Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 The Best of Times, the Worst of Times: Economic Booms, Financial Crises And the 18 Year Cycle. Akhil Patel* While it is generally accepted that developed economies experience an “economic cycle”, that is, an alternating rhythm of economic expansion followed by recession – answers to important questions as to its causes (why?), period (how long?), frequency (how often?) and impact (to what extent?) continue to defy resolution. This paper takes steps to addressing this gap by marshalling evidence that not only has an economic cycle been operating in Western economies (the US and UK in particular) since the Industrial Revolution but also that it has done so on a remarkably stable average 18- to 19-year period over that time. Drawing on historical data from the early 1800s to present, this paper presents a theoretical framework for this 18 year economic cycle; it then explains why the cycle repeats so regularly - its fundamental causes are rooted in the role that land (and speculation in land in particular) plays in an economy and the transmission of such speculative activity into the rest of the economy through the major pro-cyclical sectors such as banking. Economic difficulties (including a fall in the value of stock prices) are thus more severe at the end compared to at other points in the cycle. The recent global financial crisis must therefore be viewed in its proper context, i.e. as merely the latest (albeit the most globally synchronised) episode of a repeating phenomenon. Field of Research: Economics, Finance, Banking 1. Introduction The recent global financial crisis has renewed interest in economic and financial cycles. Output losses during recessions can be extremely large, as recent history shows. i The literature on such cycles does not well serve the investor or the business owner, faced with the prospect of significant gains and losses at such times, given that there is little consensus on how to anticipate, date or explain business cyclesii that is, how and why business cycles arise and, critically, when they occur and how long they last. This paper marshals evidence to help address this gap. This paper finds clear evidence of an 18 year economic cycle that has operated in at least the United States and the United Kingdom for well over two centuries. Major economic variables are affected at key turning points of the cycle. 2. Literature Review Mainstream economic, finance and business research, dominated by the neoclassical school, is limited in two important ways in relation to understanding the economic and business cycle operating in “Western” economies, i.e. those characterised by pricing mechanisms, mature financial sectors and private land ownership (and transfer). The literature lacks an explanation for the business cycle, and relies on the idea that its root cause is down to exogenous demand and supply shocks or largely unanticipated disruptions in the supply of money (Foldvary, 1997). These limitations relate to the role that * Mr Akhil Patel, Director, Ascendant Strategy, 27 Old Gloucester Street, London, WC1N 3AX, www.theascendantstrategy.com, Email: akhil@theascendantstrategy.com 1 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 land plays in economic activity and to the role of banks in creating an economy‟s money supply. 2.1 The Role of land Land is one of the three basic, mutually exclusive, factors of production. This was understood by the classical economists. However, in modern neoclassical theory, land is treated as a species of capital. Gaffney and Harrison (1994) posit reasons why and how this came to be the case. In its characteristics land is very different to capital: it completely fixed in supply and has a supply cost of zero. (Gaffney 1994). Therefore high land values do not arise because of any action of the owner; nor do high values results in more supply (Harrison, 2007). Property developers know the value of land as „locational value” but its real term is economic rent (Ricardo, 1821) – that is its value over and above its supply price. Economic activity inherently tends to cluster in certain locations and the land in such locations attains the greatest value. As an economy develops (e.g. through investment in infrastructure, population growth etc.), a piece of land‟s ability to generate rent increases, so does the value of the land. This is unlike capital (and labour) – where competitive dynamics ensure that any excess returns to capital come back down to reflect risks and so on (Hodgkinson, 2011). The relative scarcity of land, especially in the best locations, gives owners bargaining power in relation to the capture of a greater share of economic surplus (Harrison (1983), Gaffney (1994) et al.). Over time, as an economy develops more and more of the gains accrue to the land, increasing its value and price. This creates economic incentives away from investing in the production of real economic goods and services towards speculation in the increasing price of land. 2.2 The role of banks and the money supply Banks are regarded is mere intermediaries in majority of economic models – that is a channel between savers with excess funds and borrowers with needs for capital. This view of banks has been challenged repeatedly over the years by heterodox economists who have pointed to the role of banks in creating the money supply through their lending (credit creating) activities. In early 2014, this view was given official confirmation for the first time by a central bank (Bank of England, 2014). Simply put, private banks are not intermediaries but active agents in the monetary system: they create the money supply. When they extend a loan to a borrower, they simultaneously create a matching deposit in the system – in the borrower‟s bank account – thereby creating new money. Operating within certain, system-wide constraints, it is the demand for loans that creates deposits, not the other way around (Bank of England, 2014). 