Alcohol Prices, Consumption, and Traffic Fatalities Author(s): Douglas J. Young and Agnieszka Bielinska-Kwapisz Source: Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 72, No. 3 (Jan., 2006), pp. 690-703 Published by: Southern Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/20111841 . Accessed: 10/06/2014 13:52 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . Southern Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Southern Economic Journal. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Southern Economic Journal 2006, 72(3), 690-703 Alcohol Prices, Consumption, Traffic Fatalities Douglas We and Agnieszka J. Young* examine the relationships from 1982 across U.S. between taxes between prices, previous and consumption, studies have traffic fatalities found large, negative price data suggest using data associations and alcohol from measurement estimators alcohol Some fatalities. used little or no However, commonly and fatalities. These result prices apparently conflicting findings may error and/or endogeneity in the price data, which biases least squares ordinary a finding of no price effects. Using taxes as instrumental alcohol fatali variables, alcohol connection Bielinska-Kwapisz| among to 2000. states and toward ties are found to be negatively related to prices. biases may tively related to fatalities. However, as instruments. In addition, still remain, alcohol is strongly posi consumption taxes are not entirely suitable because JEL Classification: II, H2, C3 1. Introduction Traffic are fatalities a have to significantly the potential This on focuses paper cause leading of death, premature among particularly under people is involved in about 40% of all traffic fatalities, and hence alcohol policies 35 years of age.1 Alcohol reduce the links fatality between rates.2 alcohol prices, and consumption, traffic fatalities. The fundamental question is, How does the price of alcohol affect fatalities? Price is an important policy variable, since actually set by Schematically, Although to price, taken taxes there and is little thus Economic about the qualitative the magnitudes the estimated theory for some beverages predicts that alcohol are expected, ? ? are Tax Price relationships of and in price increases dispute estimates together, and other measures, authorities. the hypothesized of quantitative whether, by control alcohol related negatively range it is affected magnitudes nature of these sense. Some step states, to reduce Fatalities. relationships, there a further researchers, for be fatalities. ?? and is price will consumption paribus, Consumption at each involved make ceteris in some is a wide question example, about have estimated reduced form relationships based on tax and fatality data, ignoring the intermediate rela tionships between taxes and prices, prices and consumption, and consumption * 208A Linfield Hall, Montana Department of Agricultural Economics and Economics, 59717-0292 USA; E-mail djyoung@montana.edu; corresponding author. t College of Business, Montana State University, Bozeman, MT 59717-3040 USA. and fatalities. State University, Even these Bozeman, MT This research was supported by the National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism under grant R03 A A13264. two anonymous reviewers, and co-editor Dek Terrell. All conclusions and any Helpful remarks were provided by Jon Nelson, errors are the sole responsibility of the authors. Received June 2004; accepted March 2005. See http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr49/nvsr49_08.pdf, 2 Based on estimates from the National Highway Traffic 1 NCSA/TSFAnn/TSF2003EarlyEdition.pdf. Estimates http://www.niaaa.nih.gov/databases/crashO 1 .txt. Table 10. Safety Administration, http://www-nrd.nhtsa.dot.gov/pdf/nrd-30/ are lower: from the National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism 690 This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Alcohol Prices and Traffic Fatalities studies have alcohol taxes, the few However, that taxes may suggesting studies (2002) find indeed have a that estimated are relatively There estimates.3 and Bielinska-Kwapisz Young approach. different markedly produced that beverage prices substantial price-fatality few on impacts a structural for one with and fatalities. consumption inconsistent yielded relationship taking than one studies rise more results.4 A key empirical concern is the quality of the price data that is typically employed and fatalities, consumption, other behaviors. studies Many have beer, employed in analyses of are data to suffer likely from error measurement substantial and (Young and wine, prices collected by the American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association these 691 spirits (ACCRA), but Bielinska-Kwapisz 2003).5 In addition, beverage prices may be endogenous in the sense that higher demand may result in higher market prices (Manning, Blumberg, and Moulton 1995). Measurement error in the price data implies that the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimator is biased and inconsistent. consistent. may alcohol However, excise and taxes, both models, problems beer, in control renders the estimated higher taxes?including state markups also prices bias how much underestimate substantially of endogeneity Similarly, In simple prices price the OLS estimator elasticity toward discourage and wine, and consumption unit per spirits a set of states?provides biased zero. excise and That traffic taxes, fatalities. percentage variables instrumental in is, OLS in that, principle, can resolve the problems with the price data. This paper applies instrumental variable (IV) to the techniques estimation substantial provide evidence consumption larger and more suggest that than significant taxes are not and from OLS. suitable as consumption-fatalities error of price those fully and measurement of IV estimates and data, the price-fatalities of and/or on effects consumption a priori However, in both endogeneity considerations the are fatalities and price substantially some and results The linkages. evidence instruments. 