Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference

advertisement
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
Studying the Effect of Information Availability on Carbon
Dioxide Emissions Level in Developing Countries
Hoda Hassaballa*
Recently, more concerns are raised regarding the rise of pollution
emissions level and the loss of environmental quality. This is even
magnified in the case of developing countries. In the literature, the
traditional determinants of pollution emissions level are income per-capita
levels, manufacturing value added, population and trade openness.
Knowledge and information availability can also, affect pollution emissions
level. This is present in three levels: First, through the underestimation of
the pollution emission levels by self-reporting firms resulting into a principalagent problem. Accordingly, correct penalties will not be imposed by the
government on polluting firms. This will result into higher levels of pollution
emissions. Second, firms who have access to information about the
environmentally friendly techniques of production that are cost effective are
more likely to have low levels of pollution and to abide by the legal
standard. Third, through the spread of information about polluting firms
and/or products, firms are keener to reduce their pollution emissions level
in order not to lose public acceptance. However, empirical analyses that
examine the effect of information availability on pollution emissions level
are not comprehensive. To fill this gap, this research paper studies the
effect of information availability on per capita carbon dioxide emissions
level in developing countries over the period 1995-2013. A fixed effects
panel data model is used. The results indicate that information availability is
a significant determinant of per capita carbon dioxide emissions level. In
addition, the results confirm the usage of polluting techniques of production
as displayed by the positive significant coefficients of income per-capita
and the trend term. Policy implications to reduce pollution emissions level
are also given.
JEL Codes: O3 and Q5.
1. Introduction
There is a global concern about the rising pollution emissions level in particular and the
loss of environmental quality in general. Global warming, the rise of sea level, the loss of
biodiversity and deforestation are among the main problems that threaten our planet
earth. The situation is even worse in developing countries that usually rely on traditional
dirty techniques of production and erroneous consumption patterns. As a result, many
researchers directed their efforts to study the determinants of pollution emissions level. In
the literature, the commonly used determinants of these emissions level are income percapita level, trade openness, population growth and manufacturing value added (Mihci et
al, 2005; Cole, 2007; Hassaballa, 2015(A)). However, knowledge and information
availability can also affect the level of pollution emissions. This is found in three levels:
*Dr.Hoda Hassaballa is a Lecturer of Economics at The Department of Economics, Faculty of Business
Administration, Economics and Political Science, The British University in Egypt. Address: Sewis Desert
Road, Sherouk City, Cairo 11837, P.O. Box 43, Egypt. Email: hoda.hassaballa@bue.edu.eg,
Mobile: +201001101974. Fax: +202 26300010 / 20.
1
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
First, through the underestimation of the pollution emission levels by self-reporting firms
resulting into a principal-agent problem. This happens when the agent (polluter) has
access to information about his pollution emissions level which the princpal (the
government) does not have. Accordingly, incorrect penalties will be imposed by the
government on polluting firms. This will result into higher levels of pollution emissions. This
may occur when it is costly or difficult to measure environmental variables. Second, firms
who have access to information about the environmentally friendly techniques of
production that are cost effective are more likely to have low levels of pollution and to
abide by the legal standard. Hence, access to information will give these firms a superior
position. Third, through the spread of information about polluting firms and/or products,
firms are keener to reduce their pollution emissions level in order not to lose public
acceptance. This has been facilitated by the recent developments in information
technology in general and the spread of the internet usage in particular. Nevertheless, the
empirical investigation on the effect of information availabilty on pollution emissions level
in developing countries are incomplete. To fill this gap, this research paper studies the
effect of information availability on per capita carbon dioxide emissions level in developing
countries over the period 1995-2013. A fixed effects panel data model is used.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section 2 provides the theoretical and
empirical review. Section 3 describes the methodology and the empirical model used.
Section 4 shows the main findings and finally, section 5 concludes and presents the
corresponding policy implications.
2. Literature Review
For a long period, it was generally assumed in the mainstream economics that information
is complete. This was apparent in the work of Debreu (1959) and Arrow (1964) on the
competitive general equilibrium theory. However, this assumption has proven to be
unrealistic which resulted into the evolution of the economics of information. According to
Stiglitz (2000), the most important development in economics in the contemporary period
is the economics of information. This is because it has altered the general belief of perfect
information, has shown that information can be costly and has highlighted the effects of
asymmetric information on firms’ and individuals’ decisions (Stiglitz ,2000).
