Document 13615313

advertisement
Introduction to Econometrics
Brandon Lee
15.450 Recitation 9
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Law of Large Numbers
Suppose xt are IID and E [xt ] = µ. Then the Law of Large
Numbers states that
plim
1
T
T
∑ xt = µ
t=1
Intuitively, the LLN says that as the sample gets larger, the
sample average approaches the true mean.
The LLN is often the basis for establishing consistency of
statistical estimators.
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Consistency of OLS Estimator
Suppose
yi = xi β + εi
where E [εi |xi ] = 0 (which then implies that the error term is
uncorrelated to the sample: E [xi εi ] = 0)
The OLS estimator is given by
βˆ = X 0 X
−1
X 0y
Let’s verify that βˆ is consistent: that is, plim βˆ = β .
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Continued
Note
βˆ = X 0 X
−1
= X 0X
−1
X 0y
X 0 X 0β + ε
−1 0
= β + X 0X
Xε
Therefore,
−1 0
plim βˆ = β + plim X 0 X
Xε
0 −1 0 !
XX
Xε
= β + plim
N
N
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Continued
0 −1
will converge to some limit and
The key here is that XNX
0 so will XNε . But by the Law of Large Numbers, we know
that
0 Xε
plim
= E [xi εi ] = 0
N
Therefore,
plim βˆ = β
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Central Limit Theorem
Suppose that xt is a random vector such that E [xt ] = µ and
Var (xt ) = Ω. The Central Limit Theorem states that
1
√
T
T
∑ (xt − µ ) ⇒ N (0, Ω)
t=1
Here, the convergence is in “convergence in distribution”.
The CLT is often used to derive asymptotic distribution of
statistical estimators.
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Maximum Likelihood Estimator
Having observed the sample x1 , . . . , xT , we want to estimate
the unknown true parameter θ0 of the data generating process
f (x; θ ).
Maximum likelihood estimation is an intuitive procedure in
which the probability of observing our sample is maximized at
our maximum likelihood estimate θ̂MLE .
Likelihood function (it is a function of the parameter θ ,
taking as given the sample): L (θ |x1 , . . . , xT )
Log-likelihood function (this is typically what we work with):
L (θ |x1 , . . . , xT )
The goal is to find θ̂ that maximizes our (log-)likelihood
function. Sometimes we can do this by finding a solution to
the first order condition, but in other situations we may have
to resort to numerical optimization routines.
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Example: Mixture of Normals
Assume that
asset returns are IID and normally distributed,
2
N µ, σ . We’ve seen in the lectures that the MLE of µ and
σ 2 are simply given by the sample mean and sample variance,
respectively.
Let’s assume instead that returns are IID over time, but now
drawn from a mixture of normal distributions:
that is with
probability λ , it is drawn from N µ1 , σ12 and with probability
1 − λ , it is drawn from N µ2 , σ22 . This is one of the popular
approaches to modelling fat-tail distributions.
Now the parameters of the model are λ , µ1 , σ12 , µ2 , σ22 .
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Continued
Note that
f Rt |λ , µ1 , σ12 , µ2 , σ22
=λ·q
1
e
−
(Rt −µ1 )2
2σ12
2πσ12
1
e
+ (1 − λ ) · q
2πσ22
−
(Rt −µ2 )2
2σ22
and since we have IID sample,
T
L λ , µ1 , σ12 , µ2 , σ22 |R1 , . . . , RT = ∏ f Rt |λ , µ1 , σ12 , µ2 , σ22
t=1
The log-likelihood function is given by
L λ , µ1 , σ12 , µ2 , σ22 |R1 , . . . , RT


(Rt −µ1 )2
(Rt −µ2 )2
T
−
−
1
1
2σ12
2σ22

+ (1 − λ ) · q
= ∑ log λ · q
e
e
2
2
t=1
2πσ1
2πσ2
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Example: GARCH
Suppose Rt ∼ N µ, σt2 . The interesting aspect of this
specification is time-varying volatility. In particular, we assume
GARCH(1,1) structure:
2
σt2 = α + β (Rt −1 − µ)2 + γσt−1
We have in mind β > 0 and γ > 0 so that past realized and
latent volatility carry over to the current period. These kinds
of specifications can capture the volatility clustering we see in
the data.
The parameters of our model are µ, α, β , γ, σ02 .
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
Continued
The likelihood function is given by
T
L µ, α, β , γ, σ02 |R1 , . . . , RT = ∏ f Rt |µ, α, β , γ, σ02 ; R1 , . . . , Rt−1
t=1
T
1
=∏p
t=1
2πσt2
2
e
− (Rt −µ)
2
2σt
Note that σt2 is included in the information set (R1 , . . . , Rt−1 ).
Optimizing this objective function cannot be done analytically
because evolution of σt2 depends on all the parameters in a
non-trivial manner. We have to resort to numerical methods
to find the optimum.
Brandon Lee
Introduction to Econometrics
MIT OpenCourseWare
http://ocw.mit.edu
15.450 Analytics of Finance
Fall 2010
For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms .
Download