2. Methods We estimate consumption), that models regression socioeconomic per implies squares 4 capita. and nonnegative 3 variable, dependent fatalities that has yit, (Greene 2003, is the The logistic been widely the disturbance the characteristics, = y it The express wit section as rates and environment, legal functions state alcohol of and year (or prices fixed effects: \nPita + */f ? + u?+ vt + wit. (1) transformation logistic transformation used fatality restricts in previous is heteroskedastic, studies.6 and of the the observed predicted the However, thus Equation rate, fatality value of logistic 1 is estimated rit, fatalities that is to be transformation by weighted least 21.4.6). For examples, Cook (1981); Chaloupka, Saffer, and Grossman (1993); and Ruhm (1996) find large, negative relationships between beer taxes and fatalities, whereas Dee (1999); Mast, Benson, and Rasmussen (1999); and Young and Likens (2000) find little or no relationship. and Schenzler (1994) find that alcohol price is negative and significant at the 10% level in one of three specifications, but that it is sensitive to the inclusion of time-fixed effects. Price effects in Young and Likens (2000) are small, negative, and statistically insignificant. 5 The ACCRA data have been used in studies of alcohol consumption by Gruenewald, Ponicki, and Holder (1993); Kenkel (1993); Manning, Blumberg, and Moulton (1995); Beard, Gant, and Saba (1997); Grossman, Chaloupka, and Sirtalan (1998); Sloan, Reilly, and Nelson 6 (2003); studies of traffic accidents, homicides, suicides, and other deaths by Sloan, Reilly, and Schenzler (1994); spouse abuse by Markowitz (2000); alcohol-related motor vehicle fatalities by Young and Likens (2000); sales tax incidence by Besley and Rosen (1999); and suicides by Markowitz, Chatterji, and Dave (2002), among others. Young and Likens (2000) compare the logistic specification with a linear probability model differences in the results. and find that there are only small This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 692 J. Young and Agnieszka Bielinska-Kwapisz Douglas The price of alcohol, P, is the Stone price index, a geometric weighted average of the prices of beer, and wine, with spirits, to each equal weights share, beverage's oc,on the price variable in Equation to the price respect of For alcohol.8 1 is approximately the elasticity of fatalities with a coefficient example, on alcohol:7 expenditure (2) ln/?=?>lnpy, j The coefficient, in national 9y, of -0.1 a that implies 10% in increase alcohol prices is associated with a 1% decline in fatalities. Similarly, when the natural logarithm of per capita alcohol consumption is entered instead of price, the coefficient is approximately the elasticity of with fatalities to consumption. respect If beverage prices are measured with error, then the price index will be correlated with the disturbance term and theOLS estimator of the price coefficient is biased and inconsistent (Greene 2003, section If there 5.6). a is only variable single to classical subject measurement then error, the OLS estimator is biased toward zero (attenuated). Similarly, if price is endogenous, it is correlated with the disturbance term, and OLS estimates aweighted average of the demand (negative) and supply (positive) coefficients. Similar Thus, endogeneity reasoning The in alcohol if a set in pooled prices consumption error of and the OLS bias estimator replaces be eliminated can variables from away as a right-hand price can endogeneity instrumental proper Although anti-alcohol or taxes taxes is the case, data to be correlated In particular, alcohol. sentiment, If this time-series are unlikely toward attitudes alcohol. cross-section taxes alcohol unmeasured toward alcohol also be side by found. values. negative variable.9 standard two-stage and Young Bielinska (2002) show that state and federal excise taxes andmarkups explain about 30% of the variation Kwapisz stronger will to measurement due methods estimation when applies biases of prices may change are not proper to that employed similar errors with taxes over may be higher instrumental in which to changes In addition, variables. study.10 reflect they may in states in response time in this of measurement, there is in attitudes taxes may be correlated with other policies intended to reduce alcohol use, drunk driving, and/or fatalities, and data limitations may make it impossible to explicitly include these policies as control variables. In this taxes case, will We conclude variables to deal 7 be for use exogenous correlated as state that with with the disturbance term, and taxes thus not will be appropriately instruments.11 and federal the measurement excise error taxes problem, are and markups but may not be likely fully to be good satisfactory instrumental to deal with data are reported quarterly for a varying number of cities in each state. We aggregate to the state level by (2002, 2003). computing simple averages of the city-quarter data. Details are described in Young and Bielinska-Kwapisz 8 The elasticity is exactly equal to (1 - r)a, which is very close to a, because 1 r = 0.999. 9 Consumption may be correlated with the disturbance term because of measurement error or because some unmeasured factors The ACCRA to both drinking and fatalities. For example, some youth engage in a number of risky behaviors that include reckless drinking, driving, and/or unprotected sex (Dee and Evans 2001; Gruber 2001; Grossman, Kaestner, and Markowitz 2002). Alcohol consumption is then correlated with fatalities both because it is in fact a causal factor, and as a reflection of are common example, as underlying attitudes toward risk. The latter correlation is spurious, in that a reduction in alcohol consumption?for a result of higher prices?does not change attitudes toward risk. These biases in OLS estimates of the effects of consumption error biases the estimator toward zero, whereas spurious on fatalities are likely to operate in opposite directions: Measurement correlation makes the estimator too positive. 