Many researchers contributed in this field as early as Pool (1984) who tried to measure
the flow of information as well as Machlup (1962) and Porat (1978) who concentrated on
measuring the value of information. However, due to the absence of a general agreement
on how to define information, these attempts were mainly theoretical and were directed
towards measuring the effects of information instead (Bates, 1985). There is an on-going
debate in the literature on whether information is a private or a public good. On one side,
Boulding (1966), Demsetz (1967), Marshall (1974) and Stigler (1983) have claimed that
information is a private good especially if it is additional information related to a market
due to economic benefits incurred. On the other side, many others such as Samuelson
(1954; 1958) have believed that information is a public good since its consumption by one
individual does not prevent others from enjoying the same benefit.
The debate is also present in information valuation. The inability to value information
correctly could result into its violation of the economic premise of social efficiency
(Arrow1962; Hall, 1981). The reason behind this is the uniqueness of information in which
2
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
there is a degree of uncertainty in outcome and exchange of information goods (Bates,
1985). In addition, information as a good is distinctive in its multiple replications with
almost no cost as well as its acquisition is non-excludable (Bates, 1981). This resulted
into the violation of the condition of optimality and efficiency in which marginal cost should
be equal to marginal revenue of a good. However, Coase (1974) counter-attacked this
argument by highlighting that information is like any economic good. This is because its
value is determined by the expected value of its use which results into a fixed value at the
end. It is true that there is a degree of variability that arises from different tastes and
preferences (Bates,1985). Yet, this is also present in any other economic good. Hence, it
can be concluded that there are many debatable issues in the field of economics of
information that require lots of future research.
The link between economics of information and environmental economics is present in the
regulatory side. Theoretically, there are three different regulatory approaches of pollution
emissions level namely, command-and-control approach, economic incentive approach
and non-mandatory approach. Each of these regulates the pollution emissions level from
a different perspective. For instance, the command-and-control approach sets the
government responsible for regulating pollution emissions level. It puts a standard that
polluting firms should abide by. The regulatory authority is also in charge of deciding on
the type of technology used, inspection, monitoring pollution emissions level and setting
the appropriate penalties for exceeding the legal emissions limit (Tietenberg,1990).
Command-and control approach is preferred when the pollution emissions are very toxic,
marginal benefit of decreasing pollution emissions level is extremely inelastic or the
marginal abatement cost curves (MAC) are the same for all firms to be easily deducted by
the government (Hassaballa, 2015(B)). On the other hand, command-and-control
approach is usually criticized of lack of efficiency, rigidity which discourages the polluting
firms from compliance and the occurrence of principle-agent problem. The latter happens
when the agent (polluter) has access to information about his pollution emissions level
which the princpal (the government) does not have.1 Accordingly, incorrect penalties will
be imposed by the government on polluting firms. This will result into higher levels of
pollution emissions. This may occur when it is costly or difficult to measure environmental
variables. Hence, information availability plays an essential role in determining the
pollution emsiisons level.
On the other hand, the economic incentive approach is more flexible. According to this
regulatory approach, the polluting firms are competing to decide on the best technique of
production that is cost effective and reduces pollution emissions level. Hence, the firms
are free to decide on the suitable technique they use as long as they abide by the legal
standard. In addition, firms are rewarded if their pollution emissions level is below the legal
limit (Blackman, 2006, and Tietenberg, 1990). Permits and fees are the two main policies
used under economic incentive approach. Again, the role of information here is very
important. This is because the government can choose the use of economic incentive
approach due to lack of knowledge of the suitable technique of production that reduces
pollution emissions level. In addition, firms who have access to information about the
environmentally friendly techniques of production that are cost effective are more likely to
have low levels of pollution and to abide by the legal standard. Hence, access to
information will give these firms a superior position which enables them to pay fewer fees
and enjoy additional rewards. Not only this, but also information is important because
emission fees system will not be successful unless the government has the capability of
3
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
deciding on the correct amount of fees to be charged. In many developing countries,
knowing the correct fees is constrained by lack of efficient technical, administrative and
managerial systems. In case of permits, this problem is not present as prices of permits
are set by the market which entails that any violation of such market mechanism will
render the economic incentive approach ineffective.
