Harvest-Time Protein Shocks and Price Adjustment in U.S. Wheat Markets Barry K. Goodwin and Vincent H. Smith* Agricultural Marketing Policy Paper No. 5 Objective Analysis June 2005 for Informed Decision Making * Barry Goodwin is professor of agricultural economics at North Carolina State University. Vince Smith is professor of agricultural economics at Montana State University and co-director of the Agricultural Marketing Policy Center. Abstract Dynamic relationships between three classes of wheat are investigated using threshold VAR models incorporating the effects of protein availability. Changes in the stock of protein are found to generate significant impulse responses in the price of hard red spring wheat and hard red winter wheat but not soft red wheat. These impulse responses to identical changes in protein stocks are larger when the absolute deviations of protein stocks from normal levels are large. Shocks to the prices of individual classes of wheat result in complex impulse responses in the prices of the other wheats. Notably, however, a shock to the price of hard red winter weak appears to result in little or no impulse response in the price of hard spring wheat, though, importantly, the opposite is not true. Agricultural commodities such as wheat are typically heterogeneous, with quality characteristics that differ across space, time, and variety. The extent to which market prices account for such quality differences has been an important issue to the overall efficiency of markets for agricultural commodities. The benefits associated with accurate measurement of qualities by buyers and sellers in a market must be weighed against the potential costs associated with such an accurate quality assessment. Some characteristics (foreign matter, shrunken and broken kernels, etc.) are easy to measure while others (valorimeter and farinograph measures) are much more difficult and expensive to identify. Protein content is one of the most basic quality characteristics shaping the potential utility of a particular class of wheat for various uses. It plays such an important role in price interrelationships among different types and grades of wheat that it also forms the basis for U.S. standard variety grades. For example, higher protein wheat varieties such as dark northern spring and hard red winter typically command a price premium over wheat varieties with lower protein contents (for example, see Espinosa and Goodwin, 1991), and that the price premium varies over time almost surely in accord with shifts in supply and demand for that attribute (Parcell and Stiegert, 1998), as implied by the theoretical hedonic pricing framework developed by Rosen (1974). Several studies have examined the dynamics of domestic and international wheat price relationships (see, for example, Goodwin and Schroeder, 1991; International Trade Commission, 1994; Mohanty, Meyers, and Smith,1999). However, relatively little attention has been directed toward interrelationships among different types of wheat prices and quality shocks that may relate to the aggregate level of quality. Failure to account for these shocks is likely to distort estimates of these relationships and provide misleading assessments of the extent to which prices of different types of wheat are related to one another and, particularly, the extent to which different types of wheat are substitutes for one another. 1 In this paper, we are primarily concerned with the aggregate market for protein (wheat gluten) and its effect of price relationships among different classes of wheat. We consider multivariate time-series models for three classes of wheat—hard red spring, hard red winter, and soft red winter. We are interested in quantifying the relationships between the protein content associated with each year’s harvest for each type of wheat and the differentials (reflecting protein supply and demand effects) between various classes of wheat. Monthly price data are used in conjunction new data constructed by the authors that report the average (aggregate) protein content associated with each year’s U.S. harvest. ____________________________ 1 The issue of elasticities of substitution among wheat classes has been addressed by two recent studies by Marsh and Barnes and Shields using structural models of derived demand estimated with annual data. Both studies, while providing different estimates, find that wheat is not just wheat, in the sense that elasticities of substitution among different classes of wheat are by no means as large as has been suggested by some researchers (for example, Alston, Sumner and Gray). The relationships between wheat prices and protein content may vary substantially from year-to-year, depending on overall wheat yields and other quality factors.2 Further, protein content in any given year may be affected by the characteristics of the market for protein in preceding years, since grain stocks are held from year to year and