10 Beer taxes by themselves explain only about 5% of alcohol price variation, and employing the broader set of tax variables on spirits and wine, and including 11 See Manning, Blumberg, and Moulton (1995), footnote 4. Kubik and Moran taxes are endogenous. Brown, Jewell, and Richer (1996) find that county-level Eisenberg (2003) concludes because of endogeneity. that existing estimates of the effects of 0.08 therefore are less adequate as instruments than state markups and percentage taxes. (2003) provide evidence that changes in beer prohibitions on alcohol sales are endogenous. laws and graduated licensing programs are overstated This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 693 Alcohol Prices and Traffic Fatalities of problems regressions sentiment toward socioeconomic and alcohol The correlation. endogeneity/spurious include variables, over its evolution latter state time and/or dummies, the sample to the extent is mitigated problem trends that the control that for period. 3. Data The data data are missing price states the contiguous include for various 1,..., (i= in some years and 48) the years 1982-2000 so the total number states, 19), but 1,..., (t= is 869. of observations Separate regressions are estimated for fatalities in the total population and the population aged 16-20, which we term "teen" a significant display Separate 6 p.m. 6 p.m. Monday-Friday, involve alcohol. for one account fatalities plus of closely related to one or prices occur As even these sense," are than consumption day between Fatalities times."14 third of fatalities, and 6 p.m. these weekend night in each case. weekend 6 a.m. and Friday 6 a.m. less account to night for only one be more should fatalities and likely weekend indicates, times at other fatalities rates Thus, are much la fatality between occurring Table though quarter time. to 6 a.m. Monday, Sunday "other to "make accident Sunday.13 6 p.m. fatalities the Both one by about declining on alcohol, 6 a.m. and the results to alcohol involve occurring these fourth For the week. seventh to Saturday those term We computed likely 1980s, based of the total population. those twice the early since also are most and between Saturday, trend are rates which rates are about fatality downward fatality fatalities, night Teen fatalities.12 times. Per capita alcohol consumption declined steadily from the early 1980s tomid 1990s before leveling off at about 2.2 gallons of pure ethanol per capita (Nelson 1997; Nephew et al. 2002). The real price of alcohol generally declined except for an upward blip in 1991 when federal excise taxes increased.15 Extensive drinking have educational and fatalities. concluded that in part measure, measure environment by a result. The several changed of dummy last adopted educational developed a series summing often in the changes eventually as declined states and legal laws were belt fatalities because enforcement, and efforts Seat variables two by programs. indicating also may other laws simultaneously, We form affected index studies are of a state has to harder up stepped an or not whether have numerous and state, every of many effects laws decades hard-to the legal (i) an open container law, (ii) a preliminary breath test law, (iii) a dram shop law, (iv) an illegal per se blood alcohol content (BAC) level of at least 0.1, (v) mandatory licensing action upon first conviction for driving the under innovations are influence included illegal per se BAC (DUI), as separate (vi) and variables an administrative in order to provide per se law.16 evidence Two on more their recent effectiveness: level of 0.08 or less and a server training law.17 In addition, legal an teen fatality 12 Fatality data were provided by NHTSA from the FARS database (http://www.nhtsa.dot.gov/). 13 An alternative approach is to use NHTSA's measures of alcohol-related fatalities. However, these data are imputations based on samples of drivers who were actually tested for alcohol, and these samples varied greatly over time and across states (http:// Selection bias may be significant: Drivers were more likely to be tested if beer www.niaaa.nih.gov/databases/crash06.txt). cans were found in the back seat. The current method has been used by Dee (1999) and other researchers. 14 There were three instances of zero fatalities in the original data for teens during other times: North Dakota in 2000 and Rhode Island in 1993 and 1994. Since the logistic transformation can not be computed with a zero fatality rate, we assumed that one fatality occurred in each instance. 15 The price of alcohol is adjusted for national inflation using the CPI and expressed relative to the overall ACCRA cost of living in each state. It therefore represents the cost of alcohol relative to other goods, expressed in dollars of 2000 purchasing power. averages of ACCRA prices closely follow the CPI price index for alcohol "at home." The price of alcohol "away from home" has increased faster. See Young and Bielinska-Kwapisz (2002). 16 Data from NHTSA, Digest of Highway Safety Legislation, various years. 17 Data on the 0.08 law is from NHTSA's Digest of Highway Safety Legislation. Server training data provided by Alexander C. School of Public Health. Wagenaar, Alcohol Epidemiology Program, University of Minnesota, National This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 694 J. Young and Agnieszka Bielinska-Kwapisz Douglas Statistics la. Descriptive Table Mean Definition Variable RHS endogenous variables Ethanol consumption ACON Ethanol price ($/gal) APRICE Minimum Standard Deviation Fatality rates (per 1000 population) All ages, all times TOTAL TOTALWN All ages, weekend nights TOTALOT All ages, other times TEEN Ages 16-20, all times TEENWN Ages 16-20, weekend nights TEENOT Ages 16-20, other times 0.172 0.042 0.087 0.346 0.115 0.138 0.066 0.051 0.015 0.027 0.106 0.045 0.048 0.011 0.029 0.132 0.022 0.020 0.430 25.0 1.24 212.6 2.37 269.3 (gal/capita) Maximum 0.423 0.138 0.240 0.937 0.342 0.511 5.26 337.8 RHS exogenous variables = 0.0 1.0 1 0.427 0.760 Seat belt law SBELT 1.07 1.0 6.0 3.27 LEGALENV Legal environment index 0.384 1.0 0.0 0.08 0.180 ILLPER08 Illegal per se 0.422 1.0 0.0 0.237 SERVTRAN Server training law 3.12 36.715.3 25.3 Income per capita ($ 000s) INCOME 7.75 2.09 12.9 Vehicle miles traveled (OOOs/driver) VMTLIC areas 46.4 0.0 4.28 8.49 in DRY (%) dry Population living 13.82 2.30 18.72 POP1829 Population ages 18-29 (%) 18.0 0.749 20.7 DRINKAGE Legal drinking age 1.0 0.0 0.312 0.110 KEGREG Keg registration 1.00.0 0.485 0.420 YOUTHBAC Lower BAC for youth = 1 12.3 1.74 21A 63.5 CATHOLIC Catholic (%) 6.51 0.1 1.51 Mormon (%) MORMON 10.1 0.0 37.4 7.96 Southern Baptist (%) SBAPTIST 7.6 18.6 2.04 12.4 POP65 Population ages 65+ (%) 1.03 0.27 Share of GSP from hotels/restaurants (%) 0.76 TOURISM 22.4 24.0 21.0 76.2 15.1 regressions include several laws directed specifically at this age group: the legal drinking age, keg registration, and Southern Baptist; on effect and the included for the percentage of state of gross percentage fatalities via drink less, but are more Table lb displays consumption (DISCUS addition, Instrumental product alcohol states variable BAC (lower) the percentages of the population over and the hotel from these consumption, sometimes may relationships control a separate of the existence are also Controls be level 65; age teens.18 that are Catholic, and restaurant factors a tourism industry.19 also may For conflicting. for the population example, variable and measuring the to an In addition a direct have Mormon, on effect over the population 65 indirect fatalities, to tends likely to be involved in fatal accidents. descriptive All 2000). levy taxes estimation on statistics states and/or employ markups is performed the per tax measures unit based excise on in LIMDEP used as instruments taxes on beer, wine, prices of the wholesale 8.0.20 First stage for prices and spirits squared and spirits. In and wine. correlations 18 Ibid. Keg registration and youth BAC from Wagenaar, 19 based on Quinn et al. (1980) and Bradley et al. (1990). Age data from U.S. Religion variables are interpolations/extrapolations Bureau of the Census. Tourism data from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/regional/gsp/). 20 See Greene (2002), section E8.5.12 for details. This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 695 Alcohol Prices and Traffic Fatalities Table lb. Instrumental Variables Beer excise tax ($/gal) Wine excise tax ($/gal) Spirits excise tax ($/gal) Spirits excise tax (%) BTAX WTAX STAX STAXPERC SMARKUP WTAXPER WMARKUP Means the fitted between lower and and for price values is consistent for price R2 actual a larger with Maximum 8.57 1.55 22.6 0.0 113.0 0.0 0.0 52.95 31.78 66.4 56.0 35.0 84.2 = 869. by state population; N are weighted and standard deviations 6.64 6.91 7.46 9.52 22.4 0.0 4.10 10.0 18.86 11.69 40.58 3.72 12.7 1.06 2.61 Spirits markup (%) Wine excise tax (%) Wine markup (%) Minimum Standard Deviation Mean Definition Variable are, consumption error and 0.90 respectively, of measurement amount The 0.98. in that variable.21 4. Results tests Hausman of the six rates. fatality and/or of endogeneity are displayed prices 1989, 1993). The null hypothesis of exogeneity (Davidson andMacKinnon for five error for measurement As the last two columns indicate, in Table 2a is rejected at the 1% level for measurement correcting error/ endogeneity has a profound impact on the estimated price effects. OLS estimates are positive for five of the six fatality estimates rates, that imply the However, and three of in increases IV estimates imply are the estimates alcohol quite statistically are prices All the opposite: associated positively with are the estimates six of at face Taken significant. value, traffic fatalities. five and negative, these of the six are significant at the 5% level. The estimated magnitudes suggest substantial effects of prices on fatalities. A 10% increase in alcohol prices is predicted to reduce total fatalities by 5.8%. The estimated effect is somewhat larger for weekend night fatalities (6.9%), and smaller for other times (3.9%). The estimated impact on all youth fatalities (9%) is larger than for the total population. Less plausibly, the estimated impact on weekend night fatalities among youth (3.5%) is smaller than the impact on youth at other times is not significant at the 0.05 level. (9.3%), although the difference The results alcohol using in place consumption of price are similar. broadly is Exogeneity rejected at the 10% significance level or less for five of the six fatality rates, and instrumental variable estimates per is 11.3%. estimated than do OLS effects larger alcohol capita estimate the indicate is associated consumption The effects other are estimated smaller on effects weekend particularly for youth, although the difference The regressions also provide evidence For estimates. on with a 9.9% range from night increase 10.2% fatalities a 10% OLS, using example, in fatalities, to 14.1%. than on Somewhat fatalities in increase whereas the IV implausibly, at other times, is again not statistically significant. a number of other determinants of fatalities. Among the total population (Table 3), income, vehicle miles traveled, and the population 18-29 years are positively and significantly related to fatalities inmost specifications. Seat belt laws reduce fatalities 4-6%. The evidence is less strong for the legal environment index, which is negative for five of six fatality rates, but not always statistically significant.22 The percentage of the population 21 22 living in dry from the first-stage regressions are displayed in Table Al. Entering the components of the index as separate variables results in about half negative and half positive coefficients, many of which are not significant. It appears that the data are not sufficiently strong to distinguish among the effects of the large number of legal initiatives that states have implemented. Tax coefficients This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 696 J. Young Douglas and Agnieszka Table 2a. Tests for Endogeneity Bielinska-Kwapisz F-value Rate Fatality Weekend , Price Coefficient r _I_I_ All ages 28.4 0.16 All times (0.00) 2.2 3.4 All ages 0.11 17.3 1.1 3.0 (0.00) All ages 12.6 0.29 3.5 2.1 (0.00) 16-20 0.08 15.3 All times(0.00) 0.7 3.1 Other times Ages 0.4 16-20 Ages 16-20 Ages -0.58 -0.69 -0.39 -0.90 -0.10 0.5 (0.52) 12.7 nights |?