STORE QUALITY IMAGE AND THE ‘RATIONAL INATTENTION HYPOTHESIS’:

advertisement
STORE QUALITY IMAGE AND THE ‘RATIONAL INATTENTION HYPOTHESIS’:
AN EMPIRICAL STUDY OF THE DRIVERS OF $9 AND 9¢ PRICE-ENDINGS
AMONG INTERNET-BASED SELLERS
Mark Bergen
Professor, Marketing and Logistics Management
Robert J. Kauffman
Director, MIS Research Center and
Professor and Chair, Information and Decision Sciences
Dongwon Lee
Doctoral Candidate, Information and Decision Sciences
Carlson School of Management
University of Minnesota
E-mail: {mbergen, rkauffman, dlee}@csom.umn.edu
Last revised: September 20, 2004
Note: This paper was accepted for presentation in the 2004 INFORMS Conference on
Information Systems and Technology, Denver, Colorado, October 23-24, 2004.
ABSTRACT
Prior research shows that 9¢, 99¢, $9 and $99 in retail prices occur far more than expected. We
investigate the extent to which these “‘9’ price-endings” occur in Internet-based selling, and
explore what drives the observed variations. In particular, we explore theories based on
customer perceptions of store quality image and rational inattention to price-endings. To
accomplish this, we specify and test a discrete choice model for price-endings using more than
1.9 million daily observations on multiple categories of products sold by hundreds of Internetbased retailers. Our results show that a firm’s online reputation, its average price in a product
category, the relative price levels within a product category, and the total number of digits in the
product’s price have significant effects on the chosen price-endings with respect to different
product categories. The results support an image theory of store quality, and suggest other
behavioral and operations theories to explore in future work. We obtain mixed support for the
theory of rational inattention. We also explore the role of information technology (IT) in firm
price-setting, and offer new insights for marketers who wish to optimize price-setting decisions
in the competitive online environment of Internet retailing.
KEYWORDS: E-commerce, economic analysis, empirical research, Internet-based selling,
online reputation, price-endings, rational inattention, seemingly unrelated regression, strategic
pricing, technology impacts, threshold pricing.
Acknowledgments. The authors wish to thank the anonymous reviewers for the 2004
INFORMS Conference on Information Systems and Technology, as well as co-chairs, Chris
Forman, Hemant Bhargava and D. J. Wu, for their helpful input on an earlier version of this
paper.
1
INTRODUCTION
In the United States, sellers tend to choose the rightmost digits of a price so that it falls just
below a round number (Friedman, 1967; Schindler and Kirby, 1997; Twedt, 1965). These last
digits commonly are called “9” price-endings, and reflect the common use of 9¢, 99¢, $9 and
$99 as in $19.99 or $199 (Schindler and Kibarian, 2001). The use of “9”-endings has also
received considerable attention in public discussions in several European countries also, as they
convert from local currencies to the Euro (Folkertsma, et al., 2002). In addition to a tendency to
use “9”-ending prices, several surveys on price-endings report that firms use 0¢, 5¢ and 9¢ in
posted prices more than 74% of the time—and even up to 99% of the time (Stiving and Winer,
1997). According to Blinder, et al. (1998, p. 26), practitioners’ belief in these kinds of price
points “… is part of the folklore of pricing…” In an interview study of 200 large U.S. firms,
they find that 88% of the firms in the retail industry and 47% of the firms in non-retail industries
report substantial importance of these kinds of price points in their pricing decisions.1
This study investigates the extent to which threshold pricing occurs in Internet-based
selling.2 With the new retailing activities on the Internet, we expect to see changes that reflect
different technological underpinnings of the firm’s production process for prices (Dutta, et al.,
2003). Not only do the new technologies far surpass the capabilities that are available in
traditional bricks-and-mortar stores to adjust their own prices (Kauffman and Lee, 2004) and
track competitors’ prices (Kauffman and Wood, 2004), they provide the basis for consumers to
o
1
See Shapiro (1968) and Monroe (1990) for a review of earlier literature, and Anderson and Simester
(2003) for a review of more recent literature in Marketing.
2
This is also referred to as odd pricing (Monroe, 2003), psychological pricing (Lambert, 1975),
tantalizing pricing (Konieczny and Skrzypacz, 2003), and just-below-the-round-number-pricing
(Schindler, 1984), and psychological price points and threshold pricing (Kashyap 1995) in Marketing and
Economics.
2
make to-the-cent price comparisons (Bakos, 1998). The reduction in search costs for attractive
prices and bargains is accompanied by opportunities for sellers to implement algorithmic price
discrimination approaches, to segment customers based on customer relationship management
systems information and new data mining techniques. It is natural, then, that Internet-based
sellers will create new ways to set prices in e-commerce. With these changes of the Internetbased sellers’ capabilities and price setting strategies in mind, we propose the following research
questions:
□
What empirical regularities can be observed for firm-selected price-endings in Internetbased selling? Do they differ by product category? By price level?
□
What variables and drivers can explain the observed empirical regularities and variations
in price-endings in Internet-based selling? How is Internet-based selling different from
traditional bricks-and-mortar retailing? What theories help us to identify the drivers?
□
What kind of empirical model will enable us to test hypotheses about the drivers of
threshold pricing in the applied setting that we have chosen?
□
What new insights do the results provide to enable effective strategic pricing choices?
We view this research as an exploratory effort designed to provide an initial reading on one
aspect of strategic pricing on the Internet. We next describe our new e-commerce price-endings
data set and examine some first order, easy-to-see empirical regularities for product and category
price-endings. We compare them with empirical regularities for price-endings in traditional
bricks-and-mortar retailing, based on the existing literature. In the third section, we explore what
drives the observed variation in price-endings. We focus on two theories based: customer
perceptions of store quality image and rational inattention to price endings. This permits us to
lay out a theoretical model for price-ending strategies for e-commerce retailing and related
3
hypotheses. To check out the robustness of the theory, we specify and test a related empirical
binary choice model, a seemingly unrelated bivariate probit model that uses more than 1.9
million daily price observations in 2003 and 2004 for multiple categories of products. Finally,
we conclude with an interpretation of our empirical findings about alternate price-ending theories
for online selling in light of the underlying changes created by the new technologies of the
Internet. We also discuss several limitations of our findings.
EMPIRICAL REGULARITIES FOR THRESHOLD PRICE-ENDINGS ON THE NET
Previous research has focused on prices in print media and grocery scanner data (e.g., Stiving
and Winer, 1997 and Bergen, et al., 2003). We use price data collected from the Internet to
establish some observed empirical regularities of price-setting in Internet-based selling.
A New Internet-Based Selling Price-Ending Data Set
We obtained price-related data from BizRate.com (www.bizrate.com), a popular price
comparison site. We used a price information gathering agent, a data mining software tool
which automatically obtains information for multiple product categories and products sold by
Internet-based retailers, based on preset criteria. The selected product categories provide a
setting where the products in the price comparison samples are all identical. From a list of
products available at price comparison sites, we generated a large sample of unique product IDs
using stratified proportionate random sampling (Wooldridge, 2002). For each product, our tool
developed a panel of selling prices that cover products and stores over time, and qualitative
information (e.g., consumers’ ratings of stores, number of reviews), also collected from
BizRate.com.
Sometimes the Internet-based sellers’ (especially small firms) Web sites were inaccessible or
4
the required price information was not available. So, some data are missing in our original data
set. Taking this into account, we were careful to remove time-series data on products whenever
there was a total of 10% missing data. We examined if the prices the day before and the day
after were the same as on the middle day when a data point was missing. The software agent
filled in the price for the day with the missing data, so our time-series lengths are all identical.
Our data consist of 366 daily observations of retail prices in 10 different product categories
(CDs, DVDs, video games, notebooks, PDAs, software, digital cameras/camcorders, DVD
players, PC monitors, and hard drives) and 477 products sold by 317 Internet-based retailers,
covering one year from March 26, 2003 to March 25, 2004. Table 1 presents descriptive
statistics for our data set.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics for the Internet-Based Sellers’ Price-Ending Data Set
CATEGORY
Music CDs
Movie DVDs
Video Games
Software
PDAs
Hard Drives
DVD Players
PC Monitors
Digital Cameras
Notebook PCs
Total
DATA
POINTS
172,752
256,566
179,340
283,650
126,636
197,640
180,438
262,788
208,986
66,426
1,935,042
PRODUCT STORE
COUNT COUNT
46
49
50
48
45
47
49
51
46
46
477
MEAN
PRICE
15
$12.90
20
$28.27
40
$33.36
87
$306.26
96
$346.02
77
$358.63
110
$385.80
91
$703.38
150
$797.60
47 $1,694.58
317
$387.96
STD.
DEV.
MIN.
PRICE
MAX.
PRICE
$3.42
$5.49
$35.48
$27.10
$5.58 $134.99
$12.57
$6.99
$57.89
$416.27
$5.50 $5,000.00
$191.54 $39.99 $956.95
$587.57 $38.57 $3,911.95
$275.25 $57.99 $2,300.00
$680.87 $85.78 $3,199.99
$781.24 $165.99 $6,478.00
$474.17 $699.00 $3,447.00
$582.80
$5.49 $6,478.00
Note: Internet retailers have many different categories of products (e.g., Amazon.com sells books, CDs,
DVDs, computer products and electronics), so the sum of the number of stores in each product category is
not consistent with the total number of stores in all product categories.
