Protecting Retirees While Encouraging Economically Targeted Investments Jayne Elizabeth Zanglein * The ongoing debate over economically targeted investments is primarily about power and politics and only secondarily about • pensIons. Introduction The ongoing debate over economically targeted investments is primarily about power and politics and only secondarily about pensions. Although the issue is complicated by political and moral perceptions, it is the law which governs the investment of pension plan assets in the fmal analysis. Therefore, the question is not whether it is morally or politically proper to use pension fund monies to create affordable housing, to finance expansion of the infrastructure, or to provide seed money to promising fledgling businesses. Instead, the question is whether these types of investments are legal under the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA).I Critics ofeconomically targeted investments argue that these investments are illegal under ERISA. But clearly this is not the case. In its recent interpretive bulletin, the Department of Labor restated its long-standing position 2 that "all things being equal", 3 pension plan fiduciaries may consider collateral benefits when deciding between investments with commensurate risk and return characteristics. The controversy over economically targeted investments has been fueled by the sheer size ofpension funds ($4.8 trillion), 4 the availability of these funds to finance economic development in a time of reduced government spending, the encouragement of ETls by the current administration, the public fmancing of a clearinghouse on ETls, and the few highly-publicized cases in which public pension funds have lost money in economically targeted investments. These events have motivated opponents ofETls to mount a legislative attack against the Department of Labor. In March 1995, the General Accounting Office prepared a report entitled Public Pension Plans: Evaluation of Economically Targeted Investment Programs s that addressed the investment of nonfederal public pension plans in economically targeted investments. The report concluded that because public pension plans invest a limited amount in ETls, "the risk posed to public pension plans by ETl investments is relatively small.,6 In May 1995, the Joint Economic Committee on Economically Targeted Investments of the United States Congress held a hearing on economically targeted investments7 in response to H.R. 1594, a bill introduced by Representative Saxton which would "place restrictions on the promotion by the Department of Labor ... of economically targeted investments in connection with employee benefit plans.'~ Most of the witnesses who testified urged the Department to revoke its policy on ETls. 9 Another hearing was held in June 1995, this time by the House Subcommittee on Employer-Employee Relations. 10 In September, the House passed H.R. 1594 and one day later the Jayne Elizabeth Zanglein is a Professor ofLaw at Texas Tech University School ofLaw in Lubbock, Texas. 47 Winter 1996 HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 47 1995-1996 Zanglein Senate appropnatlOns subcommittee incorporated into its appropriations report portions of S. 774, a bill designed to ban the promotion of ETIs by the Department of Labor.ll At the same time, the Joint Economic Committee issued a report entitled The Economics ofETls: Sacrificing Returnsfor Political Goals. 12 The report concluded that on average, ETIs earn two percentage points less than traditional investments. This allegedly translates into a lifetime loss of $43,298 per participant. The Department of Labor has attacked the report because it is based on the flawed assumption that pension investors are legally permitted to make below-market investments. In October 1995, the Heritage Foundation issued a booklet called "How to Close Down the Department of Labor.,,13 In its report, the Foundation suggested that Congress transfer the Pension and Welfare Benefit Administration to Social Security. 14 The Foundation also suggested that Congress abolish the Economically Targeted Investment Clearinghouse as it is "misguided and jeopardizes the safety of pension plan assets.,,15 Against this backdrop of controversy surrounding the Department of Labor's interpretive bulletin on economically targeted investments, it is important to analyze the legality of ETIs within the larger political context. This article analyzes economically targeted investments in a historical, legal, and political context. The Law: Nothing New ERISA section 404(a)( 1)(A) establishes the exclusive benefit rule. 16 The exclusive benefit rule requires fiduciaries to act solely in the interests of plan participants and beneficiaries and for the exclusive purpose of providing plan benefits and defraying reasonable expenses of plan administration. 