2 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 The majority of lending that banks do in an economy is to provide mortgages (Hodgkinson, 2011), that is creating credit against the price of land. The availability of bank credit for acquiring real estate (land) helps to create additional demand against a fixed supply, thereby bidding up prices further. The impact of understanding the role of land and banks in this way is to see that over time more and more of economic activity becomes predicated on high land prices, including the health of the banking system balance sheet. But speculative activity cannot go on forever; at some point it stops. Prices in speculative scenarios either rise or fall: there is no equilibrium (Gaffney, 2010). As prices fall, this comprises the health of the banking system at the point at which the value of the loans exceed the value of the land they are collateralised against. Anderson (2008), Harrison (1983, 2007) demonstrate that this is a cyclical process throughout US and UK history, lasting on average 18 years. This is the process by which speculation in land transmits itself to the rest of the economy: as banks fail, credit is contracted and businesses start to fail (Gaffney, 2010). This also reduces aggregate demand. Furthermore, many major sectors of the economy, such as construction, start to contract – as major employers this is a further transmission mechanism into the rest of the economy (Harrison, 1983). Eventually, prices of land fall enough for new production to start again in earnest. Once the banking system has recovered, banks lend back to the economy and the process starts again (Anderson, 2008) The literature reviewed above argues for the existence of an 18 year real estate cycle. This cycle is seen to be driven by speculation in real estate. Land among the factors of production is uniquely suited to speculative activity. Other literature demonstrates the proper role that banks play in creating an economy‟s money supply and the flow of bank lending towards land prices via mortgages. Thus, when real estate prices rise, the money supply in an economy rise and becomes dependent on real estate prices continuing to rise. Thus, property price falls or real estate busts have an impact on an economy in two ways – in causing over-leveraged borrowers to default on loans and in the swift contraction in money supply for an economy. Further impacts occur in the construction industry and for SMEs which face external financing constraints. From the point of view of an investor or business owners, these insights give them the possibility of understanding how the business cycle operates and therefore to anticipate their major turning points, allowing the possibility of taking decisions to ameliorate their negative effects (and exploit opportunities for growth). This paper will examine if this is the case. 3 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 3. Methodology The paper takes the theoretical framework set out above and then examines historical data to see its impact on key variables. Since it is posited that this cycle is driven by real estate speculation, data on the following variables are gathered: Real estate (land) prices Bank lending Economic output (GDP) and the dates of major falls in output Short- and long- term interest rates. Asset values (e.g. stock indices) The focus of this paper is to derive insights that are of practical use to business owners and investors, that is to understand how the cycle operates and when it is likely to negative impact the bottom line (and the opposite). Data for these areas was gathered from at least the second half of the 20 th century. This study was confined to the United States and United Kingdom primarily for data availability issues but also because the literature reviewed above tended to focus on economies following the “Western” capitalist model – of which the US and UK are arguably the prime examples.iii The following data sets were gathered: UK real house price indexiv, 1955-2013 US real house price index, 1974-2013 US public land sales (acres), 1800-1923 UK M4 money supply and US broad money supply, 1964-2013 UK 10 year bond yields and short-term Treasury bill yields, 1956-2013 UK Gross Domestic Product, 1956-2013 UK FTSE All-Share Index, 1955-2013 This data was analysed for confirmation of regular 18 year fluctuations in real estate prices, bank lending/money supply, asset prices and so on. If there were fluctuations in these variables that coincide with the major turns in the real estate cycle, this provides evidence of the importance of the 18 year cycle and would provide the ability to assist business owners and investors in anticipating when business cycles are going to turn up and down. 4 