The price range of all the product categories is $5.49 to $6,478.00, and the mean values of
different categories vary from $12.90 to $1,694.58. Online retail prices are like those consumers
pay at the cash register, so if a product is on sale, our price data reflect the sale price as well.
Previous price-ending studies mostly focus on 9¢ price-endings because most prices in retail
5
grocery stores are less than $10.00. This may occur with pricier items too, where cents are less
often used in pricing (Bergen et al., 2003). So, we examine both 9¢ and $9 price-endings.
Price-Endings in Cents
As illustrated in Figure 1, 0¢, 5¢, and 9¢ price-endings are over-represented, with 31.9% for
9¢, 26.4% for 0¢, and 19.4% for 5¢, followed by 8.3% for 8¢. The other endings—1¢, 2¢, 3¢, 4¢,
6¢, and 7¢—are under-represented; they account for only 14.3%. The round amounts of 0¢ and
5¢ are highly accessible in memory (Baird et al., 1970); high cognitive accessibility may explain
their large proportions. These results are consistent with the patterns observed by Schindler and
Kirby (1997), who used U.S. print advertisement price data.
Figure 1. Frequency Distribution of Prices’ Last Digit in Cents: All Categories
Distribution of Last Digit in Cents (All Categories)
Percentage of Price Ending
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Price Ending in Cents
Table 2 shows frequency distributions for the last digit of the price data for each product
category. The table shows variation by product category, but 0¢, 5¢, and 9¢ endings are most
common. In some categories, such as music CDs, movie DVDs and video games, just a few
prices end with 0¢; instead, more prices end with 8¢ and 9¢. The price levels of these categories
tend to be much lower than those of other electronics products, based on the mean prices of CDs,
DVDs and video games at $12.90, $28.87 and $33.36, respectively, that we observed.
Internet-based retailers appear to use more 8¢ or 9¢ price-endings for lower-priced products.
6
To get a more complete picture of the empirical regularities associated with Internet pricing, we
also look at the price-endings by price level as a function of the number of price digits. As the
number of the digits increases, the proportions of 8¢ and 9¢ price-endings decrease, while the
proportion of 0¢-endings increases, as shown in Table 2. More than 60% of prices less than
$100 end with 8¢ or 9¢, whereas fewer than 10% end with 0¢. In contrast, when a product is
priced above $100, Internet retailers appear to use 0¢ price-endings almost 40% of the time—
relatively more than even the 9¢ price-endings. These results match findings in studies by
Heeler and Nguyen (2001) and Bock Interactive (2001) which showed that about 26% of
products sold at the Yahoo! Store had prices ending with 9¢ and $9, while 37% of the products
had 0¢ price-endings.
Table 2. Price-Endings in Cents by Product Category, Price Level for Last Digit in Price
DATA
0¢
1¢
CATEGORY
Music CDs
Movie DVDs
Video Games
Software
PDAs
Hard Drives
DVD Players
PC Monitors
Digital Cameras
Notebook PCs
All Products
POINTS
172,752
256,566
179,340
283,650
126,636
197,640
180,438
262,788
208,986
66,426
1,935,042
1.7%
3.3%
5.6%
36.1%
40.4%
28.7%
32.5%
33.8%
43.1%
52.2%
26.0%
PRICE LEVEL
Price (P) < 10
10 ≤ P < 100
100 ≤ P < 1,000
P > 1,000
P ≤ 387.96
P > 387.96
44,834
683,870
1,021,257
185,081
1,333,704
601,338
2.2% 1.25%
9.7% 2.0%
34.8% 2.0%
43.1% 1.1%
20.2% 2.0%
38.8% 1.8%
2¢
LAST DIGIT IN CENTS (%)
3¢
4¢
5¢
6¢
1.6% 1.3% 1.9% 2.2%
2.8% 3.2% 3.6% 5.1%
1.4% 4.7% 1.4% 1.3%
2.1% 1.4% 2.0% 2.6%
1.9% 0.7% 1.5% 2.7%
3.3% 2.9% 2.6% 3.2%
0.2% 0.8% 0.4% 3.4%
2.6% 2.9% 2.2% 2.7%
1.0% 0.55% 0.5% 2.1%
1.0% 1.45% 0.5% 0.6%
1.9% 2.1% 1.8% 2.85%
2.7%
2.9%
1.6%
1.8%
2.4%
1.5%
2.2%
2.3%
1.6%
1.5%
2.1%
1.2%
3.7%
3.0%
2.9%
1.9%
3.2%
2.1%
7¢
8¢
9¢
4.9%
11.1%
17.7%
29.5%
21.8%
24.4%
16.5%
27.7%
16.4%
12.3%
19.4%
3.6%
5.3%
2.1%
1.9%
1.7%
3.3%
3.4%
2.9%
1.5%
1.6%
2.9%
1.6% 31.1% 50.1%
3.4% 16.4% 45.8%
2.9% 5.1% 57.7%
2.5% 4.2% 17.7%
1.3% 3.6% 24.3%
3.2% 3.0% 25.5%
6.4% 2.8% 33.6%
2.7% 5.9% 16.6%
1.5% 3.6% 29.8%
1.0% 5.6% 23.9%
2.8% 8.3% 31.9%
10.1%
14.3%
22.9%
20.5%
18.7%
20.9%
4.2%
3.4%
2.7%
1.7%
3.2%
2.1%
4.2% 21.1% 48.3%
2.6% 14.3% 45.5%
3.0% 4.5% 24.0%
2.3% 4.5% 21.5%
2.9% 10.3% 35.0%
2.6% 4.0% 25.0%
Next, we consider the frequency distribution of the last two digits in cents from our price
data. Figure 2 shows the results for all the categories combined. The 00¢, 95¢ and 99¢ price-
7
endings are over-represented with 26.3% for 99¢, 21.2% for 00¢, and 16.0% for 95¢, followed
by 4.2% for 98¢. The other endings are under-represented, accounting for only 32.3%. These
results are somewhat different from those obtained by Schindler (2001), who also surveyed the
prices of multiple products at a variety of stores: 56.8% ended with 99¢, 6.3% with 97¢, 4.8%
with 49¢, 4.3% with 98¢, and 3.3% with 00¢. Based on these observations, we find that the
price-ending strategies of Internet-based sellers and traditional bricks-and-mortar stores may be
different.
Figure 2. Frequency Distribution of Last Two Digits of Prices in Cents: All Categories
Distribution of Last 2 Digits in Cents (All Categories)
Percentage of Price Ending
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Price Ending in Cents
Similar patterns emerge for prices in individual product categories, as reported in Table 3.
Except for three categories—CDs, DVDs and video games—the 00¢, 95¢ and 99¢-endings occur
most frequently. Overall we find that 99¢ price endings are more common for lower-priced
product categories, including CDs at 34.4%, DVDs at 31.4%, and video games at 52.6% of the
total. Among higher-priced products though, 00¢ price-endings are more often observed, with
notebook PCs at 50.6%, digital cameras and camcorders at 39.9%, and PDAs at 36.3% of the
total.
8
Table 3. Top 10 Highest Frequencies of Last Two Digits of Prices in Cents
VIDEO
GAME
CD
DVD
AVG. PRICE
$12.90
$28.87
$33.26 $306.26 $346.02 $358.63 $385.80
99¢
34.4%
98¢
15.9%
48¢
7.3%
49¢
4.4%
89¢
3.2%
18¢
2.6%
19¢
2.0%
78¢
1.5%
96¢
1.4%
65¢
1.3%
99¢
31.4%
98¢
11.1%
95¢
6.3%
49¢
3.5%
39¢
1.9%
24¢
1.6%
48¢
1.6%
19¢
1.5%
29¢
1.5%
79¢
1.5%
99¢
52.6%
95¢
13.8%
88¢
3.6%
82¢
3.5%
97¢
2.3%
50¢
2.0%
49¢
1.6%
96¢
1.4%
05¢
1.1%
45¢
1.1%
RANK
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
SW
00¢
31.8%
95¢
26.3%
99¢
15.1%
98¢
1.8%
90¢
1.0%
50¢
1.0%
97¢
0.9%
94¢
0.9%
49¢
0.8%
75¢
0.7%
PDA
HARD
DVD
PC
DRIVE PLAYER MONITOR
CATEGORY
00¢
36.3%
99¢
22.1%
95¢
18.2%
98¢
1.7%
85¢
1.5%
90¢
1.5%
88¢
1.3%
94¢
1.0%
80¢
1.0%
41¢
0.7%
00¢
24.1%
99¢
21.6%
95¢
20.6%
50¢
1.3%
89¢
1.1%
49¢
0.8%
60¢
0.7%
76¢
0.7%
30¢
0.6%
14¢
0.6%
99¢
31.8%
00¢
23.8%
95¢
14.8%
90¢
6.5%
97¢
5.3%
96¢
2.7%
88¢
1.8%
94¢
1.8%
50¢
1.5%
44¢
1.0%
DIGITAL
CAMERA
NOTEBOOK
PC
TOTAL
$703.38
$797.60
$1,694.58
$387.96
00¢
30.8%
95¢
24.2%
99¢
13.2%
98¢
2.8%
75¢
1.0%
79¢
0.9%
88¢
0.9%
50¢
0.8%
22¢
0.6%
25¢
0.6%
00¢
39.9%
99¢
28.1%
95¢
13.8%
90¢
1.9%
98¢
1.6%
85¢
1.4%
94¢
1.1%
49¢
0.9%
88¢
0.9%
96¢
0.8%
00¢
50.6%
99¢
22.5%
95¢
11.5%
98¢
3.5%
96¢
1.1%
90¢
1.1%
88¢
0.6%
02¢
0.6%
48¢
0.5%
84¢
0.5%
99¢
26.3%
00¢
21.2%
95¢
16.0%
98¢
4.2%
49¢
1.5%
90¢
1.3%
97¢
1.2%
88¢
1.1%
48¢
1.0%
96¢
0.9%
Price-Endings in Dollars
We also consider the distribution of the price-endings in dollars for all the product categories.
