1 STOREP ANNUAL CONFERENCE. GAETA, 31 May – 2 June, 2013 HOW MUCH IS TOO MUCH: DIFFERENT APPROACHES TO CONSUMPTION AND LEISURE Title: Luxury Goods and Global Economic History 1600-1900 1. Luxury and Economic History: Paradoxes. Luxury spending in recent decades has been closely associated with globalization. But luxury spending has a long and deep history, and one associated from very early periods with long-distance trade. Luxury goods have always been of obvious significance to historians of the prehistoric, ancient and medieval worlds. Andrew and Susan Sherratt followed those mundane bronze age beakers that travelled in the slipstream of the gold, silver and precious jewels that traversed Eurasia in 2000 B.C.. But Immanuel Wallerstein dismissed these luxury goods as mere preciosities on the route to modernization from the early modern world, and few economic historians of the 18thC to modern world give them any regard at all. Indeed luxury has only periodically attracted the notice of economists. Economic theory has traditionally regarded such goods as exceptions; economic historians have followed in perceiving such goods as relating only to the consumption of elites, and therefore not central to their concerns. Donald Winch has commented that even the mass consumer society which emerged in the later nineteenth and twentieth centuries had little influence on the thinking of professional economists. It did affect the dissidents and those of heterodox views; Veblen, Ruskin, and Hobson introduced discussion of ‘conspicuous consumption’, they discussed pathologies of consumption and ‘underconsumption’. The key text stimulating this conference, Keynes’ Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren, in 1929, predicted that rising productivity meant that a fifteen hour work week would suffice to provide most with their necessities and most of the superfluities they desired. But goods in the meantime were upgraded, quality differences extended, luxury branding developed, and new products invented. This process responded to psychological and sociological characteristics of status differentiation that made the demand for quality universal and inexhaustible. 2 Keynes ignored the creation of new and endlessly variable consumer goods that would continue to motivate individuals to earn enough to afford them. Consumption of material goods was also habit-forming. A consumer, excited by a new product, once its possessor quickly became accustomed to it, and moved on to aspire after the next thing. Consumer choice becomes the key marker of social inclusion and exclusion. Aspirations are associated with luxury and designer goods, with lifestyle choices of affluence and distinction. Manufacturers brand their products, seeking to obscure homogeneity. They give nearly every category of good they produce a premium brand; their products signal distinction and the pursuit of status. Recently the economist, A.K. Sen and the economic historian, Avner Offer have addressed the relationship between consumption and well-being. Sen has put forward the idea of adequacy rather than abundance in his concept of ‘capabilities and functionings’. Goods basic to well-being are those connected to nutrition, living space, clean water, sanitation, education and health care. Indeed the US with the highest income per head in the world scored fourteenth on the Human Development index of 2008 which took into account these goods of well-being. Both have argued that well-being requires social connection and inter-personal regard. Well being is not about maximizing the short-term arousal provided by maximum consumption, but about balancing consumption to a level of optimal satisfaction. (Offer, ‘Consumption and Well-being’ in Trentmann, Oxford Handbook on Consumption, pp. 658-660). And yet luxury has become a new issue of the late twentieth and twenty-first centuries, associated as it is with rising social and global inequalities, and environmental destruction. This luxury spending in recent years has also globalized. Many of those desirable and distinctive goods, from crafted fashion textiles to tropical holidays, have been produced in poor parts of the world for high-income earners in the West. New systems of ‘fast fashion’ rely on farflung sites of production. But new wealth generated in the rapid growth trajectories of the last ten years in China, India, and South-East Asia has created new groups of the super-rich and of aspirant middle classes. This current phase of luxury spending is also a phase of critique, of retrenchment, and recycling in face of environmental change, and of luxury taxes. Luxury in the age of globalization bears close parallels to the later seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, leading into industrialization in Europe. Then too luxury expenditure emerged in a global context. The East and Asia then had a very specific place in Europe’s new luxuries; the populations of China, Japan, India, South east Asia and Africa were then affected by factors of global consumption and trade, just as current populations are. There is