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 4. Findings 4.1 18 year cycle in US and UK history The newly created United States Federal Government officially began selling off its land in 1800 after the existing 13 States ceded their land to the newly formed United States Federal Government. The transfer to private ownership took place via sales of the public domain. The historical process is not our concern here. Note that propensity to speculate in land is a key driver of the 18 year cycle, and right on cue land sales reached a speculative peak every 18 years (Figure 1 below): 1818, 1836, 1854, 1869, 1888, 1908. Anderson (2008) documents the history of this process: following each boom in speculation, there was a bust which was economy wide. Figure 1. Public land sales in the United States, 1800-1923 In the 20th century, this pattern continued. Foldvary (1994), drawing on evidence marshalled by Hoyt (1933), noted that that the next real estate boom occurred in 1925. The subsequent downturn in the economy came to be known as the Great Depression of the early 1930s . The one after that would have occurred in 1943/44 but building was impeded by war measures. Thus, for the first 144 years of private ownership of land in the United States, real estate speculation peaked every 18 years and contributed to subsequent business downturns. 5 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 The US experience, as seen through land sales data (in the absence of data on underlying land prices), is quite clear. The creation of private ownership of land took place over a longer period and was a more complicated historical process in the UK.v Nevertheless, Harrison (1983, 2007), noting significant data limitations is able to piece together a similar historical pattern in the UK going back into the late 18th century, i.e. a real estate/construction/output peak every 18 years on average, even though the dates of the peaks and troughs are different than for the US. This is summarised, set out below (Table 1). Table 1: UK 19th and early 20th century real estate or construction activity peaks (taken from Harrison, 1983, 2007) Year (peak year to downturn) 1792-1794 1811-1816 1828-1832 1847-1850 1865-1867 1883-1885 1898-1902 Historical evidence Building activity and construction peaked in 1792 following a rise in speculation focused on the rent-generating opportunities presented by the canals that were built at this time. These carried raw materials to the great factories of the north and returned finished goods to the consumer markets of the south. Banking collapses started in the City of Liverpool, the centre of cotton industry at the time. Land prices and construction increased in the early 19 th century, assisted by canal building, deepening industrialisation as well as higher food prices (which increased the price of agricultural land). Construction peaked in 1811 and then fell dramatically. The subsequent economic depression occurred in 1815-16. Frenzy in stock speculation peaked in 1825; then moved into land. This soon burst in and investment slumped, beginning in 1828. The building industry hit its trough in 1832. In the three years prior to 1848, the government authorised the investment of some £250m to construct 9,500 miles of railway. The effect was to raise land prices along the railways and in the newly connected cities. This induced speculation which peaked in 1847. Six banks failed as a result. The first mortgages started to appear in this cycle. The peak was characterised by real estate and stock speculation. Even Karl Marx made money in the stock boom of the 1860s. Housebuilding increased between 1875 and 1885 and then slumped – another indication that real estate activity was high 18 years after the prior peak. Another index of activity was construction of ships in the north east. The output of shipping tonnage peaked in 1883 and then slumped. This is clear evidence of the 18 year cycle in operation. Speculative frenzy reached a crescendo at the turn of the century. Financial scams were rife in this period, as they are at every 18 year cyclical 6 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Year (peak year to downturn) (1920) 1938 Historical evidence The 18 year peak would have fallen in the early 1920s. However, this cycle was affected by the First World War. Nevertheless, after the war ended there was a massive land boom that started in the early 1920s. The interwar years were a period of continuous growth. Note that the UK was not at its cyclical peak in the early 1930s and so the Great Depression had less (though a still significant) impact on the UK economy. The end of the cycle affected by massive rearmament expenditures in the run up to the Second World War. After the reconstruction efforts following the end of Second World War, the cycle picked up again in the same way as it did in the UK and US. However, after the Second World War it appears that the US and UK cycles were now synchronised. This is demonstrated in Figure 2 below. Figure 2. UK Real House Price Index, 1955-2013, US Real House Price Index, 19752013 UK real house price index: 1955 Q1 = 100; US real house price index: 1975 Q1 = 100 Data: Nationwide, OECD, Dallas Federal Reserve. 