-ratio I IV OLS Level) (Significance nights Weekend Error in Prices and/or Measurement -0.35 0.8 0.44 -0.93 Other times_(0.00)_^6_22_ no has counties dry on effect on conditional fatalities, is positively counties to fatalities, related the price of alcohol. on conditional alcohol However, percentage consumption. This in living is consistent with the hypothesis that dry counties have a mixed relationship with fatalities: (i)more people living in dry counties is associated with a lower demand for alcohol, and on that account fewer fatalities; (ii) at the same time, people who do drink may be more account in more result There little is (Baughman that evidence 0.08 The or laws Mormon percentage likely to drive to obtain alcohol, and on that et al. 2001). server is not Southern and above, Baptists preach because apparently abstinence. fatalities. are fatalities and positively The latter relationship is unexpected, because are positively Fatalities are higher rates fatality in reducing effective whereas significant, significantly related to Southern Baptist membership. many are training related to fatalities, significantly so in two of three in the Catholic church is negatively Membership equations. fatalities for this to the population related is not Tourism group. 65 aged significantly to fatalities. related Results for teenagers (age 16-20) are broadly similar (Table 4). Increasing the drinking age by one fatalities. night but to reduce is estimated year Table 5 is some There on weekend not A nights. assesses the teen fatalities evidence youth 1-3%, by that keg BAC robustness of with the is associated registration law is not the results the varying on weekend impact with teen lower fatalities, to fatalities. related significantly by estimated largest estimation and/or technique specification. These results use price as the right-hand side variable and total fatalities (all times) as the variable. dependent Columns least two-stage concern One is that logit are specifications sometimes sensitive to weighting.23 1 and 4 of Table 5 display results for all ages and for teens with no weights; that is, unweighted squares errors Standard estimates. are using computed correction White's for group wise heteroskedasticity, assuming that variances differ among states (Greene 2002). In comparison with the weighted estimates in Tables 3 and 4, the unweighted price coefficient is slightly larger for all ages and slightly smaller for teens. Both remain statistically significant. Thus, there is little evidence that has weighting With estimates, 23 Most 2000 an state important and are which dummies sometimes on the results. included, our misleading in weights is attributable inWyoming in 1990. of the variation to 450,000 year influence are equivalent estimates because to differences of serial in population, to "difference-in-difference" correlation which (Bertrand, ranges from 34,000,000 This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Duflo, and in California in Alcohol Prices and Traffic Fatalities Table for Endogeneity Tests 2b. Error Measurement and/or in Consumption |?-ratio | IV OLS Level) (Significance All ages All times All ages Weekend nights All ages Other times Ages 16-20 All times Ages 16-20 Weekend nights Ages 16-20 Other times Coefficient Consumption F-value Fatality Rate 697 10.7 1.13 0.99 14.4 16.8 (0.00) 3.1 1.08 0.99 12.4 (0.08) 9.5 1.11 0.91 12.1 11.7 12.9 (0.00) 12.6 0.97 1.29 (0.00) 9.2 8.9 1.4 1.02 0.86 (0.23) 5.0 4.3 13.8 0.85 (0.00) 5.3 1.41 6.3 2004). Columns 2 and 5 of Table 5 provide estimates corrected for first-order serial correlation (AR1).24 There is little effect on themagnitudes of the estimated coefficients. T-ratios are Mullainathan but smaller, mostly are There whose in dry are of = were on based unaffected. are variables control server 0.08, trends time the coefficients BAC counties, which variables, religion some estimated is largely coefficients insignificant when results variables (population the three and significant different dropping insignificant dropped of substantially with experimented and/or the pattern and training, two omitted. We of "wrong" consistently observations from sign We also each state, tourism). and were also often insignificant or of unexpected sign. As columns 3 and 6 of Table 5 indicate, omitting these variables with fatalities respect the magnitude reduces markedly to the price of alcohol the of to 0.3 falls estimated for adults The response. price and 0.2 for teens, and of elasticity the teen estimate is not significantly different from zero. Most of the rest of the coefficients display smaller changes in magnitude and statistical significance. An exception is keg registration, which becomes highly significant and should treated be to reduce is estimated with fatalities as they caution, on to depend appear results these 13%. Overall, by the exact suggest specification that point of estimates the regression. 