production practices and variety choices may be important considerations in the realized protein content of a wheat crop. We use nonstructural time-series models that also allow for costly adjustment by incorporating threshold procedures to evaluate the effects of protein content shocks on the time paths of wheat prices. We account for protein availability effects on price interrelationships from year to year and quantify the extent to which shocks in the levels of protein in a particular type of wheat affect the differentials in wheat prices among the individual wheat classes. Our analysis uses dynamic impulse responses to track price responses to shocks in the protein market and other shocks to specific wheat class prices. The analysis provides new insights about the substitutability of different classes of wheat among end uses, a critical issue in recent trade dispute cases. For example, if hard red spring wheat and hard red winter wheat are perfect or very close substitutes, as suggested by Canadian Wheat Board expert witnesses in testimony before the International Trade Commission on behalf of the Canadian Wheat Board in September, 2003, then hard red winter prices are likely to respond rapidly in similar ways to a shock in hard red spring prices, and vice versa. This does not appear to be the case. While shocks to hard red spring wheat prices generate substantial responses in hard red winter wheat prices, the opposite is not the case. Shocks to hard red winter prices generate relatively weak responses in hard red spring prices, suggesting that hard red winter wheat is an imperfect substitute for hard red winter wheat. Empirical Methods The primary objective of the empirical analysis is to evaluate the extent to which dynamic relationships among prices for different classes of wheat are affected by shocks to the quality of the overall U.S. wheat harvest. In particular, we are interested in the role played by protein content—one of the major determinants of the quality and functionality of different classes and grades of wheat for different uses. Certainly a wide variety of wheat characteristics may be pertinent to the quality of any given quantity of wheat. These include factors such as variometer and farinograph measures, foreign materials, falling numbers, ash content and so forth.3 However, in terms of the aggregate wheat market and the price relationships between different types of wheats, both the results of several hedonic studies and current industry pricing practices indicate that each wheat harvest’s protein content is likely to be the most relevant factor influencing dynamic relationships among the prices of different types of wheat. In the spirit of the relatively extensive literature that has addressed these issues, we adopt a standard vector autoregression (VAR) model that includes prices of the three major wheats—Dark Northern Spring (DNS) in Minneapolis, Hard Red Winter (HRW) in Kansas City, and Soft Red Winter (SRW) in Chicago. DNS and HRW wheats typically have much higher protein contents than SRW and are directed toward end-uses that require stronger gluten content (e.g., breads). We also include a measure of the overall protein content implicit in stocks at any point in time. Our specific measure of this protein content variable is described in the following section. ____________________________ 2 Parcell The paper is organized as follows. Empirical methods are discussed in the next section. The data are then described, empirical results are presented and discussed, and a summary and conclusion are provided. and Steigert (1998) and Stiegert and Blanc both report that the effect of a marginal increase in protein on protein premiums varies among different classes of wheat such as hard red spring, hard red winter and soft red winter. 3 See Espinosa and Goodwin for a detailed discussion of how different quality factors are related to wheat prices. A standard VAR model can be written as: yt = ΓX t + et , where yt is a vector of endogenous variables for which dynamic adjustment paths are to be evaluated, Γ is a matrix of parameters to be estimated, et is a vector of random error terms, and X t = [1, yt −1 ,..., yt − j , xt ] where xt is a vector of other exogenous factors. In addition to estimating a simple VAR model, we are interested in considering the potential for nonlinearities in the underlying relationships represented by the VAR model. To this end, we appeal to recent developments in the time series literature that consider nonlinearities in the relationships inherent in nonstructural VAR type models. We hypothesize that adjustments to shocks in the inherent qualities of wheat by end-users (e.g., bakers, millers, and food processors) are costly. In particular, most production processes are tightly calibrated and have specific quality requirements. End-users may be able to make adjustments in production processes, though these adjustments are likely require significant