thus good 3 reason why economists and economic historians should give it close consideration. My research has argued that the first phase of long-distance maritime trade from Asia to Europe in tea, silk, cotton and porcelain transformed European consumer and material cultures, in turn stimulating the product imitation and innovation that led onto Europe’s own industrialization. Europe’s luxury was about trade in fine goods with the wider world, and especially with Asia. My focus is on the Asian provenance of those goods rather than on American sourced colonial groceries: sugar, chocolate, coffee and tobacco in changing the diets and food practices of Europeans. Asia’s luxury goods did more than this: they changed the clothing, household domestic and display practices, and above all, industries of Europe. The exotic in those luxury goods associated with longdistance sea voyages and East India Companies continued, for many Europeans, to depict the meaning of Empire through the nineteenth century. Arindam Dutta in his The Bureaucracy of Beauty has written ‘Economists may bristle, but empire is about taste: gold, silver, spices, silk, tea, textiles, the view, furniture, opium, coffee, bananas, paisley, arabesques....’ Eastern Luxuries There is a long history connecting luxury with foreign imports, and this passed into the mercantilist debates of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. Ancient luxuries were associated with sociable settings for the display of precious goods. The ancient Greek symposia displayed and used gold and silver drinking vessels and wine craters. Wealthy merchants and elites in Renaissance Italy conveyed their status through a taste in ancient oriental ceramics, imitated in fine majolica and in silverware and glass. But it was not just imports, but imports from the East that gave luxury its particular caché in the later seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. Silk was Europe’s classic ancient luxury import from China. The fabled Silk Route conveyed all manner of luxury and other goods, but silk marked its identity with exotic luxury. Chinese silk continued to be imported into Europe throughout the early modern period and the eighteenth century, though Italy had long become the major producer for the West from the fifteenth century onwards. By the later seventeenth century there were new imports of cotton calicoes and muslins, of porcelain and lacquerware. These attained great popularity during the eighteenth century, and were soon imported in large quantities by Europe’s East India Companies and sold as decent, high-quality semi-luxuries available in a wide range of patterns, styles, qualities, and prices. 4 Asian models also stimulated Europeans to produce their own imitations in both production processes, designs, and marketing strategies. For Asian luxury goods were highly successful transmitters of technology, designs, and aesthetics. Such goods transmitted cross-cultural characteristics across great distances. Porcelain services replaced silver plate during the European and civil wars. In Islamic lands they substituted for the gold and silver proscribed as materials for eating vessels under Koranic traditions. Indian calicoes adapted to tastes for chinoiserie, designs and markets adapted readily to an already established fashion for Chinese art. Merchants placed orders for patterns picked out on a white ground rather than the traditional Indian red or coloured backgrounds. Lacquerware furnishings had a seductive appeal, especially the cabinets with two doors enclosing a set of small (sometimes secret) drawers and a small central cupboard, a suitable vessel for holding ornamental and exotic collectables or secret and private correspondence and small or intimate treasures.i Luxury Debates The celebrated luxury debates of the eighteenth century focussed on cities and sexuality. Mandeville found a new cultural setting for luxury in populous cities where most individuals were unknown to one another. David Hume celebrated the ‘politeness’ that could develop in the enlarged public sphere of cities, and Adam Smith found in new towns and cities the middling class markets for new commodities created by industry and the division of labour. Markets for luxury fuelled by the vanity, fashion and sexuality of women were also educated in the senses and taste by women’s role in the civilizing process. The Eastern provenance of these luxury goods also aroused the interest of Europe’s savants, travellers, producers, and merchants. Enlightenment writers, natural historians, and travellers investigated and recounted the customs and manners of the peoples of the Middle East and North Africa, of China, India, and South-East Asia, including the cultures of the courts, the transformation during the early modern period of huge cities from Istanbul to Edo, and their varied and highly sophisticated consumer cultures drawing on all the world’s commodities. European curiosity in these cultures extended to investigation of production processes capable of supplying high domestic populations as well as