As illustrated in Figure 3, $9 price-endings are over-represented at 37.1%, followed by $4 at
9.9% and $5 with 9.3%. So, almost four times more prices end in $9 than with the next most
frequent price-ending, $4. Only 5.6% of prices end with $0, despite the high cognitive
accessibility of this round amount. This is similar to what Bergen, et al. (2003) found in
supermarkets.
In Table 4, we present the frequency distributions of the last digit of price by product
category. As expected, $9 price-endings are most common in almost all categories. In some
categories (e.g., CDs and DVDs), $3, $4 and $5 price-endings are common. Why? Because
prices of these product categories are often between $13 and $16, $9 price-endings don’t make
sense. In some high-priced categories, 60% of all prices end with $9, including PCs at 72.7%
9
and digital cameras at 60.1%. Also, for high-priced products whose prices are greater than the
mean (i.e., $387.96) of all the product categories, we observed price-endings with $9 more than
50% of the time.
Figure 3. Frequency Distribution of Last Digit in Dollars for Prices: All Categories
Distribution of Last Digit in Dollars (All Categories)
40
Percentage of Price Ending
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Price Ending in Dollars
Table 4. Price-Endings in Dollars by Product Category
DATA
POINTS
CATEGORY
Music CD
172,752
Movie DVD
256,566
Video Game
179,340
Software
283,650
PDA
126,636
Hard Drive
197,640
DVD Player
180,438
PC Monitor
262,788
Digit. Camera
208,986
Notebook PC
66,426
1,935,042
All Products
PRICE LEVEL
Price(P) < $10
44,834
683,870
$10≤ P < $100
$100≤P<$1000 1,021,257
P > $1000
185,081
1,333,704
P ≤ 387.96
601,338
P > 387.96
$0
5.4%
10.7%
2.1%
5.9%
4.9%
6.8%
2.8%
8.0%
2.4%
2.0%
5.6%
$1
9.0%
11.9%
1.2%
4.6%
3.8%
7.8%
1.3%
5.3%
1.9%
2.4%
5.4%
0.0%
6.5%
5.4%
4.7%
6.1%
4.5%
0.0%
8.1%
3.9%
4.8%
6.3%
3.4%
LAST DIGIT OF PRICES IN DOLLARS (%)
$2
$3
$4
$5
$6
10.9% 16.7% 22.2% 12.3% 5.7%
10.2%
9.5% 14.0% 12.2% 7.7%
2.4%
2.2%
6.8%
6.0% 7.3%
5.9%
5.4%
8.4% 10.3% 6.2%
3.9%
4.6%
8.3%
7.6% 3.3%
7.9%
8.0%
9.3%
9.9% 8.1%
3.4%
4.5%
8.2%
8.4% 2.7%
7.0%
7.1%
8.3%
9.2% 6.8%
2.3%
2.5%
6.8%
7.7% 4.1%
3.3%
1.6%
4.5%
5.0% 1.5%
6.1%
6.6%
9.9%
9.3% 5.8%
0.0%
8.3%
5.2%
4.2%
7.1%
3.9%
0.0%
9.4%
5.5%
4.2%
7.7%
4.0%
0.0%
14.3%
8.2%
5.7%
11.3%
6.9%
3.8%
10.5%
9.1%
7.5%
9.6%
8.6%
9.2%
6.8%
5.4%
4.0%
6.5%
4.5%
$7
4.6%
7.4%
10.7%
7.5%
5.9%
8.7%
5.3%
5.9%
4.2%
3.5%
6.7%
$8
3.7%
4.7%
10.7%
9.2%
7.7%
8.9%
7.3%
7.9%
8.0%
3.3%
7.5%
$9
9.5%
11.6%
50.5%
36.6%
50.1%
24.6%
56.0%
34.6%
60.1%
72.7%
37.1%
16.1% 14.8%
7.2%
6.3%
6.5%
8.2%
3.9%
5.9%
7.5%
7.7%
5.0%
6.9%
56.1%
22.6%
42.7%
55.1%
30.2%
52.4%
We conjecture that Internet retailers use more $9 price-endings for high-priced products. As
the number of the digits increases, the proportion of $9 price-endings also increases, although
products less than $10 show a high proportion of $9 price endings. (See Table 4.) This occurs
10
because prices in our data are at least $5. So, it is appropriate to ignore these observations of $9
price-endings. A better data set would track prices down to $1, which would affect the results.
We also analyze the frequency distribution of the last two digits in dollars. Figure 4 shows
results for all categories combined. Most prices have “9” price-endings, such as $99, $89, or $09.
But more prices end with $99 than any other “9” price-endings, and more than 10% end with $99.
Figure 4. Frequency Distribution of Last Two Digits of Prices in Dollars
Distribution of Last 2 Digits in Dollars
(Without 3 Categories)
Distribution of Last 2 Digits in Dollars
(All Categories)
16.0
Percentage of Price Ending
Percentage of Price Ending
12
10
8
6
4
2
14.0
12.0
10.0
8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Price Ending in Dollars
Price Ending in Dollars
Table 5. Top 10 Highest Frequencies of the Last Two Digits of Prices in Dollars
RANK
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
CD
$14
21.2%
$13
15.8%
$15
11.4%
$12
9.8%
$11
8.0%
$09
6.9%
$10
5.1%
$16
3.8%
$07
2.8%
$19
2.6%
DVD
$15
8.9%
$14
7.7%
$11
6.4%
$10
6.1%
$13
5.3%
$22
5.1%
$16
4.5%
$09
4.2%
$19
3.8%
$12
3.7%
VIDEO
GAME
$19
15.8%
$49
15.6%
$29
12.6%
$39
4.8%
$45
4.0%
$46
3.8%
$28
3.7%
$27
3.5%
$18
3.0%
$47
2.9%
SW
$99
11.8%
$89
5.2%
$79
4.0%
$19
3.4%
$49
2.9%
$59
2.3%
$69
2.2%
$29
2.2%
$97
2.2%
$98
2.1%
PDA
$99
13.4%
$49
11.0%
$79
5.0%
$19
4.7%
$59
3.5%
$89
3.4%
$69
2.9%
$29
2.8%
$39
2.2%
$94
1.8%
HARD
DVD
DRV. PLAYER
$09
$99
3.5% 14.3%
$99
$49
3.0%
8.7%
$79
$19
2.6%
5.5%
$59
$29
2.5%
5.1%
$19
$39
2.5%
5.1%
$49
$69
2.5%
5.0%
$29
$79
2.3%
5.0%
$39
$89
2.1%
3.6%
$69
$59
2.0%
2.6%
$95
$89
1.7%
2.2%
PC
MONITOR
$99
11.5%
$49
5.0%
$29
3.4%
$39
2.8%
$79
2.5%
$19
2.4%
$59
2.4%
$69
1.7%
$09
1.6%
$35
1.5%
DIGITAL NOTEBOOK
CAMERA
PC TOTAL
$99
$99
$99
30.3%
40.0% 10.5%
$49
$49
$49
7.6%
11.6%
5.7%
$79
$29
$19
4.4%
5.3%
4.4%
$14
$89
$39
4.0%
3.3%
3.5%
$69
$79
$29
3.1%
3.1%
3.4%
$15
$39
$09
2.6%
2.3%
2.8%
$94
$29
$79
2.6%
2.2%
2.6%
$19
$19
$09
2.1%
2.1%
2.5%
$13
$59
$89
1.9%
1.9%
2.4%
$09
$59
$89
1.5%
1.6%
2.3%
THREE
CATEGORIES
REMOVED
$99
15.2%
$49
6.0%
$79
3.8%
$19
3.2%
$89
3.2%
$29
3.1%
$69
2.6%
$39
2.5%
$59
2.4%
$09
1.8%
11
We find similar price-ending patterns from individual product categories, as reported in
Table 5. The $99 price-ending is more common than any other two-digit price-endings, including
the other $9-endings. The exceptions are CDs, DVDs and video games, whose prices are less
than $100. As shown in Figures 1 and 4 and Table 5, after removing these three categories, all
the $9 price-endings are included among the top ten frequencies of the last two price digits.
These findings are in synch with Bergen, et al. (2003), who found this to be true for cents.