7 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 From a low in the mid-1950s, UK real estate prices peaked in the early 1970s as did US real estate prices. Then they fell before rising throughout the 1980svi into the peak in 1989. They fell again into the early 1990s before the most recent expansion that ended in 2007. The historical picture in relation to real estate speculation is pretty clear – there is a property boom and peak in prices that culminates every 18 years. The question now is to examine how and whether this phenomenon arises in relation to other economic variables in the way suggested above. 4.2 Bank lending, crises and recessions An increasingly large share of lending by banks is for mortgages. As the recent financial crises demonstrated, lax lending for real estate purchases was responsible for the credit crunch and subsequent financial crises in a number of countries. The severe contraction of lending by banks is responsible for contractions in economic output. What is interesting to the current discussion is that such issues arise at the end of every real estate cycle. The sudden drop in credit that follows the fall in property prices transmits to the rest of the economy as banks stop lending in general. In the context of the 18 year cycle, defaults on bank loans caused by a fall in real estate prices ignite a vicious downward spiral, which can cause a banking crisisvii and a pullback in other bank lending, leading to economic contraction and further pressure on borrowers, leading to more defaults. Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) examine the impact of such crises, noting also that they are often accompanied by crises such as exchange rate, domestic and foreign debt and inflation crises. Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) and Bordo and Jeanne (2002) noted the run up in asset, (including real house) prices prior to banking crises and credit contraction across countries and over time (though they do not necessarily posit a causal link as is being done here). Figure 3 below plots the change in M4 money supplyviii in the UK and broad money in the US since 1964, mid-way through the first post- WW2 cycle. The episodes of abrupt contraction in money supply – and therefore in lending - took place in 1972-75, 1989-1992 and 2009-12. These all followed the top of the real estate prices set out in Figure 1. Note that prior to these contraction episodes were periods of (often swift) expansion in the money supply, at the same time that real estate prices were accelerating (1970-72, 198589, 2005-07). 8 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Figure 3. UK and US Broad Money supply, 1964-2013 (year on year change, %) Data: Bank of England, St Louis Federal Reserve Banking crises affect small and medium sized enterprises in particular as such borrowers lack access to other sources of finance. This is one way in which the lack of credit is the transmission mechanism by which the effects of real estate/land speculation and their collapse are passed into the economy. 4.3 GDP and recessions Figure 4 depicts the periods of recession between 1956 and 2013.ix Apart from the recession in the early 1980sx, the only recessions lasting more than two successive periods of negative growth took place in the downturn of the 18 year cycle once real estate prices were falling and bank lending was contracting. These took place in 1973-1975, 1990-1992 and 2008-10. Though not graphed, the picture for the US is similar – the main contractions in output occurring in the mid-1970s, early 1990s and the late 2000s (as well as the early 1980s).xi 9 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Figure 4. UK GDP growth and recessions, 1956-2013 Data: Office of National Statistics 4.4 Interest rates and the yield curve The rate of interest is a key economic variable for investors and business owners. One of the best lead indicators for recessionary events is the inversion of the yield curve (when the yield on longer-term government securities drops lower than shorter-term ones), because the short-term economic outlook has turned negative and requires monetary policy intervention to stimulate the economy. The graph below plots the interest rate spread between 10 year UK government bond yields and short-term Treasury bills as a proxy for the yield curve: it is normal when the spread is positive; steep when the spread is large and inverted when the spread is negative. As can be seen, the negative spread (yield curve inversion) in many cases this anticipates the coming recession. However, there are times when the yield curve inverts without a subsequent recession (e.g. the mid-to-late 1990s). However, in the context of the 18 year cycles, the yield curve associated with a peak in house prices is a much better indicator. Times when the yield curve has inverted and house prices were not at their peaks have not resulted in recessions, i.e. intermittently 1965-67, 1985-87, 1997-99. 10 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Figure 5. The spread between 10 year bond yields and short-term Treasury bills Data: Bank of England 4.5 Stock market From an investor stand point, the impact of the 18 year cycle on stock prices is a key area of concern as major stock market down turns can wipe large proportions of profits and have a long-term effect on the gains made by an investment portfolio. Stock markets tend to price in the coming downturn prior to the onset of the recession or banking crisis (something noted by Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) who found that real equity prices fall in the year before a banking crisis but recover to pre-crisis peaks within three years of the crisis). In Figures 6-8 below, the FTSE All Share Index is graphed based on the 18 year segments relating to the 18 year economic cycle. These charts clearly show that the major stock market bear market periods (apart from the fall following the bursting of the dot com bubble in 2000-2001) take place after the peak of the 18 year cycle – 1972-75, 1990 and 2008-09. 