technological modifications and to be costly.4 To capture these effects, we utilize a threshold modification to the standard VAR modeling framework. In particular, we allow the underlying structure of the model (represented by the nonstructural, reduced-form parameters of the VAR system of equations) to vary according to implied protein availability in the market. In particular, we consider a threshold defined by deviations from normal levels of protein in the market. The “normal” level of protein is defined by using a regression of protein availability on a third-order fourier series expansion, which is intended to capture the large degree of seasonality that accompanies the wheat harvests and subsequent adjustments to stocks. We define the “normal” level of protein (given by a function f(t) consisting of a fourier series expansion) by pˆ = f (t ) . Departures from normal levels are therefore determined as: Pt - f(t) = vt The explicit definition of the threshold is given by c, where the switch in regimes is triggered when departures from normal levels of protein exceed c in absolute value. In other words, two alternative regimes are defined by the absolute value of vt . The regime switching model is thus given by: (1) Γ X t if yt = (2) Γ X t if | ν t |≤ c | ν t |> c , where Γ( i ) represents the parameter estimates associated with the ith regime and c is the initially unknown threshold parameter, which has to be estimated. An alternative representation of this model is as follows: yt = (1 − δ )Γ (1) + δΓ (2) , where δ =1 if | ν t |≤ c and zero otherwise. Several different threshold modeling procedures have been developed. Here we utilize grid search procedures to find the threshold value, c, that minimizes the log of the determinant of the residual covariance matrix, a procedure equivalent to maximizing a normal likelihood function. We constrain the grid search procedures to require each regime to have at least twenty-five observations. The parameters describing the two alternative regimes are estimated conditional on the optimal threshold values. Once the parameters of the standard and regime switching VAR models have been estimated, standard methods of inference can be used to evaluate the relationships among the prices and protein variable. Here we utilize standard impulse response functions to evaluate the dynamic relationships among wheat class prices implied by the alternative parameters. In threshold models, several versions of the impulse responses could be evaluated because in such models impulse ____________________________ 4 This is widely recognized by the milling industry. In the September 2003 International Trade Commission (ITC) antidumping hearings with respect to Canadian dumping of hard red spring wheat and durum wheat, in oral testimony before the ITC U.S. milling industry executives indicated that they tended to determine blends of different wheat at the beginning of each marketing year just after harvest once the quality characteristics of different wheat classes were known. Thereafter, they were generally reluctant to change those blends. responses may not be unique for alternative observations or sizes of shocks. Potter’s nonlinear impulse response analysis procedures could be used to evaluate the responses at a particular observation and allow for switching among regimes over the period of the response. Alternatively, impulses could be calculated at every observation and mean responses or some other summary measure then reported. Finally, impulse responses could be evaluated at each alternative regime with no shifting between regimes allowed during the response. Here we adopt the latter approach in that it yields the clearest inferences regarding the differences in regimes. Data and Empirical Results We use monthly averages of daily cash prices for three alternative classes of wheat—DNS in Minneapolis, HRW in Kansas City, and SRW in Chicago. The price data were collected from the Bridge database. Average protein content for all classes of U.S. wheat (HRW, DNS, SRW, durum, and white wheats) for each crop year were provided by annually published U.S. Wheat Associates Grain Quality Reports. Quarterly stocks data were obtained from unpublished NASS data. We calculated an aggregate weighted average protein content for the aggregate U.S. wheat harvest each crop year using USDA statistics on production for each class in each year to form weights. The quarterly stocks data were multiplied by the protein content of the crop to obtain “protein stocks” for each quarter of the year. We then regressed this protein stocks variable on the terms of a third order Fourier series expansion. The data cover the 19892003 crop years. The implied pattern of seasonality in protein is illustrated in Figure 1. Note the presence of a large increase in stocks with the influx of the winter wheat harvest in June and July and then a second smaller increase that occurs with the spring wheat