Comparisons with Previous Studies
Table 6 reports the findings of previous studies on observed price-endings. Most studies
indicate that retail price-setters in the U.S. tend to choose the rightmost digits or endings of a
price so that the price falls just below a round number. In addition, some studies show that 0¢
and 5¢ are commonly for the rightmost digits of a price. With the empirical regularities we
observed, the patterns of price-endings in Internet-based retailing are almost similar in U.S. print
ads and supermarket scanner data. Thus, we see that Internet-based retailers appear to frequently
use 9¢ or $9 price-endings, just as traditional bricks-and-mortar stores do.
Table 6. Previous Findings for the Distribution of Price-Endings in Cents
RESEARCH
Twedt (1965)
Friedman (1967)
Schindler and
Kirby (1997)
Stiving and Winer
(1997)
Heeler and Nguyen
(2001)
Naipaul and Parsa
(2001)
Bergen et al. (2003)
PRODUCT
Meat
Groceries
Food
Multiple products
Tuna
Yogurt
Online retail
products
Fine-dining food
Quick-service food
Groceries
DATA
POINTS
0¢
30,878 1.0%
2,597 4.0%
3,326 3.5%
1,415 27.2%
1¢
1.0%
2.0%
8.9%
0.9%
PRICE-ENDINGS IN CENTS (%)
2¢
3¢
4¢
5¢
6¢
1.0% 9.0% 0.0% 19.0% 0.0%
1.0% 7.0% 4.0% 15.0% 1.0%
3.6% 14.3% 3.3% 18.6% 1.6%
1.7% 0.8% 2.2% 18.5% 2.0%
7¢
3.0%
6.0%
9.9%
6.6%
8¢
2.0%
3.0%
2.5%
9.4%
9¢
64.0%
57.0%
33.8%
30.7%
24,770 0.0%
2,464 10.9%
243 42.8% 0.0% 0.0%
N/A
50.5%
N/A
36.1%
0.0% 1.2% 8.2% 2.5% 0.0% 7.8% 37.4%
3,290 30.5% 0.0% 0.0%
2,878 30.1% 0.0% 0.0%
9,800,000 5.0% 2.5% 2.5%
0.0% 0.0% 56.5% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 13.0%
0.0% 0.0% 36.9% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 33.0%
4.0% 3.0% 11.0% 2.0% 3.0% 2.0% 65.0%
12
EXPLANATION FROM EXISTING THEORIES
Various theories attempt to explain “9” price-endings: operations theory (Stiving and Winer,
1997), perceived gain effect theory (Schindler and Kirby, 1997), rational inattention theory
(Bergen et al., 2003), and quality image theory (Stiving and Winer, 1997). Internet technologies
create new capabilities for pricing strategy. So this may change the drivers of firm choices of
price-endings, as well as consumers’ responses to them, and require us to find alternative
theories to be able to explain the phenomena that we observe. So, we provide an overview of
existing theories to better understand “9” price ending phenomena on the Internet.
Operations Theory
Operations theory revolves around procedural issues internal to the firm that reduce
monitoring costs (Stiving and Winer, 1997). Historically, odd pricing was developed to control
employee theft from cash registers, by requiring change to be given to the customer so the sale
was recorded (Ruffle and Shtudiner, 2003; Schindler and Kirby, 1997). But Internet
technologies obviate the need for charging odd prices; transactions now are made with credit
cards and online payment services (e.g., PayPal, MSN BillPay and iTransact). Still, firms can
algorithmically adjust posted prices. This theory raises other questions about IT impacts in the
production process for price-setting. To maintain a manageable level of complexity in the
presentation of product and pricing information, does it make sense for vendors to the dollar,
instead of to penny? Do shopbots’ price search capabilities produce listings that are ordered by
the dollar, but not by the penny? Does this change firm choices of price-endings?
Perceived Gain Effect Theory
It is widely recognized that rounded numbers are more accessible in memory. Firms exploit
high cognitive accessibility with “0” and “5” price-endings. They are reference points in price
13
evaluation. Consumers frame prices as round numbers along with a small gain (Schindler and
Kirby, 1997). According to prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979), perceptions of
gain/loss are disproportionate to the small size of a perceived gain (Thaler, 1985). So, pricesetters should favor 9¢ and $9, as we see in the U.S. retail market (Schindler and Kirby, 1997).
In Internet-based selling, customers use shopbots to locate the cheapest products in 1¢
increments Brynjolfsson and Smith, 2000). So, instead of round numbers, consumers may focus
on the lowest reported prices. Due to lower search and menu costs, Internet retailers may set
price-endings other than “9.” We see this with retail giant, Wal-Mart, which posts many prices
with 8¢ endings (Bergen et al., 2003; Bockstedt, Kauffman and Riggins, 2004). But, is
perceived gain effect theory is as applicable to e-commerce consumers, as it is elsewhere?
Underestimation and Rational Inattention Theory
Prices that end in 9¢ or $9 are associated with price under-estimation by the consumer
(Schindler and Kirby, 1997). Also called level effect theory by Stiving and Winer (1997), underestimation theory states that consumers round price numbers down due to limited memory
capacity (Basu, 1997; Lambert, 1975). So, consumers may perceive an actual price of $999.99
as $999 or $990—or possibly even $900—instead of $1,000 (Shy, 2000). Bergen et al. (2003)
also argue that it may be rational for consumers to be inattentive to the rightmost digits because
they often face large amounts of costly and hard-to-process information but are constrained by
time, resource, and information processing constraints. Thus, firms have an incentive to make
the last digits as high as possible. Along the same line with the perceived gain effect theory, we
are unsure if online consumers are rationally inattentive to price-endings. Shopbots reduce
information processing costs, making it possible for consumers to easily compare prices. But do
price comparison capabilities actually lead to purchase decisions that favor higher-valued price-
14
endings?
Store Image Quality Theory
Image effects transmit signals that enable consumers to infer something (in terms of
“images”) about a product or store based on the last digits of the price. Consumers may think a
product with a 99¢ or $99 price-ending is on sale (Shy, 2000). These price-endings have two
effects: price image effect and quality image effect (Stiving and Winer 1997). Price image effect
theory argues that product prices ending in 9¢, 99¢, $9 or $99 provide signals that products are
on sale (Schindler and Kibarian, 1996), prices have been cut (Schindler, 1984), or the price is
the lowest price (Schindler and Kibarian, 1996). A favorable price image signals a low price
(Schindler and Kibarian, 2001). In quality image effect theory, odd prices are a sign of low
quality, while even prices indicate high quality (Stiving and Winer, 1997). An unfavorable
impression of a store’s or a product’s quality might occur as a result of the use of 9¢ or $9 priceendings. But online consumers care about other non-price aspects, such as seller reputation,
delivery locations and times, contract lengths, etc. Non-price competition offers new ways to
compete and requires firms to formulate new business rules. But will non-price drivers of priceending choices be observed in Internet-based selling? Will quality play a key role? Will the
drivers be the same across product areas and industry sectors? How about over time?
IDENTIFYING THE DRIVERS OF THRESHOLD PRICING PRICE-ENDINGS
Our next goal is to explore what may be causing the variation in the use of the “9” priceendings that we observe across stores and product categories. The literature in marketing and
economics guided our effort to identify what variables may be the drivers. We examine two
theories in depth: consumers’ perceptions of store quality image and rational inattention. We
15
also present hypotheses that flow from each theory related to the variables we collected. We end
with a figure summarizing our research model for “9” price-endings on the Internet.
Model Development
Our choice of the theories was driven by two considerations. First, we focused on the
elements that IT changes (i.e., the Internet, and online price-discovery and price-setting tools).
There is increasing evidence that the reputation and quality image of online sellers has a
significant effect on consumer purchases (Hansell, 2003; Piller, 1999). Similarly, the costs of
attention to price information are impacted by IT, and should affect the degree of rational
inattention exhibited by consumers. Second, we focused on variables that can be collected by
Internet-based data collection tools and other related ITs. This directed us to observable,
detectable and consistently-collectible variables such as price, or other system-based information
related to Internet Web sites. This also pushed us away from variables and theories that would
more naturally be tested using lab experiments or survey methods.
Consumer Perceptions of Store Quality Image
With many products in the traditional market, it is difficult for consumers to observe quality
even at the time of purchase, because they are imperfectly informed about the product or store
characteristics (Stiglitz, 1987). Rao and Monroe (1989) observe that consumers may use prices
as a cue for assessing quality. Image effects transmit signals that enable consumers to infer
something (in terms of “images”) about the product or store based on the rightmost digits of the
price (Stiving and Winer, 1997). In particular, focusing on quality images, some authors have
suggested that odd prices are a sign of low quality products or low quality stores, while even
prices indicate high quality products or high quality stores (Stiving and Winer, 1997). So an
16
unfavorable impression of a store’s or a product’s quality might occur as a result of low price
image associated with 9¢ or $9 price-endings (Schindler and Kibarian, 2001).
Notice that the Internet gives consumers access to different information about products and
retailers than has ever been available before. Moreover, it has changed the set of retailers and
the ways customers interact with Internet retailers. As a result, it may facilitate the development
of store images in new ways. We also know that the Internet has impacted both price
competition and non-price competition between firms (Clay, et al., 2002). Online consumers
may care about seller reputation, delivery locations and times, contract lengths, and so on. These
may lead to different ways for consumers to assess store quality, and impact the role that
threshold prices play in the marketplace. Internet-based retailers are increasingly concerned with
effectively positioning their image.