5. Discussion There is strong fatalities. state Using and and/or in the ACCRA endogeneity price data for (OLS) estimators toward a finding of little or no effect of prices on alcohol, which biases conventional traffic error of measurement evidence federal tax rates as instrumental there variables, is strong in evidence most specifications that fatalities are in fact negatively and significantly related to the price of alcohol, ceteris Our paribus. that an indicate estimates point increase in the beer tax of 50 cents per six pack of reduce traffic fatalities by about 4.5%; this amounted to 1900 lives in the year 2000. Qualitatively similar results hold for the relationship between alcohol consumption and fatalities: beer would Estimates Are estimates based on the partial of instrumental reduced-form the effects of price variable estimates on are techniques of the price-fatality consumption and than larger those consumption OLS. consistent relationship on from fatalities? By with structural definition, the elasticity of fatalities with respect to the price of alcohol, Efp say, is equal to the product of the price consumption 24 Estimated elasticity, Ecp, and the consumption-fatality elasticity, Efc. Our basic rho is 0.46 for all ages and 0.12 for teens. This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions point estimates thus 698 J. Young and Agnieszka Bielinska-Kwapisz Douglas Table 3. Fatality Regressions for Total Population Alcohol All Right-hand Side Variable In (alcohol price) (All Ages) Price Alcohol Weekend Other All Times Times Nights Times -0.58 -0.69 -0.39 3.4 3.0 2.1 Ln (alcohol consumption) 1.08 1.13 0.045 0.040 0.022 VMTLIC 18-29 (%) Population 0.014 0.5 2.3 0.023 0.030 3.7 -0.045 -0.004 Catholic (%) -0.009 Mormon (%) -0.010 7.0 5.3 -0.041 -0.043 2.8 3.1 3.1 0.4 0.005 0.6 3.9 4.0 0.010 0.008 0.008 0.7 0.9 0.6 -0.009 -0.012 1.9 0.7 0.7 4.1 0.8 0.5 0.045 0.055 7.9 7.0 6.0 Population 65+ 0.024 0.026 0.024 Adjusted R2 1.4 -0.018 0.5 1.6 -0.021 Southern Baptist (%) (%) 0.3 0.006 5.1 0.9 2.1 1.8 -0.003 -0.013 0.010 1.5 0.038 1.7 1.9 -0.028 -0.021 -0.002 0.013 1.5 -0.003 3.8 -0.017 2.1 0.2 0.034 0.4 3.8 -0.008 -0.002 0.011 4.8 -0.046 0.009 1.8 0.005 2.8 -0.055 4.3 0.001 -0.011 2.2 training Tourism 0.010 2.6 0.027 (%) 0.003 0.029 0.5 Server 5.9 0.009 5.0 0.001 0.08 0.022 0.055 0.8 BAC - 2.2 2.5 -0.004 in dry counties (%) Population 0.010 5.6 0.037 3.1 Legal 0.017 5.4 -0.038 environment 1.11 11.7 9.5 0.051 7.2 Seat belt law 0.045 10.6 0.022 7.7 11.7 Other Times Nights 14.4 Income Consumption Weekend -0.015 1.0 1.0 0.7 0.94 0.91 0.92 0.93 0.94 0.93 State and year dummies are included in every equation. Estimation is by 2SLS using combined state plus federal excise taxes on beer, spirits, and wine, and for control states, the percentage excise taxes and/or markups on spirits and wine, as = applicable. Price or consumption is treated as endogenous. iV 869. Dependent variable: logit of fatality rate (absolute values of f-statistics are below parameter estimates). imply the price-consumption is elasticity ? Ecp = EfJEfp -0.58/1.13 This =-0.51. is within value the range of price elasticities for aggregate alcohol consumption estimated in previous work (Leung and 2003). Phelps 1993; Young and Bielinska-Kwapisz What do these estimates imply about the impact of alcohol taxes on traffic fatalities? The answer depends on the degree towhich alcohol taxes are shifted forward to retail prices and on how important taxes are as a share of retail prices. Young and Bielinska-Kwapisz (2002) found that spirits, beer, and wine However, taxes are excise overshifted: taxes are only Retail prices 11-18% rise of retail more than prices. Thus, one-for-one the 1991 with change an increase in federal in excise taxes. taxes, which doubled the beer tax from 16 cents per six pack of beer to 32 cents and increased the wine tax by 500%, increased retail prices by only about 6%. Based on a price-fatality elasticity of 0.58, the predicted decline in total fatalities is about 3.5%. This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Alcohol Prices and Traffic Fatalities Table 4. Fatality Regressions for Teens (Ages 16-20) Alcohol Side Variable Right-hand All Times Weekend In (alcohol price) Price Nights Alcohol Other Times -0.89 -0.35 -0.93 3.1 0.8 2.2 1.29 VMTLIC 0.065 0.023 7.5 4.3 0.031 0.015 Seat belt law -0.042 2.3 2.3 environment Legal 0.3 Population 1.2 BAC = 0.08 Server training -0.006 Catholic (%) -0.008 Mormon (%) -0.023 1.3 6.9 4.9 -0.009 Adjusted R2 -0.011 -0.023 -0.028 -0.014 0.022 1.7 0.8 3.0 2.3 1.2 -0.057 -0.046 -0.055 -0.071 -0.057 1.7 3.2 -0.012 -0.008 1.0 1.2 -0.000 -0.013 2.6 1.8 0.8 0.4 0.027 0.005 -0.006 0.8 0.6 0.4 -0.003 -0.014 2.7 1.6 0.9 -0.040 -0.015 -0.046 0.3 0.005 2.4 0.5 -0.016 0.004 1.4 -0.037 2.1 0.003 1.2 0.041 -0.003 1.0 0.2 0.023 -0.019 0.9 0.8 1.9 0.058 -0.127 Youth BAC 2.3 -0.022 1.1 0.059 registration 0.8 0.021 2.3 Keg 0.008 2.5 1.7 0.4 Southern Baptist (%) 0.015 0.0 4.0 4.0 0.041 0.052 0.078 0.033 1.8 4.5 0.010 -0.005 6.3 1.6 2.1 -0.002 in dry counties (%) 0.016 0.041 4.5 -0.019 1.41 1.02 4.3 9.4 Drinking age Other Times Nights 8.9 0.055 5.0 Consumption All Times Weekend Ln (alcohol consumption) Income 699 0.056 4.4 4.5 -0.034 -0.182 -0.039 0.8 4.8 1.6 -0.019 0.019 -0.091 0.5 0.013 0.006 2.5 0.026 -0.005 0.5 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.2 1.1 0.85 0.79 0.76 0.87 0.79 0.77 State and year dummies are included in every equation. Estimation is by 2SLS using combined state plus federal excise taxes on beer, spirits, and wine, and for control states, the percentage excise taxes and/or markups on spirits and wine, as = %69. applicable. Price or consumption is treated as endogenous. N Dependent variable: logit of fatality rate (absolute values of ?-statistics are below parameter estimates). These can results also be expressed as a tax-fatality Ignoring elasticity. the in the wine increase tax for simplicity, the implied elasticity of fatalities with respect to the beer tax is 0.06. This figure is about one than Evans, lower quarter Neville, and Graham's (1991) estimate of 0.08, and about one half of Ruhm's (1996, table 2) estimate of 0.11. Chaloupka, Saffer, and Grossman (1993, p. 181) estimated that doubling the federal beer tax would have reduced fatalities by 3.9%, similar to the finding in this paper. The estimated tax elasticity for teen fatalities is about half again as large (0.09), because the teen price elasticity of fatalities is estimated to be that much larger (Tables 2 and 4). This value is substantially smaller than some previous estimates. For example, Ruhm's (1996, table 4) tax elasticity for 18- to 20-year-olds is twice as high (0.17-0.21), and Chaloupka, Saffer, and Grossman (1993, p. 181) report that doubling the federal beer tax would reduce fatalities