harvest in the late fall. Deviations from normal protein levels are given by the deviations from the seasonal patterns presented in Figure 1. We then utilize cubic spline smoothing to interpolate the quarterly protein stock measures to obtain monthly observations. Such interpolation is most likely to adequately represent data at a higher frequency in cases where movements in the variable between observations are likely to be smooth and gradual. This is certainly the case for a highly aggregated variable such as the total protein stocks implied for the aggregate U.S. market. The observed and interpolated protein stocks series are illustrated in Figure 2. The blocks represent observed data while the line represents the interpolated data used to covert from quarterly to monthly frequencies. Table 1 presents parameter estimates for a standard VAR model. Parameter estimates for nonstructural models of this form are usually of limited interest and inferences are more efficiently extracted from impulse responses. However, the coefficients on the protein stocks variable are certainly of interest in their own right. The coefficients are negative in every case, suggesting that above-normal stocks of protein are likely to have a depressing effect on prices for each class of wheat. The coefficient is largest in the case of the Kansas City hard red winter price. The negative effect is also large for the Minneapolis hard red spring price. The effect for soft wheat prices in Chicago is much smaller and not statistically significant. These results are consistent with a priori expectations. They imply that positive shocks to the aggregate protein content of wheat in the U.S. market have negative effects on hard red winter and hard red spring wheat prices—high protein wheats generally directed to uses demanding a high gluten content. In contrast, the effect is not statistically significant in the case of soft red winter wheat in Chicago. Soft wheats are typically much lower in protein content and are directed toward uses that call for lower gluten wheats (e.g., cakes and crackers rather than bread). Impulse responses for the standard VAR model are presented in Figures 3-6. Figure 3 illustrates the dynamic paths of adjustment in prices to a positive one-unit shock to the protein stocks variable. The largest impact is realized by the Kansas City price—a result entirely consistent with a simple consideration of the VAR model protein coefficients reported in Table 1. The impulse indicates that a one unit increase in protein generates a response of a 42 cent decrease in the Kansas City per bushel price and a 34 cent decrease in the Minneapolis per bushel price. In contrast, the soft wheat price in Chicago shows only a small negative response to the same protein shock. In every case, the largest response occurs two months after the shock, and that responses take ten or more months to die out. This suggests that end users are likely to be somewhat slow to adjust to protein shocks and that market effects from such shocks persist for several months. This finding seems to be consistent with statements by U.S. millers at the 2003 ITC hearings on CWB dumping that they tend to determine blends of different wheats for milling on an annual marketing year basis after harvest and to be relatively unresponsive to price changes. normal protein levels are large. Again, the largest effects are implied for Kansas City (hard red winter) wheat prices. Large responses are also implied for Minneapolis prices, although the adjustments are somewhat smaller than those implied for the hard red winter prices. This is not surprising because the quantity of hard red winter wheat produced in the U.S. is usually about twice as large as the quantity of hard red spring wheat and hard red winter wheat is therefore a more prominent source of aggregate protein. Adjustments to price shocks are modest once protein shocks are accounted for. Minneapolis and Kansas City prices appear to be more closely linked that either market is with Chicago. The results appear to imply a price leadership role for the Minneapolis market in the Kansas City-Minneapolis relationships. An innovation in the Kansas City price results in almost no impulse response in the Minneapolis price while an innovation the Minneapolis price results in a smaller adjustment in the same direction in the Kansas City price that peters out after about 6 months. Impulse responses for the alternative regimes are presented in Figures 7-11. Figures 7 and 8, which illustrate price responses to protein shocks in the alternative regimes, are especially striking. A much large response to a one unit shock to protein is implied by the outside regime parameters. When deviations from normal protein levels are more modest, prices scarcely react at all. However, significant adjustments occur when deviations from normal protein levels are large. This result is consistent with our hypothesis that large