Stiving (2000), in his study of price-endings at twelve department stores, find that retailers
with a relatively elegant image, such as Nordstorm and Macy’s, are among the most likely to use
prices that end in “0.” They also tend to avoid prices that end with a “9” so as not to signal
lower quality. We expect higher quality Internet retailers to exhibit similar pricing. We next
present four hypotheses related to the effects of store quality image on the use of “9”-endings by
Internet-based retailers.
We looked for proxies of store quality that are accessible in the kind of data that our data
collection agent was able to collect. In general, higher quality stores tend to have higher product
quality, service levels, product assortment and support. As such they may face higher costs
and/or charge higher margins for their products. This leads to higher prices for higher quality
stores. One advantage of our data collection agent is the quality of pricing data that we can
access. What is not as clear with its use is whether absolute or relative price level data, or both,
17
are more effective ways to identify high quality stores. This leads to our first two hypotheses.
□
Hypothesis 1 (The Relative Store Price Level – Store Quality Hypothesis). Similar to
traditional retailing, Internet-based sellers that charge higher prices will use “9” priceendings less frequently than the lower-priced sellers to signal their high quality.
□
Hypothesis 2 (The Relative Product Price Level – Store Quality Hypothesis). Also
similar to traditional retailing, firms will use “9” price-endings for higher-priced online
products less frequently than for the lower-priced online products.
Another advantage of our data collection approach is that we can access information that is
systematically collected and posted on the Web. There is one source of information on store
reputation that can be used as a proxy for store quality. Like prices, there are variants of this
information that can be used, which leads to our next two hypotheses. On the Internet,
information asymmetries prevail. It is rare for buyers to be able to inspect product quality before
they purchase because buyers and sellers are geographically separated and cannot interact faceto-face as they transact. Also, it is doubtful that Internet retailers with low online prices will be
the most reliable (Kauffman and Lee, 2004). So, digital intermediaries, such as trusted third
parties or an online reputation mechanism (Dellarocas, 2003), will play a significant role in
building trust between buyers and sellers to “perfect” business processes associated with
Internet-based transaction making (Dai and Kauffman, 2005).
There is also increasing evidence that the reputation of online sellers has a significant effect
on consumer purchases (Hansell, 2003; Piller, 1999). As a result, online marketers must
understand the importance of consumer reviews or ratings on their stores as a proxy for the
consumer’s perceptions of the quality of the store. Most all reported image effects relate to the
digits “0” and “9,” the two most commonly used price-endings. “0” has been suggested as a
signal of higher quality while “9” signals both a lower quality for the store and a good price.
This leads us to assert a third hypothesis:
18
□
Hypothesis 3 (The Store Reputation Hypothesis). In Internet-based selling, higherquality firms, based on store reputation, will choose “9” price-endings less often than
lower-quality firms.
The Internet provides unprecedented opportunities to collect data on more subjects with
lower costs, fewer strict assumptions, and greater realism (Kauffman and Wood, 2003).
However, with these new opportunities also come challenges. If the research data come from
online reputation mechanisms where participants are anonymous and the researcher does not
control the instrument design, then issues of data reliability may be of concern.
According to the price image effect theory, the use of the “9” price-endings creates the
impression of a price that is relatively low, which may affects sales increases (Anderson and
Simester, 2003; Schindler, 1996, 2001). This leads us to assert:
□
Hypothesis 4 (The Store Popularity Hypothesis). In Internet-based selling, more
popular firms in terms of the number of reviews will use “9” price-endings more
frequently than less popular firms.
Rational Inattention Theory
Rational inattention theory (Bergen et al., 2003; Sims, 2003) argues that it may be rational
for consumers to be inattentive to the rightmost digits because they are constrained by time,
resources, and information processing constraints. Since many consumers appear to ignore the
last digit of the price, firms have an incentive to make it as high as possible at $9 or 9¢ (Basu,
1997; Shy, 2000). The rational inattention theory of pricing suggests that consumers tend to pay
less attention to the rightmost digits of a “9”-ending price. The longer the string of digits, the
more important is the leftmost digit relative to the rightmost digit. We define price length as the
number of digits in a price, inclusive of dollars and cents.
The Internet makes more marketing information available than before, which may create
greater information overload, amplifying this effect. At the same time, computers and shopbots
19
make the ability to search and evaluate information easier, decreasing the impact of this effect.
To explore the role of rational inattention in this environment, we propose the following
hypothesis for Internet-based retailing:
□
Hypothesis 5 (The Price Length Hypothesis). As with traditional retailing, as the
length of a product price increases in terms of the number of digits in the price, Internetbased sellers will use “9”-ending prices more often.
This leads us to propose the model, illustrated in Figure 5, whose predictions we will test.
Figure 5. A Research Model for “9” Price-Endings in Internet-Based Selling
Quality Image Drivers
Relative
Store Price
H1 ( )
Relative
Product Price
Store
Reputation
H2 ( )
H3 ( )
Store
Popularity
H4 (+)
“9” Ending
Prices
H5 (+)
Price
Length
Rational Inattention Driver
DATA AND MODELING METHOD
The Data
Since we focus on the extent to which the technological environment of Internet-based
selling affects firm choices about price-setting strategy, it is natural for us to explore how online
reputation and price images appear to relate to price-ending choices. To support this exploration,
we selected data on the sellers’ online reputation from the original data set. Refer to Table 1
20
again. We define online reputation as the overall rating for each store averaged over the set of
individual ratings used to produce it.3 So, we sampled data from stores with greater than or
equal to 100 reviews to control for response biases. Our data collection approach yielded
1,210,728 daily observations for 449 different products sold by 116 Internet-based retailers, as
reported in Table 7.
Table 7. Descriptive Statistics for the Data (for Sellers with Number of Reviews ≥ 100)
CATEGORY
DATA
POINTS
NUMBER OF
PRODUCTS
Music CDs
Movie DVDs
Video Games
Software
PDAs
Hard Drives
DVD Players
PC Monitors
Dig. Cameras
Notebook PCs
115,290
178,608
126,270
192,516
83,448
127,368
69,540
170,922
115,290
31,476
46
49
49
48
44
42
45
50
43
33
1,210,728
449
Total
NUMBER OF
STORES
MEAN
PRICE
STD.
DEV.
15
$5.49
$26.98
$13.81
12
$5.76 $134.99
$28.20
23
$6.99
$57.89
$32.73
41
$9.95 $5,000.00 $320.99
47 $39.99 $956.95 $355.89
36 $49.00 $3,168.99 $360.32
40 $59.94 $1,069.00 $359.54
41 $87.87 $3,199.99 $711.65
69 $189.00 $6,000.00 $719.70
17 $699.00 $2,998.00 $1,726.22
$3.44
$27.20
$12.94
$494.12
$197.05
$560.51
$227.38
$703.55
$602.80
$419.24
116
MIN.
PRICE
MAX.
PRICE
$5.49 $6,000.00
$356.89 $551.41
Defining the Variables for the Empirical Model
To examine what drivers are most important in explaining price-endings in e-commerce, we
used a binary coding for each of the prices collected in this study as either a “9” or “not a 9.” 4
Although it is not difficult to figure out what “9” price-endings are supposed to look like, we
actually attempted to identify two different categories of “9” price-endings: 9¢ and $9 priceendings. Consumer perceptions of “9” price-endings may be different for different price levels
o
3
This measure is susceptible to self-reported sample biases, so the number of reviews is critical for
evaluating the quality of our model’s results. If the overall rating is based on only a few reviews, the
results may be unreliable. The larger the number of reviews, the more accurate is the overall rating.
We sampled our original data set to identify stores with a large enough number of reviews (about 100) to
control response bias. The number of reviews is a proxy for store popularity, since the greater the number
of reviews, the more products the store will have been sold and the more customers will have been served.
4
The prices are the actual selling prices without any shipping or handling fees, adjusting any promotions
or discounts.
21
of the products. For example, $1,999.00 may be a “9”-ending price, just as $10.99 would be. So,
we define two different dependent variables: NineCents and NineDollars, as described in Table 8.
Table 8. Definitions of the Dependent and Independent Variables in the Empirical Model
VARIABLE
DEFINITION
Dependent Variables (“9” Endings)
NineCents
Binary variable indicating rightmost digit in cents is “9”; coded as 1, and 0 otherwise.
NineDollars
Binary variable indicating rightmost digit in dollars is “9”; coded as 1, and 0 otherwise.
Independent Variables
RelativeStorePrice
Store’s average price for each product category divided by average price for each product
category for all stores.
StoreReputation
Store’s online reputation, proxied by consumers’ average rating of the store.
NumReview
Ln(number of consumer reviews for each Internet-based retailer).
RelativeProductPrice Price of each product divided by the average price for the product category across stores.
PriceLength
The number of digits in price, including the decimal point.
We operationalize five potential drivers of observed firm choices for price-endings in
Internet-based selling. (1) We defined RelativeStorePrice as a relative measure of the prices
charged by each Internet-based seller. Some retailers sell many different categories of products,
so we calculate an average price for each category-store combination. Then, we divide the
average price by the mean price of each product category to produce a store’s relative price for
each product category. (2) We also created an explanatory variable, RelativeProductPrice, to
capture the relative price of each observation within its product category, defined as the price of
the product, divided by the average price for the product category. (3) To measure the quality of
the store in terms of consumer ratings, we averaged the ratings provided by BizRate.com,
collected once a week. The values of the average number of reviews lie between 100 and
900,000. So, we transformed the number of reviews to reduce outlier effects with a logarithm.