11 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Figure 6. FTSE All Share Index, 1955-75 Real estate peak in 1973; stock market peak in 1972 Figure 7. FTSE All Share Index, 1976-93 Real estate peak in 1989; stock market peak in 1990 October 1987 stock market crash and recovery 12 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Figure 8. FTSE All Share Index, 1994-2013 Dot com crash Real estate peak in 2007; stock market peak in 2007 Data: Global Financial Data 4.6 The downturn On average, the downturn following the peak of the 18 year cycle takes around 3-4 years. The process includes both the contraction in output and the recapitalisation of the banks that is required for the new cycle to begin again. The stock market recovers first, as noted above and as pointed out by Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) – stock markets are back up to pre-crisis peaks within three years of the banking crisis (see also Harrison (1983) and Anderson (2008)). However, the normalisation of the yield curve takes longer as does the pick up in lending and rise in house prices. Table 2 below sets out the length of this process in the last three cycles in the UK. While the stock market does reach its low point first (within two years), house prices, in real terms, fall for up to six years; the contraction in credit (or reduction in growth) up to four years and the yield curve reaches its most positively sloped point anywhere up to six years after the peak of the cycle. 13 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Table 2. The length of the downturn after cyclical peaks, United Kingdom, 1956 2013 Cycle (peak date) 1973 Stock market: Real house Lending: peak peak to trough prices: high to growth to low low 24 months 6 quarters 11 quarters Yield curve: inversion to peak spreadxii 45 months 1989 Dec 1972 – Dec 1974 8 months Q4 1973 – Q2 1977 23 quarters Q4 1972 – Q3 1975 14 quarters Nov 1973 – Aug 1977 57 months Q2 1989 – Q1 1996 Q4 1988 – Q2 1994 Oct 1989 – June 1994 2007 April – December 1990 16 months 22 quarters 15 quarters (and counting) 29 months Oct 2007March 2009 Q3 2007 - Q1 2013 Q1 2009 - ? Oct 2007 – March 2010 4.7 The expansion The downturn takes 1.5 to 6 years, depending on which measure is used (Table 2 above). Harrison (2007) and Anderson (2008) suggested this was on average four year process, drawing on real estate and other data and on the works of Hoyt (1933) who studied the real estate cycle in Chicago in the one hundred years up to and including the Great Depression. Once the expansion is underway, the process lasts on average 14 years to the next cyclical peak, based on the observation that low to high, real house prices go up for around that length of time. Harrison (1983, 2007) suggests that this expansion is interrupted by a midcycle recession. Thus, in the analysis above, the recessions of 1961 and 1979-81 should be seen as of a different type to those of 1973-75, 1990-92 and 2008-10. The key point to note is that the latter stages of the cycle is characterised by much easier credit conditions and looser lending standards. As argued above, as economies expand the gains of this wealth is ultimately increases the economic rent and therefore accrues to the owner of land rather than the owner of capital or to wages. This process is most emphatically demonstrated by the prevalence of tall buildings that open at the peak or just after the peak of the ensuring recession. The business case for a tall building is high land prices (requiring the need to build up to generate economic returns), optimism about the economic outlook and large amounts of credit. This phenomenon was first observed by Richard Cantillon in the 18th century. The two tallest buildings in London (and at the time of opening, in the EU) are the Shard and the One 14 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Canada Square, which opened, respectively, in 2010 and 1991, during the recessions which occurred after the peak of the 18 year cycles which gave rise to them. 4.8 The generalised cycle The foregoing analysis demonstrates that the 18 year cycle is both a theoretical framework as well as an account of the key expansions and contractions that take place within the developed economy. Not all recessions take place every 18 years, but the ones which are prolonged and which involve major financial and credit problems and are more costly to firms and households occur on average every 18 years. In between times, the economies expand, a process interrupted only by minor recessions which in general come and go quickly. Following the evidence presented in Anderson (2008), Harrison (1983, 2007) the following general patterns can be observed within an 18 year cyclical period. The first act of the 18 year cycle begins as the wreckage of the previous cycle is cleared away, where economies move