changes in protein may have more significant effects on prices than when protein shocks are small.5 As we have noted, price adjustment patterns may reflect adjustment costs associated with changes in production technologies that may be needed to respond to substantial changes in wheat protein availability. Table 2 reports estimates from a threshold VAR model that allows shifting between regimes according to the absolute value of the size of shocks to the overall protein stocks available in the market. The optimal threshold has a value of 0.1659. The band implied by this threshold that defines alternative regimes is illustrated in Figure 2. As one would expect, switching among regimes is infrequent, reflecting the fact that the overall availability of protein in the market is a slowly adjusting variable. This implies that the market tends to remain in a regime for an extended period of time rather than jumping back and forth between alternative regimes on a month to month basis. Protein stocks generally have larger (more negative) effects on prices in the “outside” regime, which corresponds to periods when there are large deviations from normal levels of protein. This is to be expected in that, to the extent that costly adjustments underlie the price relationships, such adjustments are more likely to be undertaken and are likely to be more extreme when deviations from In the threshold VAR models, price adjustments are similar to those found for the standard VAR model, though again a much larger degree of price responsiveness is implied in the outside regime. This suggests that wheat prices are more responsive to shocks in other markets when protein content is above-normal or below-normal. However, the impulse responses to do imply that when the price of one class of wheat is shocked the prices of other wheat classes adjust in very similar ways. This suggests that wheat is not just wheat and that soft red winter is by no means a perfect substitute for hard red winter or hard red spring. Similarly, the threshold model results also suggest that cross market linkages between hard red spring wheat and hard red winter wheat are complex. ____________________________ 5 Note that our terminology may be somewhat confusing here. All impulse response diagrams illustrate responses to equivalent one-unit shocks. However, the regimes are defined by the size of the protein shock. We could have presented shocks that differed in terms of the size of the shocks in alternative regimes. In such a case, the differences in impulse responses would be exaggerated. Comparing the impulses at a common level of shock allows a clearer view of how the underlying structures of the models differ across regimes. Conclusion This study has utilized new data and innovative econometric techniques to address a longstanding issue in discussions about wheat markets - the dynamic relationship between the prices of different classes of wheat. A key data innovation consists of the development and utilization of a measure of the aggregate stock of protein in the U.S. wheat crop. Data on average protein content by class of wheat were combined with USDA statistics on production by class and quarterly stock data to obtain protein stocks for each quarter of the year. A third order Fourier expansion was then utilized to obtain estimates of normal protein levels that accounted for quarterly seasonal effects. The quarterly data were then interpolated using cubic splines to obtain month-by-month estimates of protein stocks. A key econometric and modeling innovation with respect to wheat price dynamics has been the utilization of a threshold modification of the VAR model to account for potential adjustment costs associated with changing use patterns of different classes of wheat. The results from the estimated threshold variant of the VAR model were also compared with those from a standard VAR model in which adjustment costs are ignored. The major findings of the research are as follows. In the standard VAR model, a positive one unit shock to protein stocks has the largest and statistically significant negative effect on the Kansas City hard red winter price and a smaller but still substantial effect on the Minneapolis hard red spring price, as measured by impulse responses. The impulse response of the Chicago soft red price was not statistically significant and small. Similar effects were identified in the threshold model in which two regimes were identified: the “inside” regime and the “outside” regime. The “inside” regime is one in which protein levels do not deviate very much in absolute terms (either up or down) from normal seasonal levels. The “outside” regime is one in which protein levels do deviate substantially. The range within which protein levels were deemed to be normal was computed in the econometric estimation procedure. In the threshold models, the effects of a unit change in the protein stock level were qualitatively