Lastly, the non-mandatory approach regulates pollution emissions level through voluntary
actions of polluting firms. In the absence of regulations, firms will not voluntary adopt any
measure of pollution control unless it is in their interest (Storey and McCabe, 1999). This
occurs when firms are threatened by penalties costs, market pressures and public
pressures. All these push firms to take self-regulation actions towards pollution control.
The role of information is also vital here. This happens when firms are afraid of losing
public acceptance as a result of the release of environmental information about these
firms (Khanna and Anton, 2002). Theoretically, each firm will compare the costs of public
disclosure of ‘‘bad’’ information to the abatement costs that the firm incur to be labelled by
the public as green producer (Konar and Cohen,1997). Nowadays, consumers have an
increasing demand of a cleaner environment and this will affect their choices of products.
Thus, firms are keener to reduce their pollution emissions level in order not to lose public
acceptance and to capture a wider market share.
After this theoretical review of different regulatory approaches of emissions level, it is
apparent that information availability affects deeply pollution emissions level which in turn
reflects the strong link between economics of information and environmental economics.
On the empirical level, many studies such as Terkla (1984), Dudek and Palmisano (1988),
Feldman and Raufer (1987) and Tietenberg (1989) compared command-and-control
approach to economic incentive approach. Their findings were mainly that efficiency gains
are achieved when economic incentive approach is used. This is because economic
incentive approach provides incentive to firms to compete and innovate to reach the best
technology with minimum cost. Dudek and Palmisano (1988) showed that this is also true
in practice; however, the size of innovations is not large. In addition Feldman and Raufer
(1987) and Tietenberg (1989) showed that economic incentive approach has another main
advantage which is absent in command-and-control approach, namely, leasing credits.
With respect to non-mandatory approach, many empirical studies were carried out such
as Khanna (2001), Dasgupta et al. (2000), Videras and Alberini (2000) and Henriques and
Sadorsky (1996). In parallel to the theoretical studies, these empirical studies also showed
that the chief motivation of firms to take voluntary control of pollution is their expectation to
make profit. Since this will be in the firms’ interest, it will be self-enforced. The effects of
regulatory threats, past environmental performance, desire for public recognition and size
of the firms were empirically examined and quantified.
To the author knowledge, very little empirical research was conducted to examine
explicitly the effect of information availability on pollution emissions level. For example,
Khanna (2001) and Banerjee et al. (2003) studied the effect of public pressure on joining
non-mandatory approach. Their results showed that it was significantly and positively
affecting the motivation of firms to join non-mandatory approach. It is apparent here that
while doing so, the effect of information availability was implicitly studied. In line with that,
others like Arora and Gangopadhyay (1995) and Kennedy et al. (1994) have studied the
4
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
effect of information on consumer or firm behaviour. Moreover, Hamilton (1995) and
Konar and Cohen (1997) examined the behaviour of firms in response to a significant
stock market reaction as a result of disclosure of information through the toxic release
inventory (TRI). Their results confirmed that firms that had the largest decrease in their
stock prices on the day of the release of TRI later decreased their emissions more than
other firms in the industry. This shows how information availability implicitly affects
pollution emissions level through its effect on stock prices.
Finally, Foulon et al. (1999) studied the effect of disclosure of information about polluting
firms on emissions levels and degree of compliance. This was done through examining
the effect of the release of British Columbia’s list of polluters on pollution emissions level.
Their results indicated that the effect of disclosure of information about polluting firms on
pollution emissions level and compliance is greater than that of fees or penalties.
After this theoretical and empirical review, it becomes evident that information availability
affects the level of pollution emissions. Nevertheless, empirical analysis that explicitly
measures such an effect is rare to find. For that, this research paper constitutes a step
forward to have a better understanding of the explicit effect of information availability on
pollution emissions level.
3. The Methodology and Model
The empirical model investigates the effect of information availability on per-capita carbon
dioxide emissions level based on the econometric work of Cole (2007). A dynamic panel
data model is used to examine the effects of information availability, per-capita income,
trade openness, manufacturing, population growth and technical progress on per-capita
carbon dioxide emissions in developing countries over the period 1995-2013 for which
data is available. First difference is used instead of logs due to the presence of negative
observations.
3.1 The Econometric Approach
The following fixed effects panel data model with homogenous slopes is considered:
EM
it
  INFit  
X
it

EM
it 1
  i  T i   it
(1)
For country i at time t, EM is the per-capita carbon dioxide emissions measured in metric
tons per capita; INF is the measure of information availability; X is a vector of explanatory
variables that affect emissions level other than information availability; λ is the fixed effect
dummy variable for individual unobserved effects, T is a trend term and ε is the error term.