extensive wider world trade in high-quality goods. Luxury goods, often perceived at the time as the master works of single craftsmen, were discovered to be the outputs of large-scale production units organized with intense division of labour, such as Jingdezhen, the porcelain city; or the composite products of a whole series of tribal, religious, and caste communities, again highly specialized through an intense division of labour. Yet the porcelain was harder and finer than any 5 European substitutes; writers marvelled at muslins so delicate they could hardly be seen, and cottons printed in unusual colour palettes with dyes unaccountably fixed. Acquiring Asian Goods The discovery of and desire for Asia’s luxuries were not the same as their possession. This required an enormous expansion in trade and distribution over the course of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. The rise of Europe’s East India Companies, monopolies to be sure, but competing with each other and considerably bolstered by significant private trade, brought more luxury goods to Europe, made them accessible to broader groups of the wealthy elites, and in Britain and the Netherlands to the middling and sometimes artisan classes. Such luxuries became cheaper relative to staples, thus increasing the relative incomes of the wealthy even as those of the poor declined. The Asia-Europe trade considerably developed the institutions and organization of international markets, and in the realms of economics, reduced transactions costs over the period. The East India Companies functioned as early versions of multinational corporations, both in developing markets for Asian luxury goods, and in organizing supply and shipping. Merchants developed and adapted designs in anticipation of European taste, and interacted in Asia with gobetweens, banyans and Hong merchants, using pattern books, textile swatches, musters and models to transmit to the manufacturing communities on the ground. They imported large quantities, judging quantities and markets on information gathered at the quarterly East India Company auction sales. Between 1500 and 1795 11,000 European ships set out for the Cape route to Asia – 8,000 returned – some were wrecked, but many of these 3,000 stayed for the intra-Asian trade. Tea, textiles, porcelain, lacquerware , furnishings, drugs and dyestuffs made for a systematic global trade carried in quantities which by the later eighteenth century came to 50,000 tons a year, as estimated by Jan de Vries. This made for just over one pound of Asian goods per person for a European population of roughly 100 million. If we look to textiles and porcelain alone, we see the prodigious amounts of these goods reaching Europe from the seventeenth century. Riello’s recent estimates show 1.3 million pieces of cotton textiles reaching Europe by the late 1680s, and 24.3 million pieces over the period 1665-1799. 1 The indicators for porcelain are similar. The British alone imported between 1 and 2 million pieces a year of Chinese porcelain by the early eighteenth century. The Dutch imported 43 million pieces from the beginning of the seventeenth century to the end of the 18th century. The English, French, 1 Giorgio Riello, Cotton: the Fabric that Changed the World (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2013), p. 6 Danish and Swedish companies imported another 30 million pieces; in one year 1777-8 European ships unloaded 700 tons of porcelain. A driving force in the extension of the China trade was the tea trade. Over the later seventeenth and the early eighteenth centuries tea imports increased steadily, amplified over the period by smuggling. By the 1770s smuggling dominated the tea trade; in 1783 legal tea in EIC warehouses was 5.9 millions lbs. and in the same year 7-8 million lbs. were smuggled in. The Tea Commutation Act reduced the duty from 119% to 12.5%, and legal tea in the warehouses rose to 16.3 million lbs in 1785, and 21 million pounds by 1800-1. We need also, however, to put the Asian trade in wider perspective. There was steady decadal growth of c. 1% per annum up to the estimated figure of 50,000 tons in the late eighteenth century; the trade was growing faster than Europe’s population, but not by a great deal. 50,000 tons could be fitted into one of today’s container ships. We can compare this with Europe’s growing trade with the New World – this grew at 2.2% per year, and the rise in the number of slaves transported from Africa to the New World also grew by 2.1% per annum. But yet these Asian imports by the mid eighteenth century were by no means marginal to the European economy. Jan de Vries estimates that another measure, the cumulative value of British, French and Dutch imports from Asia came to only 11.5% of their total aggregate imports. Imports from the Western Hemisphere were c. 30% of total imports; by value Europe’s imports from the Americas was nearly three times that from Asia.2 De Vries concludes that it is likely that the greatest impact of this trade was to stimulate new European consumer wants, and indeed it is striking