similar to those reported for the standard VAR model. When the absolute deviation of protein levels was small (the “inside” regime), price impulse responses were also small, and when the absolute deviation of protein levels was large (the “outside” regime) the impulse responses were much larger. In the outside regime, the impulse response of the Kansas City hard red winter price was much larger than the impulse response of the Minneapolis hard red spring price. These results are consistent with the hypothesis that adjustment costs associated with buyers (millers, etc) of different wheats changing their patterns of use are relatively large. In the threshold models, the effects of price shocks for a specific class of wheat also depend on the regime. However, one interesting result is that shocks to the Kansas City hard red winter price result in almost no impulse responses on the part of Minneapolis Hard red spring prices, although shocks to the Minneapolis price do generate a qualitatively similar but smaller impulse response on the part of the Kansas City price. In addition, an exogenous shock to the Chicago soft red price generates very weak impulse responses in the Minneapolis price, although somewhat stronger impulse responses in the Kansas City price. These results also provide some further insights about a long-standing argument between the Canadian Wheat Board and U.S. wheat producers. Fairly consistently, in a variety of wheat trade cases brought before the U.S. ITC between 1992 and 2004, the CWB and its expert witnesses have claimed that wheat is just wheat and, in particular, hard red winter and hard red spring are almost perfect substitutes for one another. The evidence from this study tends to suggest that such is not the case. The markets may be related but an exogenous shock in the price of hard red winter wheat simply does not generally result in a similar impulse response in the price of hard spring wheat. Table 1. Standard VAR Model of Wheat Prices: Parameter Estimates Dependent Variable Chicago Price Kansas City Price Minneapolis Price Explanatory Variable Constant Protein Stocks (t) Chicago Price (t-1) Kansas City Price (t-1) Minneapolis Price (t-1) Chicago Price (t-2) Kansas City Price (t-2) Minneapolis Price (t-2) Constant Protein Stocks (t) Chicago Price (t-1) Kansas City Price (t-1) Minneapolis Price (t-1) Chicago Price (t-2) Kansas City Price (t-2) Minneapolis Price (t-2) Constant Protein Stocks (t) Chicago Price (t-1) Kansas City Price (t-1) Minneapolis Price (t-1) Chicago Price (t-2) Kansas City Price (t-2) Minneapolis Price (t-2) Parameter Estimate 37.3687 -20.7671 0.7734 0.2567 -0.0638 0.0341 -0.1826 0.0585 67.6815 -41.1863 -0.0504 1.0444 0.0112 0.0891 -0.2491 -0.0217 65.5465 -33.5678 -0.2288 0.5022 0.6614 0.2000 -0.4948 0.1993 Standard Error 17.1231 13.1919 0.1183 0.1234 0.0922 0.1184 0.1220 0.0912 17.8796 13.7747 0.1235 0.1288 0.0962 0.1237 0.1274 0.0952 19.3841 14.9338 0.1339 0.1397 0.1043 0.1341 0.1381 0.1032 t Ratio 2.18 -1.57 6.54 2.08 -0.69 0.29 -1.50 0.64 3.79 -2.99 -0.41 8.11 0.12 0.72 -1.96 -0.23 3.38 -2.25 -1.71 3.60 6.34 1.49 -3.58 1.93 Table 2. Threshold Switching Regime Model Parameter Estimates Dependent Variable Chicago Price Kansas City Price Minneapolis Price Explanatory Variable Constant Protein Stocks (t) Chicago Price (t-1) Kansas City Price (t-1) Minneapolis Price (t-1) Chicago Price (t-2) Kansas City Price (t-2) Minneapolis Price (t-2) Constant Protein Stocks (t) Chicago Price (t-1) Kansas City Price (t-1) Minneapolis Price (t-1) Chicago Price (t-2) Kansas City Price (t-2) Minneapolis Price (t-2) Constant Protein Stocks (t) Chicago Price (t-1) Kansas City Price (t-1) Minneapolis Price (t-1) Chicago Price (t-2) Kansas City Price (t-2) Minneapolis Price (t-2) Threshold Parameter Proportion of Observations Outside Regime Parameter Standard Estimate Error 22.7792 19.0585 -11.4098 14.6109 0.5035 0.1448 0.6560 0.1614 -0.1935 0.1357 0.2188 0.1459 -0.4298 0.1633 0.1451 0.1309 58.2909 19.5316 -37.0815 14.9736 -0.2723 0.1484 1.3526 0.1654 -0.0438 0.1390 0.2971 0.1496 -0.5197 0.1673 0.0367 0.1341 57.6586 21.6677 -24.4373 16.6112 -0.4385 0.1646 0.8157 0.1835 0.6917 0.1542 0.3664 0.1659 -0.6722 0.1856 0.0958 0.1488 0.1659 0.6278 t Ratio 1.20 -0.78 3.48 4.07 -1.43 1.50 -2.63 1.11 2.98 -2.48 -1.84 8.18 -0.31 1.99 -3.11 0.27 2.66 -1.47 -2.66 4.45 4.48 2.21 -3.62 0.64 Inside Regime Parameter Standard Estimate Error 85.9199 36.7720 -13.1946 37.1174 1.3042 0.2093 -0.3652 0.2183 -0.0265 0.1213 -0.2871 0.1926 0.1911 0.1905 -0.0358 0.1229 144.7974 37.6848 -20.1873 38.0387 0.6244 0.2145 0.1662 0.2237 0.0378 0.1243 -0.0868 0.1974 -0.0640 0.1952 -0.0371 0.1260 106.6062 41.8062 -22.7985 42.1989 0.2421 0.2380 -0.1928 0.2482 0.5412 0.1379 0.0131 0.2190 -0.2158 0.2166 0.3566 0.1398 0.3722 t Ratio 2.34 -0.36 6.23 -1.67 -0.22 -1.49 1.00 -0.29 3.84 -0.53 2.91 0.74 0.30 -0.44 -0.33 -0.29 2.55 -0.54 1.02 -0.78 3.92 0.06 -1.00 2.55 Figure 1. Estimated Seasonality in Protein