A large number of reviews will not have the same proportional effect on the decision of priceendings as small number of reviews. We operationalized two explanatory variables,
StoreReputation and NumReview, to measure the effects of online reputation and popularity for
22
Internet-based retailers. (4) Finally, to measure the extent of the consumer’s rational inattention,
we define PriceLength as the number of price digits including the decimal point. Table 9
provides descriptive statistics for the explanatory variables.
Table 9. Descriptive Statistics for Key Variables
VARIABLE
RelativeStorePrice
RelativeProductPrice
StoreReputation
NumReview
PriceLength
DATA POINTS
1,210,728
1,210,728
1,210,728
1,210,728
1,210,728
MEAN
1.29
1.00
8.09
4.17
5.65
STD. DEV.
4.40
1.02
1.10
0.88
0.67
MIN.
0.18
0.03
1.68
2.00
4.00
MAX.
71.00
15.58
9.47
5.95
7.00
Table 10 presents pairwise correlations between all the explanatory variables. The highest
absolute value of any pairwise correlation is 0.448, which is below the frequently-used threshold
of 0.6 suggested by Kennedy (1998). We also calculated variance inflation factors (VIFs) to
detect multicollinearity among the explanatory variables. The highest VIF is 1.311. Values in
excess of 20 would be a concern (Greene, 2003).
Table 10. Correlations among Variables: All Categories (N=1,210,728)
RelativeStorePrice
RelativeProductPrice
StoreReputation
NumReview
PriceLength
RelativeStorePrice
RelativeProductPrice
StoreReputation
NumReview
PriceLength
1.000
-0.001
-0.058
0.037
0.041
1.000
0.003
0.013
0.448
1.000
0.032
0.085
1.000
0.041
1.000
The Seemingly Unrelated Probit Regression (SUPR) Method
We assume that Internet-based retailers are profit maximizers with respect to choices
between “9” and “not 9” price-endings. This decision can be modeled with a binary choice
model. Specifically, to explore the effects of Internet-based sellers’ quality images and
consumers’ rational inattention on the sellers’ price-ending strategies, we employ a binary
probit model. This general model permits us to define the probability that a firm i chooses a “9”
23
price-ending (9¢ or $9) for product j on a specific day t as:
P (NineEnding = 1) = f (RelativeStorePrice, RelativeProductPrice, StoreReputation,
NumReview, PriceLength)
As with the linear probability model, the disturbance terms in a probit model exhibit
heteroskedasticity (Gujarati, 2003). So instead of using ordinary least squares (OLS), we use
maximum likelihood estimates (MLE) to correct this defect. The full form of the binary probit
model is:
P( NineEndingi , j ,t = 1) = β0 + βRelativeStorePrice RelativeStorePricei , j ,t + β RelativeProductPrice RelativeProductPricei , j ,t
+ βStoreReputation StoreReputationi , j ,t + β NumReview NumReviewi , j ,t + βPriceLength PriceLengthi , j ,t + ui , j ,t
As the two dependent variables used in this study (i.e., NineCents and NineDollars) are not
likely to be mutually exclusive, any inferences drawn from the comparison of the regression
coefficients on the basis of the two equations may suffer from some level of confounding
problems. That is, the error terms may be correlated across the two equations for the same
observation but will be uncorrelated across different observations (Greene 2003). So, we use a
seemingly unrelated probit regression (SURP) for bivariate dependent variables to resolve this
potential problem. In addition, some of the explanatory variables— RelativeStorePrice,
StoreReputation and NumReview—do not vary by store. If these variables are being used across
repeated observations, this may lead to the inflation of the standard errors. So, to correct for
repeated observations, we adjust the standard errors by clustering our data at store level.
EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION AND RESULTS
We used Stata 8.0 (www.stata.com) to estimate two regressions with the same explanatory
variables, allowing the disturbance terms in both regressions to be correlated with each other.
We used both likelihood ratio (LL) statistic and the count-R2 to validate the results. The countR2 is defined as the number of correct predictions divided by total number of observations
24
(Gujarati, 2003). In binary choice regression, however, goodness of fit is of secondary
importance. There is no universally-accepted goodness of fit measure for binary choice models,
unlike R2 for linear regression (Kennedy 1998). What matters is the expected signs of the
regression coefficients and their statistical, logical and practical significance (Gujarati, 2003).
Empirical Results for All Categories of Data
We first examine the empirical model using all the data available, as reported in Table 7.
The results of the SURP regression for each dependent variable are as follows:
□
NineCents:
□
NineDollars:
Pi *, j ,t = 0.485 − 0.006 RelativeStorePricei*, j ,t + 0.127 RelativeProductPricei*, j ,t
+ 0.053StoreReputationi*, j ,t + 0.342 NumReviewi*, j ,t − 0.517 PriceLengthi*, j ,t
Pi *, j ,t = −2.063 − 0.014 RelativeStorePricei*, j ,t − 0.058RelativeProductPricei*, j ,t
− 0.055StoreReputationi*, j ,t + 0.099 NumReviewi*, j ,t + 0.328PriceLengthi*, j ,t
Table 11 shows the coefficients of the variables and the robust standard errors. First, the
effects of RelativeStorePrice on the choice of “9” price-endings are negative and significant in
each model for the different dependent variables. This is consistent with the Relative Store Price
Level - Store Quality Hypothesis (H1), which states that Internet-based sellers that charge higher
prices will use a “9” price-ending less frequently than the lower-priced sellers to signal their high
quality. The effects of RelativeProductPrice show mixed results. In the NineDollars model the
estimated coefficients show negative and marginally significant effects on “9” price-ending
decisions. However, in the NineCents model we obtained an unexpected result: positive and
significant effects on the decision to use “9”-endings. This result indicates that Internet-based
sellers, rather counter-intuitively, may use more 9¢-endings but fewer $9-endings for high-priced
products. We conclude that the Relative Product Price Level – Store Quality Hypothesis (H2) is
supported only in NineDollars Model.
25
Table 11. Results of Seemingly Unrelated Probit Model: All Categories
NINECENTS MODEL
NINEDOLLARS MODEL
COEFF.
ROBUST S. E.
COEFF.
ROBUST S. E.
***
***
Constant
0.485
0.8844
-2.063
0.7953
0.0021
RelativeStorePrice
-0.006***
0.0029
-0.014***
RelativeProductPrice
0.127***
0.0339
-0.058***
0.0361
***
StoreReputation
0.053
0.0673
0.055***
0.0477
0.1150
0.099***
NumReview
0.0972
0.342***
0.1064
PriceLength
-0.517***
0.1250
0.328***
Note: Bivariate probit (maximum likelihood estimation); 1,210,728 data points; Wald test of
ρ=0: χ2(1) = 10.52, P=0.001; -2LL = 2,940,565; Robust standard errors assume clustering at
the store level; significance levels: *** = 0.01, ** = 0.05, * = 0.10; estimated coefficients in bold
indicate consistent results with the hypotheses.
VARIABLE
The effects of StoreReputation are not significant (p=0.429 and 0.250, respectively) in
support of the Store Reputation Hypothesis (H3) in both models. In addition, we obtained an
unexpected opposite result—positive effects of StoreReputation on the choice to use a “9” priceending. This result indicates that Internet sellers with high reputation tend to use more 9¢ and $9
price-endings than the other price endings. We also assessed the relationship between the
number of reviews and “9” price-ending decisions. We found significant and positive effects for
NumReview (the number of consumer reviews) on “9”-ending prices for each of the two
dependent variables. This provides strong support for the Store Popularity Hypothesis (H4).
Apparently the more popular retailers on the Internet use “9” price-endings more frequently,
which, in turn, may result in increased consumer purchases. (It requires data on actual sales to
nail down if purchases actually increase.)
Finally, we assess the implications of rational inattention in terms of the estimated
coefficients of PriceLength in each model. As predicted by the Price Length Hypothesis (H5),
the estimated PriceLength variable should be positive, and this was true for in NineDollars
model. But PriceLength shows significant and negative effects on “9”-ending price decisions in
the NineCents model, the opposite of our prediction.
26
In a nutshell, our results show that the proposed model is well supported in the NineDollars
model except for StoreReputation, which indicates that the Internet-based retailers are less
attentive to 9¢-endings. Instead, they focus on $9-endings just as traditional retailers (e.g., retail
grocery stores) are more attentive to 9¢-endings to maximize their profits.
For the measurement of the goodness-of-fit of our model, we conducted concordant pairs
analysis using count-R2, which assesses the accuracy model in predicting the dependent variables
(Agresti, 2002; Gujarati, 2003). Count-R2s, the percentage of concordant pairs in the total
observations, for the three models are 73.4% and 62.7%, respectively, as reported in Table 12.
In addition, the sums of the percentage of the correct predictions in each category of our models
(i.e., 131.7% and 104.8%, respectively) are greater than 100%, which is the threshold suggested
by McIntosh and Dorfman (1992).
Table 12. Concordance Pairs Analysis Using Count-R2: All Categories
PREDICTED
NINECENTS MODEL
0
1
Correct
85,358
89.3%
OBSERVED
0
714,028
237,099
42.4%
1
174,099
Count-R2
73.4%
Note: The cutoff value for concordance is 0.5.