There are many benefits of using a panel data set such as the increase of the sample size
resulting in a better estimation and the increase of the power of the test statistics. Hence,
it is chosen instead of cross section or time series sets.
3.2 The Choice of Variables
To measure the effect of information availability on pollution emissions level, the number
of internet users is used. According to Wu (2011), internet access results into a more
transparent society in which information becomes available to different economic agents
5
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
including consumers, producers and the government. Hence, it can be used as a source
of public access to information on polluting firms. In addition, the internet can supply firms
with the most up-to-date techniques that can be used to reduce their emissions level. In a
nutshell, the internet makes information available at a very low cost. Not only this, but
because the majority of contributors to the internet are the people and not the
governments, this results into a high degree of transparency (Wu, 2011). Hence, it can be
used as a proxy measure of information availability. Furthermore, it was used before by
other researches such as Bernhard (1993), Hanson (2008), Schroth and Sharma (2003)
and Wu (2011). It is expected to have a negative relationship between the number of
internet users and pollution emissions level. The logic behind this is that the more
available the information is, reflected by the number of internet users, the less the level of
pollution emissions will be.
In addition to information availability, the traditional determinants of pollution emissions
level such as per capita income level, manufacturing value added, population growth and
trade openness are used to investigate their effects on pollution emissions level (Mihici,
2005; Cole, 2007; Hassaballa, 2015(A)). The effect of income on pollution emissions level
is tested through the use of per capita income. There will be a negative relationship
between pollution emissions and per capita income in the case of usage of
environmentally friendly techniques of production. Contrary to this, this relationship will be
positive illustrating the case of usage of traditional dirty techniques of production. This is
also true in the case of manufacturing value added in which the share of industry in GDP
is measured to examine the effect of manufacturing on pollution emissions level. The
reason behind this is that manufacturing always carries the burden of increasing pollution
emissions level. Accordingly, the nature of the relationship is still indefinite. Population
growth can be also used to determine pollution emissions level. Larger population
overburdens environmental resources and leads to higher levels of consumption and
wastes. Hence, population growth and pollution emissions level exhibit a positive
relationship. Lastly, trade openness, calculated through the sum of exports and imports to
GDP, is used. This is because trade liberalization also affects pollution emissions level.
Similarly, the nature of the relationship is indistinct as it depends on the type of traded
goods.
Carbon dioxide per capita is used to measure pollution emissions level. Carbon dioxide is
a valid measure for pollution emissions since it is the main source of global warming.
Furthermore, it is widely used by many researchers such as Yaung (2001) and HoltzEakin and Selden (1995). In addition, there is a strong correlation between carbon dioxide
and other pollutants.2 Lagged value of carbon dioxide emissions level is used to test
whether there is persistence or correction of emissions. A trend term is also used to
reflect technical progress over time. The sources of data are the World Development
Indicators database. Missing data were calculated through the use of linear interpolation.
3.3 Estimation
To examine the effect of information availability on pollution emissions level, a dynamic
panel data model is used. The sample studied includes 25 developing countries over the
period 1995-2013.3 Hausman test between random effects and fixed effects models was
carried out. The results showed that fixed effects model is more adequate as a result of
the rejection of random effects model. Hence, fixed effects panel data model is used as
6
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
indicated in equation 1. Table (1) shows the results of the panel least square estimation of
equation 1 in which at time t in country i,  carbon dioxide emissions measured in metric
ton per capita (CO2) is regressed on the change of its lagged value,  information (Inf)
measured by the number of internet users (per 100 people),  per capita income (Y), 
manufacturing value added (MANU),  population growth (pop),  trade openness (TO)
and a trend term.
4. The Findings
The empirical results illustrated in table (1) indicate that information availability is not a
significant determinant of carbon dioxide emissions level. In addition, the coefficients of
all other variables are found insignificant with the exception of lagged carbon dioxide
emissions and income per capita. The coefficient of lagged carbon dioxide emissions is
found significant and negative at 5% level. This shows that there is correction of pollution
emissions over time. As for income per-capita, its coefficient is found significant and
positive reflecting the use of polluting techniques in production. These two results are
contradictory. In addition, the results of information availability, trade and population seem
not meaningful especially if you relate that to developing countries. Accordingly, white test
for heteroskedasticity was used. The results of the White test indicated the presence of
heteroskedasticity. To correct for this, generalized least squares (GLS) weights and White
correction were used as a robust check. The results of these estimations are shown in
table (2) and table (3) respectively.
