, Atlanta, Chicago, San Diego • Survey of 47 new condo projects covering 11,000 units found 32-38% of new sales to “non-occupiers” • Analysis of tax records showed 23-30% of all city condo tax bills sent to different address • Largest non-occupier share in San Diego, lowest in Atlanta and Boston MIT Center for Real Estate 2nd homes contribute to the greater volatility of condos relative to Single Family Homes: NYC Real Condo Real Single Family Multi-Housing Permits (5+ Units) 30 300 250 25 200 20 150 15 100 10 50 5 0 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 MIT Center for Real Estate Price stability requires a drop in duration, which requires a big reduction in the For Sale Inventory. Net flows into (+) and out (-) of the Inventory : history and a recovery scenario Average Annual Change, Ths. 2001-2005 2006-2007 2008-2010 Total households Owner Households (-) due to overall growth due to changes in homeownership rate 1,100 1,100 700 400 1,200 450 800 -350 1,200 600 800 -200 Total completions Completions for Sale (+) 1,700 1,450 1,750 1,500 1,000 700 Demolitions (-) 200 200 200 Net Conversions from Rent to Own (+) 200 100 -200 Non-Occupier Demand* (-) 200 200 200 Change in For Sale Inventory 150 750 -500 * Demand for 2nd homes and "investments" from domestic and foreign buyers. MIT Center for Real Estate What we do and don’t know about Housing Supply! • Do construction costs move with the “cycle” (i.e. does land really get all excess profits)? • Why are construction costs so variable across the country (when many inputs are tradable)? • How important is “time” or “delay” in adding to cost? More than just interest expense? • How is the industry organized differently in fast as opposed to slow growing areas? • Maintenance and Investment in existing structures. MIT Center for Real Estate Construction Costs: Declining gradually in constant $, and immune to the level of building activity F ig u re 3 4 : W a s h in g to n , D C Ap a rtm e n t C o n s tru c tio n R e a l C o s t In d e x vs N e w Ap a rtm e n t S u p p ly 1 8,0 0 0 1 15 .0 0 1 6,0 0 0 1 10 .0 0 1 4,0 0 0 1 00 .0 0 1 0,0 0 0 8 ,00 0 95 .0 0 6 ,00 0 90 .0 0 4 ,00 0 85 .0 0 2 ,00 0 01 99 03 20 20 19 97 19 95 19 91 89 93 19 19 87 Y e ar 19 19 85 19 83 19 79 77 75 81 19 19 19 19 73 19 71 19 69 0 19 67 80 .0 0 Building Permits Issued 1 2,0 0 0 19 Cost Index 1970 = 100 1 05 .0 0 C o n stru ctio n C os t Ind e x A p a rtm en t B u ild ing P e rm its MIT Center for Real Estate Housing construction during the cycle: Starts → Inventory → Completions [Inventory of Units under construction, 1000s] 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 Figure by MIT OpenCourseWare. MIT Center for Real Estate What impacts the concentration of the Home Building Industry (T. Somerville)? • Builders are “bigger” in high volume MSA markets (i.e. each builds more). • Concentration (e.g. top 10 share) does not change as market volume and market size vary. • Thus high volume markets do not have more, same size builders, but rather the same number of builders – each building more units. • Equals = Monopolistic competition. • Larger # of regulatory agencies (towns) leads to a greater number of smaller builders. Why? MIT Center for Real Estate Maintenance, Improvements, and expansions as “Supply” • It is rational to let buildings eventually deteriorate. With discounting, the net benefits of maintenance decline over time. • Major improvements, expansions constitute a huge annual market (30% as large as new development). • Improvements are “rational” and are more likely to occur when housing is a “good investment” (i.e. low P and high expected ΔP/P ). • The Elderly improve less = another way of consuming your housing equity! (instead of a reverse mortgage)