NINEDOLLARS MODEL
0
1
Correct
41,362
94.5%
711,735
410,444
10.3%
47,187
62.7%
Additional Results for Hypothesis Tests of Rational Inattention with Price Length
Because three explanatory variables, RelativeProductPrice (H2), StoreReputation (H3) and
PriceLength (H5) in the NineCents model exhibit somewhat contradictory results for the
proposed hypotheses, we conducted further analyses on the NineCents model with PriceLength.
Testing for the significance of this variable constitutes a Rational Inattention Hypothesis in this
research.
27
First, we analyzed the lowest-priced level products, whose price digits equal 4. As reported
in Table 13, the estimated models show a reasonable fit with the data by showing the count-R2 as
72.1%. With the exception of the StoreReputation Hypothesis, the results show the consistency
with the proposed hypotheses. However, only the Number of Reviews Hypothesis is strongly
supported. The results indicate that, among the drivers of the “9”-ending prices, the quality
image drivers, i.e., RelativeStorePrice (H1) and RelativeProductPrice (H2) have negative but no
significant effects on the Internet-based retailers’ “9¢”-ending price decisions for low-priced
products. In addition, these results are somewhat consistent with existing empirical research on
price endings (Stiving, 2000), which found that higher-priced stores use more round prices than
lower-priced stores and higher priced products within a product category tend to be priced using
round numbers.
Table 13. Results of Binary Probit NineCents Model by Price Length (Number of Digits)
4 DIGITS
5 DIGITS
6 DIGITS
7 DIGITS
VARIABLE
COEFF.
S. E.
COEFF.
S. E.
COEFF.
S. E.
COEFF.
S. E.
Constant
-3.561***
1.651 -2.831***
0.926 -1.943***
0.761 -1.340***
1.297
0.004
0.014***
RelativeStorePrice
-0.454***
1.166
0.127***
0.205 -0.011***
0.005
***
***
***
RelativeProductPrice -1.535
1.122
0.308
0.117
0.136
0.062
0.075***
0.035
0.103 -0.074***
0.208
StoreReputation
0.207***
0.091
0.084***
0.074 -0.002***
0.260
0.210
0.098
0.202
NumReview
0.396***
0.285***
0.183***
0.715***
-2LL
41,005.3
590,381.5
660,566.1
89,680.0
Count-R2
72.1%
67%
76%
82.5%
N (Obs.)
35,584
457,511
618,001
99,632
Note: Binomial probit (maximum likelihood estimation); Robust standard errors assume clustering at store
level; price length includes the decimal point; significance levels: *** = 0.01, ** = 0.05, * = 0.01; estimated
coefficients in bold indicate consistent results with the hypotheses; PriceLength variable omitted.
Among the online reputation drivers, the popularity of the store (based on number of
reviews) has positive and significant effects on “9¢” price endings in almost all the digits of
prices. Only the NineCents model in 7-digits of prices shows a marginally consistent result, as
reported in Table 13. So, the Store Popularity Hypothesis (H4) is well supported.
28
But the Store Reputation Hypothesis (H3) is not supported in all price digits for the
NineCents model. However, as the lengths of prices increase, the coefficients of StoreReputation
show negative effects on “9¢”-ending prices (including 6 and 7 digits), also reported in Table 13.
These results suggest that Internet-based retailers with high online reputation tend to use “9¢”endings often for low-priced products, while they less frequently use “9¢”-endings for highpriced products to signal their quality.
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION
We began by examining some first order, easy-to-see empirical regularities for product and
category price-endings present in our online retail price data. We compared them with the wellknown empirical regularities for price-endings that are observed among traditional bricks-andmortar retailers, based on the existing literature, setting up for additional exploration to gain an
understanding of the observed variations in price-endings. We find that Internet-based retailers
appear to frequently use 9¢ or $9 price-endings just as traditional bricks-and-mortar stores do.
This is very interesting findings in that we believe that firms today are able to flexibly manage
and optimize prices by reducing the managerial costs and menu costs through the intensive use
of IT. By combining supply chain management systems with revenue yield management, for
example, firms now possess the capability to achieve refined pricing decisions that are in line
with both current demand and current supply. So, we go on to explore drivers of the variation
we observed in the use of “9” price-endings across retailers and product categories. On the
whole, we find evidence that “9” price-endings are not set as often by higher quality stores. This
lends support for theories of “9” price-endings that suggest that they are associated with lower
quality offerings in the marketplace (Stiving and Winer, 1997). Therefore, managers on the
29
Internet should be wary of the signals associated with threshold pricing approaches, especially if
they are competing on quality. This also lends support to suggestions that firms are competing
on quality on the Internet, and not just on price. Moreover, it is possible the high quality firms
are winning. Consider the following quotation about price-endings at the Yahoo! Store:
“Does it matter whether your product price is $19 or $20? According to a recent Yahoo!
Store study, yes, but not in the way you would expect. Yahoo! Store determined that
around 21% of merchant products have prices which end in ‘9’, suggesting that many
merchants expect the slightly lower price to influence sales. In contrast, [] products with
prices ending in ‘0’ accounted for almost half of that: 11%. However, when it came to
what actually sold, the ‘9’-ending products were 26% of all orders, but the ‘0’-ending
products were nearly 37%. The implication is that, all things being equal, people prefer
to buy products with rounded prices like $40 or $80 instead of $39 or $79. The price is
right.” (Bock Interactive, 2001, www.bockinteractive.com/newsletter5.html)
We obtained mixed support for the Rational Inattention Hypothesis. It is only true for $9endings. It does not hold for 9¢-endings in our data set. This may be due to other behavioral
considerations. Schindler and Kirby (1997) argue that with longer price length, one should
expect there to be a decrease in the relative size of the one-unit differences between a “9”-ending
price and “0”-ending price, which may be used as a consumer’s reference price of the product.5
As consumers may perceive smaller gains as price length increases, price-setters are less likely to
favor the use of the “9” price-endings in cents (Schindler and Kirby, 1997). This may also be
due to firms’ costs of price adjustment, suggesting that they also choose to be rationally attentive
to dollars, but not to cents. This offers a new heuristic to handle the complexity of pricing from
the perspective of the Internet-based retailer. Consumers on the Internet can easily compare
prices as well as trace product information through price comparison sites or search engines.
The technology itself provides a basis for the consumer being able to achieve a higher level of
o
5
Schindler and Kirby (1997) provide the following example: a one unit difference between the two-digit
price of $39 and $40 is 2.5% of $40. However, the one unit difference between the three-digit price of
$439 and $440 is only 0.23% of $440. Kauffman and Wood (2003) make a similar argument in terms of
the proportional differences that occur in follow-the-leader pricing in e-commerce.
30
attention to price—if they use it. So, in spite of the earlier arguments in favor of rational
inattention to price endings, shopbots may actually “flatten” some of the potential behaviors that
would support this theory. Therefore, we believe that exploring these issues in terms of
marketing and economic theory promises to be an interesting direction for future IS research.
At a minimum our results highlight the kinds of opportunities arising from the new kinds of
data being generated in IS from price information-gathering agents. At one time, the empirical
findings in this area were largely based on small numbers of prices in carefully constructed data
sets. Many of the authors of the studies actually collected their data by hand, as they had no
other choice. But the advent of scanner data sets allowed studies of “9” price-endings in larger
scale (Bergen, et al. 2003). Today, sophisticated software tools for data collection allow an
assessment of the patterns of price endings with a scale and scope unimagined by previous
generations of researchers. We have focused on the use of “9” price-endings on the Internet.
But clearly, application of these tools for collecting interesting new data sets extends far beyond
this narrow topic. Indeed, massive quasi-experimental data mining of the kind that we have
implemented, subject to the appropriate analysis, has the capacity to answer the questions that
many marketing analysts never have thought to ask (Hahn and Kauffman 2003). As a result, the
theories of price rigidity, asymmetric pricing, asynchronization, and other issues seem ripe for
analysis with price-gathering software agents.
This is not to say that our analysis is without limitations. The data on prices are stunning in
the scale of price information available. They permit us to assess the use of “9” price-endings
across a wide variety of products, product categories, stores and time periods. But data on
related issues, such as sales volume, operating costs, wholesale prices, and so on do not become
“magically” available using these methods. Nor is direct information about customer
31
perceptions and information processing. This suggests that data-collecting agents are best suited
to test theories that lead to direct implications of pricing patterns across products, categories,
stores or time. To go substantially beyond these questions, the data available from the Internet
will need to be subsidized by additional data on firms (their costs, policies with respect to the use
of technology for the production of prices, etc.) or a laboratory experiment (e.g., consumers with
similar demographics and other factors were presented with the same goods at different prices
(or price-endings) and to have seen what their choice process was), to be most effective in the
future.
Furthermore, there are a wide range of theories that can be explored—for example, the
behavioral and operational theories—that may be fruitfully explored in future work. We have
only begun to explore differences in these theories based on the Internet versus the bricks-andmortar worlds. In our future work, we hope to design and implement critical tests to understand
which theories work better to explain these observed findings.
REFERENCES
Agresti, A. Categorical Data Analysis (2nd Edition), John Wiley and Sons, New York, NY,
2002.