Table 1: Empirical Results of Equation 1a
Dependent Variable
 CO2
 Inf
Y
 MANU
 TO
 Pop
Trend
 Co2(-1)
Constant
a
R Squared
Coefficients
-0.009859
(-1.658664)
0.000213
(2.210468)*
0.004941
(0.502958)
0.000288
(0.173208)
0.258598
(1.979953)
0.005328
(1.584728)
-0.111997
(-2.244220)*
-0.018453
(-0.508041)
0.0856
t- values are in parentheses
* Significance at 5% level
7
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
Table 2: Empirical Results of Equation 1 (GLS)
Dependent Variable
 CO2
 Inf
Y
 MANU
 TO
 Pop
Trend
 Co2(-1)
Constant
R Squared
Coefficients
-0.005867
(-2.309365)*
0.000394
(7.010905)**
-0.006118
(-1.254066)
0.001325
(1.630289)
0.077479
(1.026656)
0.002725
(2.864668)**
-0.107330
(-1.482642)
-0.023935
(-2.328432)
0.206038
a
t- values are in parentheses
* Significant at 5% level
**Significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels
Table 3: Empirical Results of Equation 1 (White Correction)
Dependent Variable
 CO2
 Inf
Y
 MANU
 TO
 Pop
Trend
 Co2(-1)
Constant
R Squared
Coefficients
-0.005867
(-2.059542)*
0.000394
(7.118890)**
-0.006118
(-1.517632)
0.001325
(1.511496)
0.077279
(1.069211)
0.002725
(2.230773)*
-0.107330
(-1.989394)
-0.023935
(-1.993573)
0.206038
a
t- values are in parentheses
* Significant at 5% level
**Significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels
8
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
After applying general least squares weights and White correction, the empirical results of
equation 1 show that information availability is a significant determinant of pollution
emissions level. This is because its coefficient is found significant and negative. This
indicates that information availability decreases pollution emissions level in developing
countries. In addition, income per-capita has a positive significant coefficient. This
indicates the prevalence of polluting techniques of production in developing countries.
This moves in line with the result of the trend term. The trend term is found significant and
positive which indicates that there is deterioration of the control of pollution emissions over
time. Hence, contradictory results have been eliminated. All other explanatory variables
are found insignificant which can altered in the future by increasing the sample size. It is
important to highlight that R squared is relatively low. However, this can be expected in
dynamic fixed effects panel data model.
5. Conclusion and Policy Implications
This research paper studied the effect of information availability on pollution emissions
level. This was conducted in a dynamic panel data model. A fixed effects panel data
model was used for a sample of developing countries over the period 1995-2013. The
empirical results highlighted that information availability has an influential effect on
pollution emissions level. In addition, there is a negative relationship between information
availability and pollution emissions level. Furthermore, positive correlation between
economic growth and pollution emissions level was detected. Since, this was also the
case for the trend term, it becomes apparent that developing countries rely heavily on
polluting techniques of production and lack the needed attention to apply appropriate
pollution control measures. These findings necessitate designing appropriate policy
implications that would enhance environmental quality and reduce pollution emissions
level in developing countries. These include:
1. Incorporate environmental objectives with economic objectives and reflect that in
various governments’ plans and actions.
2. Enforce stringent environmental laws through the adoption of a comprehensive
system of inspection, monitoring and measurements of pollution emissions level by
developing countries’ governments. This is to minimize the occurrence of principalagent problem and to ensure that pollution fees are calculated correctly.
3. Ensure compliance through the application of the ‘carrot and stick’ principle. That is to
provide incentives to firms in the form of financial, technical and managerial
assistance to ensure compliance. At the same time, impose penalties on polluting
firms that do not abide by the legal standard.
4. Monitor and assess polluting firms’ activities to announce that to the public in regular
publications. Make these information available through different media channels
whether formal or informal ones.
5. Spread awareness among consumers and producers about the real threats that our
environment faces in the absence of pollution emissions correction scheme.
6. Learn about successful stories of different countries that managed to reduce their
pollution emissions level to judge its applicability.