from recession back to growth and business conditions pick up, unemployment comes down and consumer spending returns. This leads to the first expansion of an 18 year cycle. The first key policy dilemma within the new cycle is the point at which monetary policy should tighten (following the looser policy adopted in the throes of the previous crisis). Monetary policy tightens once the recovery is underway. Banks lend into the economy when the yield curve is in more normal territory (when it is steeply sloped, banks have an incentive to borrow short to lend long back to government: there is less money for lending to businesses; thus once the recovery has started, loose monetary policy rather than tight inhibits the recoery). An increasingly confident economy may often experience a mid-cycle slow down. Such contractions generally prove to be short-lived and tend not to be financial in their nature, i.e. implicate the financial system. xiii The next act of the cycle is the second boom. Speculation plays as much of a role in this boom as does business expansion, though standard economic data may not be able to distinguish between the two. In this phase of the cycle, higher demand for real estate (land) is more obvious; and land is more expensive to acquire, mortgages comprise an increasing proportion of the loans made by the banking system, the quality of a bank‟s loan book is increasingly predicated on high land values. A characteristic of this phase is easy credit and relaxed lending standards. The final part of this phase is frenetic real estate activity. 15 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 The final great act of the cycle is the crash. At some point the cycle can no longer continue to support ever increasing values. When asset speculation is taking place, if prices are not increasing they are falling. As speculation stalls, prices fall, dramatically. Unlike other contractions, the problem with such falling values is that the banking system faces the real possibility that loans outstanding exceed the collateral value of assets they were created against and that people are no longer able to meet their loan obligations. Such problems disrupt the normal operation of the banking system (e.g. inter-bank lending) and can lead to a full-blown economic crisis. They also result in the need for large scale intervention in the banking system by government; the cost of such bailouts is often huge additional borrowing which then results in reduced public spending in other areas, exacerbating or prolonging the recession. A stylised diagram of the 18 year cycle is presented in Figure 9 below. Figure 9. The stylised diagram of the 18 year cycle 5. Conclusion This paper argues that it is possible to understand the business cycle and anticipate its various expansions and downturns. For the benefit of investors and business owners, making real life decisions that significantly affect profitability, it provides a coherent 16 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 framework in which more timely decision-making can be made. It also argues that the recent global financial crisis while more globally synchronised than other historical crises needs to be viewed in the context of a repeating occurrence. It therefore may have been of a different scale to other cyclical peaks in the UK and US but was not of a different type. The evidence underpinning the demonstration of the 18 year cycle has largely been drawn from the United States and United Kingdom. This analysis could usefully be extended to other countries or regions that follow the same “Western” economic model. A further extension could also be made to consider the increasingly important emerging markets, some of whom have only just adopted similar patterns of land ownership and financing of real estate activity. A key area of interest would be to consider whether such economies display a similar 18 year rhythm and at what point after such Western economic practices are adopted does this materialise.xiv 6. References Anderson, P. 2008, The Secret Life of Real Estate and Banking, Shepheard Walwyn. Ball, L. 2014, „Long Term Damage from the Great Recession in OECD Countries‟, Working Paper. Available at http://www.econ2.jhu.edu/People/Ball/long%20term%20damage.pdf Accessed 20th July 2014. Bank of England (2014) „Money Creation in the Modern Economy‟, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 2014 Q1, pp.14-27. Available at <http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/quarterlybulletin/2014/qb14 q102.pdf> Accessed 21st July 2014. Bordo, M. and Jeanne, O. 2002, „Boom-Bust in Asset Prices, Economic Instability and Monetary Policy‟, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no.8966. Foldvary, F. 1997, „The Business Cycle: A Geo-Austrian Synthesis‟, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, vol.56, no.4, pp. 521-41. Gaffney, M. 1994, „Land as a Distinctive Factor of Production‟, in N. Tiedman (ed.) Land and Taxation, Shepheard-Walwyn, London. Gaffney, M. and Harrison, F. 1994, The Corruption of Economics, Shepheard-Walwyn, London. Gaffney, M. 2010, After the Crash: Designing a Depress-free Economy, Wiley-Blackwell, Chichester. 