17 Opponents of economically targeted investments cite this statutory language as evidence that economically targeted investments are inherently unlawful. The exclusive benefit rule establishes a duty of undivided loyalty - an extremely high standard of care. IS The exclusive benefit rule is duplicated in the Internal Revenue Code l9 and the Taft-Hartley Act.20 Yet neither the Department of Labor nor the Internal Revenue Service has ever interpreted the exclusive benefit rule as prohibiting "incidental" or "collateral" benefits. The Internal Revenue Code's version ofthe exclusive benefit rule is found in I.R.C. section 40 1(a)(2). 21 Under this rule it must be impossible for any part of the plan assets to be ''used for, or diverted to, purposes other than ... the exclusive benefit of ... [the] employees or their beneficiaries."22 Violation of this rule may result in disqualification of the plan.23 Initially, the Internal Revenue Service interpreted the exclusive benefit rule to prohibit all "objects or aims not solely designed for the proper satisfaction of all liabilities to employees or their beneficiaries."24 Later, when the IRS realized that this 48 rule was unworkable, it modified the rule to express a more realistic interpretation of the exclusive benefit rule: the primary purpose test. If the primary purpose of the investment is to benefit plan participants fmancially, the exclusive benefit rule does not preclude others from deriving a benefit from the transaction. 25 Investments must meet four conditions: "(1) the cost must not exceed fair market value at the time ofpurchase; (2) a fair return commensurate with the prevailing rate must be provided; (3) sufficient liquidity must be maintained to permit distributions in accordance with the terms of the plan; and (4) the safeguards and diversity that a prudent investor would adhere to must be present.,,26 If these conditions are met, the fiduciary's motivation for selecting the investment becomes irrelevant. In Revenue Ruling 71-391,27 the IRS noted that although plans must adhere to the exclusive benefit rule, "[t]his requirement, however, does not prevent others from also deriving some benefit.,,28 Courts have agreed with the IRS that the exclusive benefit rule is not meant to be interpreted literally.29 One district court explained that "by adopting the 'exclusive purpose' standard, Congress did not intend to make illegal the fact of life that most often a transaction benefits both parties involved."30 The Department's Long-Standing Position Congress tailored ERISA's exclusive benefit rule after the IRC's exclusive benefit rule. 31 The Department of Labor has consistently interpreted ERISA's exclusive benefit rule as prohibiting fiduciaries from subordinating retirement assets to ''unrelated activities.,,32 But the Department has never stated that all incidental or collateral benefits are prohibited. The Department has specifically stated that: There is nothing in ERISA, however, requiring that an investment decision be wholly uninfluenced by the desire to achieve social or incidental objectives if the investment, when judged solely on the basis of economic value to the plan, is equal or superior to alternative investments otherwise available.33 This basic statement of philosophy has remained virtually unchanged over the last twenty years. It has remained intact throughout the Carter, Reagan, Bush, and Clinton administrations in spite of the different political philosophies on ETIs expressed by these administrations. The rule was announced by Ian Lanoff, the first administrator of the Pension and Welfare Benefits Program. Lanoff, a Carter appointee, said that although the exclusive benefit rule "does not exclude the provision ofincidental benefits to others, the protection of retirement income is, and should continue to be, the overriding social objective governing the The Kansas Journal of Law & Public Policy HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 48 1995-1996 Economically Targeted Investments investment of plan assets.,,34 However, Lanoffwas cautious in providing guidance to trustees who wished to pursue social objectives with pension fund assets (primarily, at that time, union construction). Under Lanotrs guidance, the Department aggressively commenced litigation against trustees of funds who implemented innovative investments and advocated "social investing."35 Lanoff tempered the Department's position on social investment by warning trustees that "[t]o introduce other social objectives may be to dilute this primary objective [of protecting retirement income]."36 The Department of Labor's position under the direction of Lanoffbecame known as the "all things being equal" test. Under this test, "a fiduciary might choose on the basis of non-economic considerations between two alternatives which in his judgement were economically equally advantageous.,,37 A plan fiduciary is not permitted to consider non-economic factors if"the investment or investment course of