7. Be updated with new techniques of production that are cost effective and at the same
time environmentally friendly.
9
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
8. Ban giving licences to new polluting firms and design a time frame to old polluting
firms to adjust their emissions level accordingly or else their licences will be
withdrawn.
9. Choose the most suitable regulatory approach to the country’s financial, technical,
administrative and institutional capacities to ensure its success.
All in all, it is very essential to preserve our environmental resources and to avoid its
depletion. Any legislation or action necessary to achieve that should be implemented.
This should be set as a number one priority in developing countries in particular in order to
ensure sustainable development and to provide a healthy way of life to many generations
to come. Perhaps for that, we will be remembered.
End Notes
1. For adverse selection problems related to environmental regulations, see, for example,
Sheriff (2009) and Quillérou (2010).
2. Hoffmann et al. (2005) highlighted that the correlation coefficients of carbon dioxide with
nitrous oxide and sulfur dioxide are 0.9529 and 0.9536 respectively.
3. These countries are Albania, Angola, Argentina, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Belize, Brazil,
Columbia, Costa Rica, Cuba, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Hungary, India, Indonesia,
Jordan, Macedonia, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, South Africa, Tunisia, Ukraine and
Venezuela
References
Arora, S. and Gangopadhyay, S. 1995, Towards a theoretical model of voluntary overCompliance, Journal of Economic Behavior Organization, Vol.2, pp.289-309.
Arrow, K. 1962, ‘Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention’ in The
rate and direction of economic activity: economic and social factors.
Universities-National Bureau for Economic Research Conference series, Princeton.
Arrow, K. 1964, The role of securities in the optimal allocation of risk bearing, Review of
Economic Studies, Vol. 31, pp.91-96.
Banerjee, S.B., Lyer, E.S. and Kashyap, R.K.. 2003, Corporate environmentalism:
antecedents and influence of industry type, Journal of Marketing, Vol.67, pp.106122.
Bates, B. 1985, ‘Information as an economic good: A re-evaluation of theoretical
Approaches’, the 35th Annual Conference International Communication
Association, Honolulu.
Bernhard, N.E. 1993, ‘Ready, willing, able: Network television news and the federal
government 1948-1953.’ In: W.S. Solomon and R.W. McChesney, Editors,
Ruthless criticism: New perspectives in U. S. communication history, University of
Minnesota Press, Minneapolis, pp. 291–312.
10
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
Blackman, A. 2006, Economic incentives to control water pollution in developing countries:
how well has Colombia’s wastewater discharge fee program worked and why?
Resources, Vol. 161, pp. 21-23.
Boulding, K. 1966, The economics of knowledge and the knowledge of economics,
American Economic Review, Vol.56, pp.1-13.
Coase, R. H. 1974, The market for goods and the market for ideas, American Economic
Review. Vol. 64, pp.384-391.
Cole, M. A. 2007, Corruption, income and the environment: an empirical analysis,
Ecological Economics, Vol.62, pp.637-647.
Dasgupta, S., Hettige, H. and Wheeler, D.2000, What improves environmental
compliance? evidence from Mexican industry, Journal of Environmental Economics
and Management, Vol.39, pp.39-66.
Debreu, G. 1958, The theory of value. John Wiley & Sons, New York.
Demsetz, H. 1967, Toward a theory of property rights, American Economic Review, Vol.
59, pp.347-359.
Dudek, D. J. and Palmisano, J. 1988, Emissions trading: why is this throughbred
hobbled? Columbia Journal of Environmental Law, Vol.13, pp. 217-256.
Feldman, S. L. and Raufer, R.K. 1987, Emissions trading and acid rain implementing a
market approach to pollution control, Rowman & Littlefield., Totowa, N.J.
Foulon, J., Lanoie, P. and Laplante, B.1999, Incentives for pollution control: Regulation or
and information. Centre Interuniverstaire De Recherche En Analyse Des
Organisations, Montreal.
Hall, K. 1981, The economic nature of information, Information Society, Vol.1, pp.143-166.
Hamilton, J.T. 1995, Pollution as news : Media and stock market reactions to the toxics
release inventory data, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
Vol.28, pp.98-113.
Hanson, E.C. 2008, The information revolution and world politics. Rowman & Littlefield,
Lanham, MD.