Stocks Variable Seasonality in Stocks*Protein 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 1 3 5 7 9 11 Month Figure 2. Actual and Interpolated Protein Stocks Variable Actual and Interpolated Protein Stocks 0.6 0.4 0.2 -0.6 Date Jan-04 Jan-03 Jan-02 Jan-01 Jan-00 Jan-99 Jan-98 Jan-97 Jan-96 Jan-95 Jan-94 Jan-93 -0.4 Jan-92 -0.2 Jan-91 0 Jan-90 Deseasonalized Protein 0.8 Figure 3. Standard Impulse Responses to Protein Shocks Impulse Responses to Protein/Stocks Shock 0 0 5 10 Cents/Bushel -10 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) -20 -30 -40 -50 Periods After Shock Figure 4. Standard Impulse Responses to Chicago Price Shocks Impulse Responses to Chicago (srw) Price Shock Cents/Bushel 1.4 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.6 Periods After Shock Figure 5. Standard Impulse Responses to Kansas City Price Shocks Impulse Responses to Kansas City (hrw) Price Shock Cents/Bushel 1.4 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.6 Periods After Shock Figure 6. Standard Impulse Responses to Minneapolis Price Shocks Impulse Responses to Minneapolis (hrs) Price Shock Cents/Bushel 1.4 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.6 Periods After Shock Figure 7. Outside Regime Impulse Responses to Protein Shock Impulse Responses to Protein/Stocks Shock 0 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 Cents/Bushel -10 -20 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) -30 -40 -50 Periods After Shock Figure 8. Inside Regime Impulse Responses to Protein Shock Impulse Responses to Protein/Stocks Shock Cents/Bushel 12 8 6 4 10 -10 2 0 0 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) -20 -30 -40 -50 Periods After Shock Figure 9.A. Outside Regime Price Responses to Chicago Price Shocks Figure 10.A. Outside Impulse Responses to Kansas City Price Shocks Impulse Responses to Chicago (srw) Price Shock Impulse Responses to Kansas City (hrw) Price Shock 1.4 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Cents/Bushel Cents/Bushel 1.4 9 10 11 12 -0.6 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.6 Periods After Shock Periods After Shock Figure 9.B. Inside Regime Price Responses to Chicago Price Shocks Figure 10.A. Inside Impulse Responses to Kansas City Price Shocks Impulse Responses to Chicago (srw) Price Shock Impulse Responses to Kansas City (hrw) Price Shock 1.4 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.6 Cents/Bushel Cents/Bushel 1.4 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.6 Periods After Shock Periods After Shock Figure 11.A. Outside Impulse Response to Minneapolis Price Shocks Impulse Responses to Minneapolis (hrs) Price Shock Cents/Bushel 1.4 0.9 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.4 -0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.6 Periods After Shock Figure 11.B. Inside Impulse Response to Minneapolis Price Shocks Impulse Responses to Minneapolis (hrs) Price Shock 1.6 Cents/Bushel 1.1 Chicago (srw) Kansas City (hrw) Minneapolis (hrs) 0.6 0.1 -0.4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -0.9 Periods After Shock References J. N. Barnes and D. A. Shields, “The Growth in U.S. Wheat Food Demand,” Wheat Yearbook, 1998, USDA Economic Research Service, pp 21-29 Espinosa, J. A., and B. K. Goodwin. “Hedonic Price Estimatoin for Kansas Wheat Characteristics.” Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 16 (1991): 72-85. Goodwin, B. K., and T. Schroeder. “Price Dynamics in International Wheat Markets,” Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 39(1991): 237-54. T. L. Marsh, “Elasticities for U.S. Wheat Food by Class,” unpublished Working Paper, Kansas State University, September 2002. Mohanty, S., W. H. Meyers, and D. B. Smith. “A Reexamination of Price Dynamics in the International Wheat Market,” Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics v47 (1999): 21-29. Parcell, J. L., and K. Stiegert. “Competition for U.S. Hard Wheat Characteristics,” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 23 (1998): 140-154. Potter, S. M. “A Nonlinear Approach to US GNP," Journal of Applied Econometrics. 10(April-June 1995):109 125. Stiegert, K, and J-P. Blanc. “Japanese Demand for Wheat Protein Quantity and Quality,” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 22 (1997): 104-119. United States International Trade Commission. Wheat, Wheat Flour, and Semolina Investigation 22-5. Publication 2794, Washington ,D.C., July 1994. Copyright 2005: The programs of the MSU Extension Service are available to all people regardless of race, color, national origin, gender, religion, age, disability, political beliefs, sexual orientation, and marital or family status. Issued in furtherance of cooperative extension work in agriculture and home economics, acts of May 8 and June 30, 1914, in cooperation with the U.S. Department of Agriculture, Dr. Douglas Steele, Vice Provost and Director, Extension Service, Montana State University, Bozeman, MT 59717.