Anderson, E., and Simester, D. “Mind Your Pricing Cues,” Harvard Bus. Rev., 81 (9),
September 2003, 96-103.
Baird, J., Lewis, C., and Romer, D. “Relative Frequencies in Numerical Response in Ratio
Estimation,” Perception and Psychophysics, 8, November 1970, 358-362.
Baker, W., Marn, M., and Zawada, C. “Price Smarter on the Net,” Harvard Bus. Rev., 79 (2),
February 2001, 122-127.
Bakos, Y. "Towards Friction-Free Markets: The Emerging Role of Electronic Marketplaces on
the Internet," Comm. of the ACM, 41 (8), August 1998, pp. 35-42.
Basu, K. “Why Are So Many Goods Priced to End in Nine? And Why This Practice Hurts the
Producers,” Economics Letters, 54 (1), January 1997, 41-44.
Bergen, M., Chen, H., and Levy, D. “Making Sense of Ignoring Cents: Another Implication of
Rational Inattention,” in A. Ratfai (Ed.), Proc. 2003 Central European Univ. Workshop on
32
Microeconomic Pricing and the Macroeconomy, Budapest, Hungary, October 10-11, 2003.
Bock Interactive. Yahoo! Store Commerce Quotient from Internet World. The Bock Newsletter
on Yahoo! Store, 5, April 20, 1999. Available at www.bockinteractive.com/newsletter5.html.
Bockstedt, J., Kauffman, R.J., and Riggins, F. The Move to Artist-Led: Market Structure in the
Digital Music Industry,” in R. Sprague (Ed.), Proceedings of the 38th Hawaii International
Conference on Systems Science, Kona, HI, IEEE Computing Society Press, Los Alamitos, CA,
2005.
Brynjolfsson, E., and Smith, M.D. “The Great Equalizer? Consumer Choice Behavior at Internet
Shopbots,” Working paper, Sloan School of Management, MIT, Cambridge, MA, July 2000.
Clay, K., Krishnan, R., Wolff, E., and Fernandes, D. “Retail Strategies on the Web: Price and
Non-Price Competition in the Online Book Industry,” J. Ind. Econ., 50 (3), Sept. 2002, 351-367.
Dai, Q., and Kauffman, R.J. “Partnering for Perfection: An Economics Perspective on B2B
Electronic Market Strategic Alliances,” in K. Tomak (Ed.), Advances in Information Systems and
Economics, Idea Group Publishing, Harrisburg, PA, 2005.
Dellarocas, C. “The Digitization of Word of Mouth: Promise and Challenges of Online Feedback
Mechanisms,” Mgmt. Sci., 49 (10), October 2003, 1407 -1424.
Dutta, S., Zbaracki, M.J., and Bergen, M. "Pricing Process As A Capability: A Resource Based
Perspective," Strat. Mgmt. J., 24 (7), July 2003, 587-686.
Friedman, L. “Psychological Pricing in the Food Industry,” in A. Phillips and O.E. Williamson
(Eds.), Prices: Issues in Theory, Practice, and Public Policy, Univ. of Pennsylvania Press,
Philadelphia, PA, 1967, 187-201.
Folkertsma, C. K., van Renselaar, C., and Stokman, A.C.J. “Smooth Euro Changeover, Higher
Prices? Results of a Survey among Dutch Retailers,” WO Research Memorandum Series, 682E,
Netherlands Central Bank, Amsterdam, Netherlands, April 2002.
Greene, W.H. Econometric Analysis (5th Edition), Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 2003.
Gujarati, D.N. Basic Econometrics (4th Edition), McGraw-Hill, New York, NY, 2003.
Hahn, J., and Kauffman, R. J. “Managing What You Thought You Never Could Measure: A
Data Mining-Based Approach to Measuring the Business Value of Web Site Design,” in Proc.
Revolutionary Strategies and Tactics in Research Design and Data Collection for E-Business
Mgmt. Workshop, Pittsburgh, PA, September 29, 2003.
Hansell, S. “Amazon Decides to Go for a Powerful Form of Advertising: Lower Prices and Word
of Mouth,” New York Times, February 10, 2003, C8.
Heeler, R., and Nguyen, A. “Price Endings in Asia,” in B. Murphy and L. Engle (Eds.), Proc.
Australia New Zealand Marketing Assn., Auckland, New Zealand, December 2001.
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,”
Econometrica, 47 (2), March 1979, 263-292.
Kashyap, A. K. “Sticky Prices: New Evidence from Retail Catalogues,” Qtrly. J. Econ., 110 (1),
February 1995, 245–274.
Kauffman, R.J., and Lee, D. “Should We Expect Less Price Rigidity in the Digital Economy?,”
33
in R. Sprague (Ed.), Proc. 37th Hawaii Intl. Conference on Sys. Sci., Kona, HI, 2004, IEEE
Comp. Soc. Press, Los Alamitos, CA, 2004.
Kauffman, R.J., and Wood, C.A. “Revolutionary Research Strategies for E-Business
Management: A Philosophy of Science Perspective for Research Design and Data Collection in
the Age of the Internet,” in Proc. Revolutionary Strategies and Tactics in Research Design and
Data Collection for E-Business Mgmt. Workshop, Pittsburgh, PA, September 29, 2003.
Kauffman, R.J., and Wood, C.A. “Follow the Leader: Strategic Pricing in E-Commerce,”
Managerial Decision and Economics, 2004, forthcoming.
Kennedy, P. A Guide to Econometrics (4th Edition), MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1998.
Konieczny, J.D., and Skrzypacz, A. “A New Test of the Menu Cost Model,” in A. Ratfai (Ed.),
Proc. 2003 Central European University Workshop on Microeconomic Pricing and the
Macroeconomy, Budapest, Hungary, October 10-11, 2003.
Lambert, Z.V. “Perceived Prices as Related to Odd and Even Price Endings,” J. Retailing, 51 (3),
Fall 1975, 13-22.
McIntosh, C. S. and Dorfman, J. H. “Qualitative Forecast Evaluation: A Comparison of
Performance Measures,” Amer. J. Agr. Econ., 74 (1), February 1992, 209-214.
Monroe, K.B. Pricing: Making Profitable Decisions (3rd Edition), McGraw Hill, NY, 2003.
Naipaul, S., and Parsa, H.G. “Menu Price Ending that Communicate Value and Quality,” Cornell
Hotel and Restaurant Admin. Qtrly., 42 (1), February 2001, 26-37.
Piller, C. “Everyone Is a Critic in Cyberspace,” Los Angeles Times, December 3, 1999, p. A1.
Rao, A.R., and Monroe, K.B. “The Effect of Price, Brand Name, and Store Name on Buyer's
Perceptions of Product Quality: An Integrated Review,” J. Mktg. Res., 26(3), Aug.1989, 351-357.
Ruffle, B.J., and Shtudiner, Z. “99: Are Retailers Best Responding to Rational Consumers?
Experimental Evidence,” Dept. of Economics, Ben-Gurion Univ., Beer Sheva, Israel, July 2003.
Schindler, R.M. “Consumer Recognition of Increase in Odd and Even Prices,” Adv. Cons. Res.,
11 (1), 1984, 459-462.
Schindler, R.M. “Symbolic Meanings of a Price Ending,” Adv. Cons. Res., 18 (1), 1991, 794-801.
Schindler, R.M. “Relative Price Level of 99-Ending Prices: Image Versus Reality,” Mktg. Letters,
12 (3), August 2001, 239-247.
Schindler, R.M., and Kibarian, T.M. “Testing for Perceptual Underestimation of 9-Ending
Prices,” Adv. Cons. Res., 20 (1), 1993, 580-585.
Schindler, R.M., and Kibarian, T.M. “Increased Consumer Sales Response Though Use of 99Ending Prices,” J. Retailing, 72 (2), 1996, 187-199.
Schindler, R.M., and Kibarian, T.M. “Image Communicated by the Use of 99 Endings in
Advertised Prices,” J. Advertising, 30 (4), Winter 2001, 95-99.
Schindler, R.M., and Kirby, P.N. “Patterns of Rightmost Digits Used in Advertised Prices:
Implications for Nine-Ending Effects,” J. Cons. Res., 24 (2), September 1997, 192-201.
Shy, O. “Why 99 Cents?” Dept. of Economics, Univ. of Haifa, Haifa, Israel, June 2000.
34
Sims, C.A. “Implications of Rational Inattention,” J. Mon. Econ., 50 (3), April 2003, 665-690.
Stiglitz, J.E. “The Causes and Consequences of the Dependence of Quality on Price,” J. Econ.
Lit., 25 (1), March 1987, 1-48.
Stiving, M. “Price-Endings When Prices Signal Quality,” Mgmt. Sci., 46 (12), December 2000,
1617-1629.
Stiving, M., and Winer, R.S. “An Empirical Analysis of Price Endings with Scanner Data,” J.
Cons. Res., 24 (1), June 1997, 57-67.
Thaler, R. “Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice,” Mktg. Sci. 4 (3), Summer 1985, 199-214.
Twedt, D.W. “Does the '9 Fixation' in Retail Pricing Really Promote Sales?” J. Mktg, 29 (4),
October 1965, 54-55.
Wooldridge, J.M. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data (1st Edition), MIT
Press, Cambridge, MA, 2002.
Download