Hassaballa, H. 2015(A), The effect of corruption on carbon dioxide emissions in the
MENA region, European Journal of Sustainable Development, Vol.4, pp.301-312.
Hassaballa, H. 2015(B). ‘Different regulatory approaches of emissions: theory and
practice’, In: Sharma, U.C, Prasad, R. and Sivakumar, S.(Eds.), Energy Science and
Technology: Opportunities and Challenges, Vol.1, Studium Press LLC, USA.
11
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
Henriques, I. and Sadorsky, P.1996, The determinants of an environmentally responsive
firm: an empirical approach, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
Vol.30, pp.381-395.
Hoffmann, R., Lee, C., Ramasamy, B. and Yeung M. 2005, FDI and pollution: a Granger
causality test using panel data, Journal of International Development, Vol.17, pp.311317.
Holtz-Eakin, D and Selden, T. 1995, Stoking the fires? Co2 emissions and economic
growth. Journal of Public Economics, Vol.57, pp.85–101.
Kennedy, P.W., Laplante, B., and Maxwell, J. 1994, Pollution policy : the role of publicly
provided information, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol.26,
pp.31-43.
Khanna, M. 2001, Non mandatory approaches to environmental protection, Journal of
Economic surveys, Vol.15, pp.291-324.
Khanna, M. and Anton, W. 2002, Corporate environmental management:
regulatory and market-based incentives, Land Economics, Vol.78, pp.539-558.
Konar, S. and Cohen, M. 1997, Information as regulation: The effect of community right
to know laws on toxic emissions, Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, Vol. 32, pp. 109-124.
Machlup, F. 1962, The production and distribution of knowledge in the United States.
Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Marshall, J. 1974, Private incentives and public information, American Economic Review.
Vol.64, pp.373-390.
Mihci, H., Cagatay, S and Koska, O. 2005, The impact of environmental stringency on the
foreign direct investment of the OECD countries, Journal of Environmental
Assessment Policy and Management, Vol. 7, pp.679-704.
Pool, I. 1984,Tracking the flow of Information, Science, Vol. 221, pp.609-613.
Porat, M. 1978, Global implications of an information society, Journal of Communication,
Vol. 28, pp.70-80
Quillérou, E. and Fraser, R. 2010, Adverse selection in the environmental
stewardship scheme: Does the higher level stewardship scheme design reduce
adverse selection? The Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 61, pp.369-380.
Samuelson, P. 1954, The pure theory of public expenditures, Review of Economics and
Statistics, Vol.36, pp.387-389.
12
Proceedings of Annual Switzerland Business Research Conference
12 - 13 October 2015, Novotel Geneva Centre, Geneva, Switzerland
ISBN: 978-1-922069-86-3
Samuelson, P. 1958, Aspects of public expenditure theories, Review of Economics and
Statistics. Vol.40, pp.332-338.
Schroth, P.W. and Sharma, P. 2003, Transnational law and technology as potential forces
against corruption, Management Decision, Vol. 41, pp. 296–303.
Sheriff, G. 2009, Implementing second-best environmental policy under
adverse selection, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol.57,
pp.253- 268.
Stigler, G. 1983, ‘The economics of information’. In George Stigler, The organization of
industry. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Stiglitz, J.E. 2000, The contributions of the economics of information to twentieth century
economics, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, pp.1441-1478.
Storey, D.J. and McCabe, P.J. 1980, The criminal waste discharger, Scottish Journal Of
Political Economy, Vol.27, pp.30-40.
Terkla, D. 1984, The efficiency value of effluent tax revenues, Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, Vol.11, pp.107-123.
The World Development Indicators (http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/worlddevelopment-indicators)
Tietenberg, T.H. 1989, Acid rain reduction credits, Challenge, Vol.32, pp.25-29.
Tietenberg, T.H. 1990, Economic instruments for environmental regulation, Oxford Review
of Economic Policy, Vol.6, pp.17- 33.
Videras, J. and Alberini, A. 2000, The appeal of voluntary environmental programs: which
firms participate and why? Contemporary Economic Policy, Vol. 18, pp.449-461.
Wu, W. 2011, Internet Technology and Its Impact on Corruption, A Senior Honors Thesis,
University of California, San Diego.
Yaung H. 2001, Trade liberalization and pollution: a general equilibrium analysis of carbon
dioxide emissions in Taiwan. Economic Modelling, Vol.18,pp.435–454.
13
Download