among 18- to 20-year-olds by 11.8%, implying an even larger tax elasticity of 0.21. This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 700 J. Young and Agnieszka Bielinska-Kwapisz Douglas Table 5. Robustness Checks All Ages Teens AR1 Side Variable Right-hand In (alcohol price) -0.70 Income VMTLIC -0.77 environment Legal -0.84 -0.74 2.2 2.5 1.8 0.036 0.026 0.041 0.048 0.041 8.2 4.2 6.5 4.6 8.7 0.020 0.007 0.030 0.028 0.021 0.038 7.9 4.0 2.7 6.8 -0.029 -0.026 1.4 0.053 5.2 9.8 -0.031 -0.023 2.5 2.3 2.0 -0.008 -0.008 -0.004 1.3 0.001 BAC = 0.08 Catholic Mormon (%) Drinking age 1.7 1.0 1.0 -0.004 0.7 0.027 1.1 1.6 0.9 0.008 0.9 0.0 0.3 0.005 0.010 0.006 2.0 0.0 2.4 -0.008 -0.013 2.0 1.0 -0.010 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.058 0.056 0.064 6.9 5.4 6.4 5.1 0.027 0.029 0.034 3.2 1.5 0.018 -0.018 0.7 -0.002 0.82 0.93 1.6 -0.034 -0.130 0.9 5.5 -0.003 0.9 0.8 0.2 0.78 0.75 0.86 -0.018 0.92 -0.013 -0.020 1.9 Youth BAC -0.001 0.1 -0.059 registration Adjusted R2 -0.013 0.041 0.2 Dependent 1.3 -0.005 0.000 (%) variable: -0.008 0.8 1.4 Keg 1.5 -0.010 0.038 2.4 (%) -0.013 0.2 -0.017 0.044 1.3 0.022 1.0 Tourism 0.8 0.013 -0.023 Southern Baptist (%) Population 65+ 0.9 0.3 -0.005 (%) -0.017 0.001 1.0 training -0.19 0.062 8.8 1.8 Server 12.7 -0.030 in dry counties (%) Population -0.31 Omit Some Xs Corrected 2.8 5.2 Seat belt law AR1 Unweighted 3.8 0.054 18-29 (%) Population Omit Some Xs Corrected Unweighted logit of fatality rate (absolute values of ?-statistics below parameter estimates). these more modest in this study should be regarded with caution, however. One reason is that they still seem too large. Only a minority of fatalities involve alcohol; currently the proportion is 30-40%. Thus, a 1% increase in per capita alcohol consumption could fatalities increase by more than twice that increase fatalities by 1.13% only if alcohol-involved Even amount. Second, measures is responsive nights 25 Dee are the pattern of estimated price and consumption effects across the different fatality Teen counterintuitive. sometimes to the price of apparently less (1999) and Dee estimates obtained and Evans alcohol than responsive are to fatalities fatalities alcohol on at other consumption weekend times, nights and than total fatalities (2001) obtain similar results. This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions are less apparently fatalities at on weekend other times.25 701 Alcohol Prices and Traffic Fatalities In part, Moore these are variables are or be a number certain ing citizen rent effects. is of on point infrequent in state changes of price modest are effects obtained effects for DUI, excise taxes'" to what sensitive some when of approach as the resulting taxes, alcohol and (Cook other the control insignificant effects here, estimators by enforcement of is not confined to this estimates a "reduced are biased and inconsistent study. Whether form" if taxes took by are stricter legislating and mobiliz efforts, to overstate likely and fatalities, simultaneously taxes, educational instead or states increasing and are taxes that attitudes underlying to curb intended to the extent abuse?say up stepping policy" is done measures policy reflect may policies In particular, estimated "endogenous other and unmeasured with to reduce the of taxes alcohol variables. fronts penalties problem a "structural" that correlated groups?then The and estimates more much instrumental improper and more "small excluded. concern on directly with included, related be action In addition, alcohol, A toward reflect may p. 421). variables thus results 2001, their deter actual a researcher takes regressing fatalities endogenous. Indeed, all of the most frequently cited estimates of the impact of alcohol taxes rely on the assumption that taxes are exogenous. all of Thus, these studies may be biased, and a more accurate assessment will not be possible until the determinants of policy are more fully understood and estimation procedures are modified accordingly. This study has substantially resolved the discrepancy between estimates on based propriate tax and price as exogenous Tax Coefficients Table Al. but data, it remains to be seen whether the tax data Dependent Real Real Side Variable beer Variable wine Consumption tax excise tax excise -0.01 spirits excise tax Spirits excise tax (%) (%) 2.98 0.0027 excise tax (%) 0.0053 -5.6 4.5 0.001 -0.0004 -0.0007 0.7 Wine markup (%) Adjusted R2 1.75 -0.005 1.6 Wine 0.0041 0.0014 0.6 Spirits markup Log of Ethanol Price 3.4 1.1 Real ap from First-stage Regressions Log of Ethanol Right-hand are themselves variables. -0.0008 0.0016 1.2 0.00064 1.9 0.0034 2.7 -0.0002 2.3 0.45 0.98 0.89 Absolute values of ?-statistics below parameter estimates. Each equation also includes all of the right-hand variables from the structural fatality equations (see Table 3). This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions side exogenous 702 Douglas J. Young and Agnieszka Bielinska-Kwapisz References American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association 1982-2000. ACCRA cost of living index, quarterly (ACCRA). reports. Louisville, KY: ACCRA. and John Pepper. 2001. Slippery when wet: The effects of local Baughman, Reagan, Michael Conlin, Stacy Dickert-Conlin, alcohol access laws on highway safety. Journal of Health Economics 20:1089-196. Beard, T. Randolph, application Paula A. Gant, and Richard P. Saba. 1997. Border-crossing to alcohol. Southern Economic Journal 641:293-306. Bertrand, Marianne, Esther Duflo, estimates? Quarterly Journal and Sendhil Mullainathan. 2004. How sales, tax avoidance, much should we and state tax policies: An trust difference-in-differences 119(1):249?75. of Economics Besley, Timothy J., and Harvey S. Rosen. 1999. Sales taxes and prices: An empirical analysis. National Tax Journal June: 157-78. 1990. Churches and church membership Bradley, Martin B., Norman M. Green, Jr., Dale E. Jones, Mac Lynn, and Lou McNeil. in the United States 1990. Atlanta: Glemnary Research Center. Brown, Robert, R. Todd Jewell, and Jerell Richer. Journal 1996. Endogenous alcohol prohibition and drunk driving. Southern Economic 62:1043-53. 