17 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 Harrison, F. 1983, The Power in the Land, Shepheard-Walwyn, London. Harrison, F. 2007, Boom Bust: House Prices, Banking and the Depression of 2010, Shepheard-Walwyn, London. Hodgkinson, B. 2011, A New Model of the Economy, Shepheard-Walwyn, London. Hoyt, H. 1933, One Hundred Years of Land Values in Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. 2008, „Is the 2007 US Sub-prime Financial Crisis So Different? An International Historical Comparison‟, American Economic Review, vol.98, no.2, pp.339-44. Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. 2009, This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly, Princeton University Press, New Jersey. Ricardo, D. 1821, On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, John Murray, London. End Notes i Average potential loss of output, weighted by size of economy and measured against pre-crisis growth trajectories, was 8.4 per cent across OECD countries between 2008 and 2009. Some countries experienced a potential output loss of almost 30 per cent. For further analysis see Ball (2014). ii The term business cycle and economic cycle is used interchangeably in this paper. In some of the literature or commentary on business and economic cycles, the business cycle is often used to denote shorter term fluctuations in output while the economic cycle is a longer-term cyclical process. iii The US and UK were also easier cases to examine because they had not undergone changes such as th joining currency unions as other “Western” countries during the second half of the 20 century. However, these insights can be extended to other countries that broadly follow the same economic model. iv Ideally, data on land prices would have been used: however, such data are not gathered systematically in either the UK or the US. v Transfer of land to private ownership began in earnest after 1540 following the dissolution of the monasteries under Henry VIII when vast amounts of Church land was claimed by the Crown, which then sold it. Harrison (2007) notes that proper trading conditions for the sale and purchase of land were only in place by around 1700 “with scriveners acting as conveyancers, cartographers as land surveyors and solicitors doubling up as real estate agents and mortgage advisors” (p.77). vi In the UK, the 1980s economic expansion became known as the “Lawson boom”, named after Thatcher‟s long-serving Chancellor of the Exchequer, Nigel Lawson. According to this view of the economy, the fruits of the boom ultimately end up in the price of land – as seen in the higher prices for real estate. vii We follow Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) in defining a banking crisis as marked by 18 Proceedings of 9th Annual London Business Research Conference 4 - 5 August 2014, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-56-6 “bank runs that lead to the closure, merging, or takeover by the public sector of one or more financial institutions” or the “closure, merging, takeover or large-scale government assistance of an important financial institution (or group of institutions) that marks the start of similar outcomes for other financial institutions” (p.11). Our research shows that this occurs every 18 years, following the peaking of the 18 year real estate cycle. viii A measure of broad money (M4) has been used following the insight, now confirmed by the Bank of England (2014), that private banks are largely responsible for creating an economy‟s money supply. Any use of a broad money supply measure would suffice for this analysis. Ideally, one would also capture the flow bank credit to the FIRE sector as an additional piece of analysis. ix The process by which the start and end of recessions are dated has generated a literature in itself. I follow the general rule of thumb that is often used by academics and commentators – that is, two consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth. x This was a manufacturing led recession owing to the strong pound (boosted by North Sea oil revenues) and the need to tackle high inflation. The upward movement of interest rates, high borrowing costs and relatively low costs of imports caused many manufacturing companies to fail. This recession, while significant in terms of lost output, did not implicate the banking system unlike the cyclical recession to take place approximately ten years later, in 1990-92. xi In this section and the ones that follow, for the sake of brevity, I have provided the data only for the UK and made a comment where the picture for the US is significantly different. xii In Table 2, the stock market fall (peak to low), real house price fall (peak to low), lending or money supply growth (peak to low) and yield curve (inversion to most positive sloped, i.e. widest spread) have been taken as indicators of the length of the downturn. At the end of the periods indicated by these variables, stock market or house prices start to rise again, lending picks up or the yield curve moves back into more „normal‟ territory – i.e. there is an improvement in economic conditions and a return to economic growth. xiv Harrison (1983) demonstrates that the Japanese experience from 1990 was an equivalent 18 year cyclical peak. Anderson (2008) argues that the East Asian financial crisis that started in 1997 was the cyclical peak for the economies of that region. Certainly, in both cases, there was a massive run up in real estate prices and speculation, aided by loose lending practices, prior to the ensuing crises and downturns. 19