that the growth of demand for almost every Asian commodity generated the search and development of alternate sources of supply outside Asia: Total Value of Imports to Britain, France, and the Dutch Republic in the 1770s (millions of guilders)3 Source of Imports of Total Imports Britain W.Hemisphere 32.3 57.4 71.9 Asia 24.2 8.6 2 3 France Jan de Vries, ‘The Limits of Globalization’, p. 728. Ibid., p. 729. Netherlands 22.4 20.0 Total % 151.7 52.8 11.2 7 Total 151.1 171.1 147.4 This 50,000 tons had a wide impact on European consumers. European consumption of non-European goods in the 1640s affected only the most elite consumers, and consisted mainly of pepper, spices and exotica. By the 1780s European households consumed annually non-European goods valued at 14-15 English shilling or 8 Dutch guilders per household for Europe’s c. 120 million. Of course this consumption was highly unequal by region and class, but its impact was high including reorganizing the structure and timing of meals, drawing poor and rural householders to the shops that were the only source of the goods, raising the utility of cash incomes, and providing a whole range of new goods for import tariffs and excise taxes. Wider Global Impact of the Asia trade Historians are now becoming aware of wide impact of Asian-sourced luxury goods on European consumption and even industrial structures. What is equally important, however, is the wide global impact of this trade. It affected Spanish America and China; India and Africa. As European trade with Ming and Qing China expanded, commercialization brought new luxury expenditure among the Chinese mercantile classes as well as the literati. Private kilns in Jingdezhen expanded to provide not just the blue and white export ware sold on world markets, but the diverse and high quality wares for urban domestic markets. The Manila galleon which brought Spanish-American silver into China’s domestic economy and fuelled her trade to the wider world also brought Chinese luxury goods, porcelain and silks into Acapulco and Manila to be traded not just on to Europe, but to the hinterlands of Spanish America. This was a sophisticated trade in Chinese goods especially geared to the elaborate and ornate consumer rituals of creole and Spanish cultures in Mexico and other parts of Spanish America. Equally, the European trade in Indian textiles was part of a wide Indian Ocean trade that affected India, Africa and South East Asia as much as it did Europe. The expansion of trade following on the East India Companies trade in the later 17th and early 18thC. suggest an impact in Bengal amounting to 40% of the growth in the region’s economy in that period. Bengal by the later 17thC. was India’s largest single manufacturing centre and entrepot for world trade; added to it were major export economies on the Coromandel coast and 8 Gujarat/Mahashtra. The Indian economy throughout this period of greatly expanded trade with Europe was highly commercialized. Highly specialized textile villages were fed and housed with goods from great distances. The raw cotton woven by Bengal weavers was transported from Gujarat. European trade in textiles also added to a substantial trade in Indian textiles to East and West Africa, a trade marked by sumptuary codes, by luxury and by rapid fashion changes. African consumer tastes dictated many varieties of textiles in East-Central and South-East African markets. Such textiles bestowed moral and social qualities; they were markers of high and low status. Indian weavers, brokers and merchant networks in the interior of Gujarat were very closely connected with the African consumers of their cloth. (Machedo, ‘Cloths of a new Fashion’ in Riello and Roy). Fashions changed swiftly and were negotiated between Gujarati Vaniya merchants and African middlemen . If we turn back to the impact of this Eastern trade on Europe, we see its wide effect on consumer cultures. The impact of the rapid growth of and considerable extent of this trade in luxury goods from Asia to Europe between the later seventeenth and later eighteenth century was to transform what Europeans formerly perceived as exotic Eastern curios into quality commodities in a great variety of designs and grades of fineness. The impact of that Asian luxury goods trade was furthermore to provide the model for consumer markets in Europe for quality goods that were not high luxuries for elites only. Luxury and Consumption: the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries Luxury consumption in early modern Europe, as in the social and cultural life of Asia, Africa, the Americas and the Pacific was constrained by sumptuary laws and codes or customs. The sumptuary laws imposed by European governments were directed to preventing public display above one’s social station. The use and display of rare and precious objects, frequently acquired through longdistance trade were marks of elite status. But merchants and others acquiring new wealth frequently clashed with local sumptuary structures. The laws grew extensive in the later Middle Ages just as commerce expanded. Tensions