1993. Alcohol control policies and motor-vehicle fatalities. Journal of Legal Chaloupka, F. J., H. Saffer, and M. Grossman. Studies 22(1): 161-86. Cook, Phillip J. 1981. The effect of liquor taxes on drinking, cirrhosis, and auto fatalities. InAlcohol and public policy: Beyond the shadow of prohibition, edited by M. H. Moore and D. R. Gerstein. Washington, DC: National Academy Press, pp. 255-85. J. Moore. 2001. Environment and persistence in youthful drinking patterns. In Risky behavior Cook, Philip J., and Michael among youths, edited by Jonathon Gruber. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 375-437. 1989. Testing for consistency using artificial regressions. Russell, and James G. MacKinnon. 5:363-84. Davidson, and James G. MacKinnon. Davidson, Russell, Press. 1993. Estimation and inference in econometrics. Econometric Theory New York: Oxford University S. 1999. State alcohol policies, teen drinking, and traffic fatalities. Journal of Public Economics 72:289-315. S., and William N. Evans. 2001. Teens and traffic safety. In Risky behavior among youths, edited by Jonathon Gruber. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 121-65. Dee, Thomas Dee, Thomas DC: DISCUS. Spirits Council of the U.S. (DISCUS). 2000. History of beverage alcohol tax changes. Washington, Daniel. 2003. Evaluating the effectiveness of policies related to drunk driving. Journal of Policy Analysis and 22:249-74. Management Distilled Eisenberg, Evans, W. N., D. Neville, and J. Graham. Risk Analysis 11:279-89. Greene, William H. Software, Greene, William Inc. LIMDEP version deterrence 8.0 econometric of drunk driving: Evaluation modeling guide. Volume of recent American 2. Plainview, NY: policies. Econometric H. 2003. Econometric Grossman, Michael, Monitoring 2002. 1991. General analysis. 5th edition. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Frank J. Chaloupka, and Ismail Sirtalan. 1998. An empirical analysis of alcohol addiction: Results the Future panels. Economic Inquiry 36:39-48. from the 2002. Get high and get stupid: The effect of alcohol and marijuana Grossman, Michael, Robert Kaestner, and Sara Markowitz. use on teen sexual behavior. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 9216. of Gruber, Jonathon. 2001. Introduction. In Risky behavior among youths, edited by Jonathon Gruber. Chicago: University Chicago Press, pp. 1-28. Gruenewald, P. J.,W. R. Ponicki, and H. D. Holder. 1993. The relationship of outlet densities to alcohol consumption: series cross-sectional 17:38-47. analysis. Alcoholism: Clinical and Experimental Research Kenkel, Donald S. 1993. Drinking, driving and deterrence: The effectiveness Law and Economics 36:861-76. and social costs of alternative policies. A time Journal of Jeffrey D., and John R. Moran. 2003. Can policy changes be treated as natural experiments? Evidence from state excise taxes. Working Paper, Department of Economics, Syracuse University. Leung, S. F., and C. E. Phelps. 1993. "My kingdom for a drink ... ?": A review of estimates of the price sensitivity of demand for alcoholic beverages. In Economics and the prevention of alcohol-related problems: Proceedings of a workshop on Kubik, economic and socioeconomic issues in the prevention of alcohol-related problems, October 10-11,1991, edited by M. E. and G. Bloss. Bethesda, MD: NIAAA Research Monograph No. 25:1-31. 1995. The demand for alcohol: The differential response to Manning, Willard G., Linda Blumberg, and Lawrence H. Moulton. 14:123-48. price. Journal of Health Economics Hilton Sara. 2000. The price of alcohol, wife abuse, and husband abuse. Southern Economic S., P. Chatterji, R. Kaestner, and D. Dave. 2002. Substance use and suicidal behaviors Working Paper No. 8810. Markowitz, Journal Markowitz, among young adults. NBER Mast, Brent D., Bruce L. Benson, Economic Journal 66:214-49. and David W. Rasmussen. 1999. Beer taxation and alcohol-related This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 67:279-303. fatalities. Southern Alcohol Prices and Traffic Fatalities J. P. Nelson, 1997. Economic Economics and demographic in U.S. alcohol demand: A growth accounting analysis. Empirical 22:83-102. J. P. 2003. Advertising bans, monopoly, 22:1-25. of Industrial Organization Nelson, factors 703 and alcohol demand: Testing for substitution effects using state panel data. Review T. M., G. D. Williams, H. Yi, A. K. Hoy, F. S. Stinson, and M. C. Dufour. 2002. NHTSA surveillance report #59: state, and regional trends, 1970-99. Rockville, MD: National Apparent per capita alcohol consumption: National, Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism, Division of Biometry and Epidemiology. Quinn, Bernard, Herman Anderson, Martin Bradley, Paul Goetting, and Peggy Shriver. 1980. Churches and church membership in the United States 1980. Atlanta: Glenmary Research Center. Nephew, 15:435-54. Ruhm, C. 1996. Alcohol policies and highway vehicle fatalities. Journal of Health Economics 1994. Effects of prices, civil and criminal sanctions, and law enforcement Sloan, F. A., B. A. Reilly, and C. M. Schenzler. alcohol-related mortality. Journal of Studies on Alcohol July: 454-65. on of the Census. Tourism data from US Bureau of Economic Analysis. Available http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/ regional/gsp/. Accessed 24 October 2005. School of Public Health. Wagenaar, Alexander C. Alcohol Epidemiology Program, University of Minnesota, 2002. Alcohol taxes and beverage prices. National Tax Journal LV:57-73. Young, D. J., and A. Bielinska-Kwapisz. U.S. Bureau Young, D. J., and A. Bielinska-Kwapisz. Studies on Alcohol 64:235-238. Young, D. J., and T. W. 20:107-26. Likens. 2003. Alcohol 2000. Alcohol consumption, regulation beverage and auto fatalities. prices, and measurement International Review This content downloaded from 153.90.170.56 on Tue, 10 Jun 2014 13:52:42 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions error. Journal of Law and Economics of