focused especially on the divide between indigenous and foreign goods; and sumptuary laws became associated with protectionist economic regulation. Injunctions centred on silk, furs, gold, silver and jewels, and exotic commodities from India, China, and Persia. It was impossible to stem the flow of these Eastern luxuries. By the beginning of the seventeenth century in England sumptuary laws were a dead letter, the Netherlands never had them, and while they held on in some other parts of Europe they were increasingly difficult to enforce.ii Fashion and Luxury 9 Luxury goods encountered a new fashion dynamic by the later sixteenth century. Silks, now manufactured, brocaded, and embroidered in Europe ‘became a disputed medium of style’; their ‘fashioning’ was still labourintensive.iii A closely approximate imitation arrived with the new wave of Asian-European seaborne trade: printed and painted cotton calicoes. The fabrics were light like silk, the colours vibrant, and the patterns and designs infinitely variable. These new goods from the East shook the old framework of the sumptuary dispute. Such goods came from afar, but they were not the rarities represented by silk; their value and status from the start was ambiguous, and they quickly moved to the forefront of new priorities over novelty and fashion. By the eighteenth century fashion was part of the language of luxury. Fashion dictated values. Fashion goods in turn drew on imitative impulses, product innovation, and creative adaptation. The key goods which came to feature in the consumer revolution, clothing and domestic items, were furthermore connected to sociability: fashionable clothing; the glass, chinaware, and silver accoutrements of the tea and dining table; the mirrors, ornamental ware, and seating furniture of dining and drawing rooms. These reflected the rise of middling groups and urban politeness. States, markets and global export ware The luxury goods imported from Asia brought to Europe a new knowledge of an export ware sector. These goods introduced to Europe lessons of complexity and of simplicity in product design and technology. Asia produced fine cottons, silks, porcelain, and other fine goods for world markets, deploying complex skills and adapting designs to capture the tastes of consumers from Malacca to Cairo, and from Lisbon to Amsterdam. These products offered a new design complexity that seemed readily adaptable to different cultures and fashions. European producers came to match Indian and Chinese luxury by providing other desirable characteristics: high output at affordable prices, variety and novelty, rapid turnover, warehouse selling, precision, exactness and order. Luxury now had an alternative, a high-quality cotton in a varied product mix produced by machinery. Luxury and a global history of those goods from the East, long neglected by economists and economic historians, thus played a key role in the industrialization of the West. Current Globalization That shift from a world where Asia’s luxury products drove the search for the technologies and industrial organization leading into the industrialization of Europe and North America was followed by two centuries of Western domination of world manufacture. The twenty-first century has seen a new Asian ascendancy: Europe has lost those manufacturing catalysts of textiles, 10 ceramics, and metal goods back to Asia. And the West, now facing the manufacturing and technological challenge of China and the rising capacity of India, is also experiencing new anxieties over its place in the world economy. New issues of world recession have connected consumption and production in ways hitherto unimagined. Luxury brands once rooted in Europe, for example Wedgwood pottery, are now manufactured in distant parts of the world. Consumption crises raise questions over the location of global manufacturing and the fates of industrial workforces, as in the recent events in Bangladesh. These issues of globalization have a deep history; issues of needs and wants, of consumption and luxury were issues of global history which set the very origins of European industrial and consumer revolutions. . i Berg, Luxury and Pleasure, 51–6; Oliver Impey, Chinoiserie: The Impact of Oriental Styles on Western Art and Decoration (Oxford: The Ashmolean, 1977), 20–6; Robert Finlay, ‘The Pilgrim Art: the Culture of Porcelain in World History’, Journal of World History, 9 (1998), 141–89, 178–9; Giorgio Riello, ‘The Indian Apprenticeship: the Trade in Indian Textiles and the making of European Cottons’, in Giorgio Riello and Tirthankar Roy (eds.), How India Clothed the World (Leiden: Brill, 2009), 309–47. ii Ibid., 891; see also Alan Hunt, Governance of the Consuming Passions. A History of Sumptuary Law (New York: St Martin’s Press, 1996); N. B. Harte, ‘State Control of Dress’, in D. C. Coleman and A. H. John (eds.), Trade, government and Economy in Pre-Industrial 11 England (London: Weidenfeld and Nicholson 1976), 132–65; De Vries, The Industrious Revolution, 46, 136. iii Beverly Lemire and Giorgio Riello, ‘East & West,’, 75–103.