action provide[s] the plan with less return, in comparison to risk involved, than comparable investments or investment courses of action available to the plan; or alternatively, involve[s] greater risk to the security of plan assets than such other investment or investment courses of action offering similar return.,,38 Each of Lanotrs successors has taken a similar position. Robert Monks, a Reagan appointee, was supportive of collateral benefits during his short tenure at the Department of Labor. He noted that "Congress, speaking through ERISA, stated that investment objectives that provide the greatest return to the plan consistent with acceptable risk must be paramount. However, that does not mean that plans must ignore deeply felt social views when faced with investment of equal investment merit.,,39 Jeffrey Clayton, a Reagan appointee, said that "[w]hile [the exclusive benefit rule] does not exclude the provision of incidental benefits to others, the protection of retirement is, and must continue to be, the overriding social objective governing the investment ofplan assets.... [I]nvestment performance may not properly be sacrificed in order to advance the social welfare of a group or region; however, an investment is not impermissible under ERISA solely because it has social utility.'>4O In 1986, Clayton's successor, Dennis Kass, another Reagan appointee said: The controversy over economically targeted investments has been fueled by the sheer size of pension funds ($4.8 trillion). The view that non-economic benefits may be achieved incidental to the proper investment of pension funds is one of long standing under both the Internal Revenue Code prior to the passage of ERISA and under ERISA. Clearly, to prohibit such benefits where the provisions of the law have been scrupulously ~dhered to would unnecessarily constrain fiduciaries in the exercise of their Such a investment duties. prohibition could result in specific investment opportunities being avoided by fiduciaries simply in order to avoid the possibility of an incidental benefit arising from them. 41 David Walker, a Reagan appointee, stated "that under ERISA, pension plan investments must be made based upon what is in the economic interest of the plan as a separate and distinct legal entity established for the purpose of providing retirement income, that other considerations can be considered provided that they are incidental and do not compromise the required investment decision.,>42 David George Ball, a Bush appointee, was conservative in his approach to economically targeted investments. Nevertheless, during his tenure he wrote: "Since the enactment of ERISA in 1974, the Department has consistently stated its position that ERISA's rules are flexible enough to permit plans to invest in areas of the economy that are most appropriate for each individual plan's circumstances. In fact, our regulations ... adopted a broad interpretation of ... [prudence] precisely for the purpose of encouraging plan fiduciaries to look beyond the traditional types of trust investments."43 Ball cautioned that "[i]t is axiomatic, however, that plan fiduciaries, in order to be prudent, must achieve a rate of return that is appropriate for the degree of risk involved. To do otherwise would, in effect, subsidize certain investments at the expense of market place discipline.'>44 Olena Berg, a Clinton appointee, is the most vocal of the departmental spokespersons on economically targeted investments. Under her guidance in June 1994, the Department of Labor issued Interpretive Bulletin 94_1 45 in an effort to clarify the Department's long-standing policy that all things being equal, a pension plan may make an investment which contains a collateral or social benefit. The interpretive bulletin does not set any new conditions or special requirements for economically targeted investments. The Department specifically stated in the bulletin that "[t]he fiduciary standards applicable to ETIs are no different than the standards applicable to plan investments generally.'>46 The Department restated its position that a Winter 1996 49 HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 49 1995-1996 Zanglein fiduciary may invest plan assets in an ETI "if the ETI has an expected rate of return that is commensurate to rates of return of alternative investments with similar risk characteristics that are available to the plan, and ifthe ETI is otherwise an appropriate investment for the plan in tenns ofsuch factors as diversification and the investment policy of the plan.'>!? Why the Fuss? If Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 does nothing more than clarify the Department's long-standing position on economically targeted investments, then why all ofthe fuss? Numerous events have impelled the subject ofETIs to a political forefront. First, the size of pension fund assets has made the issue increasingly more important. In the late 1970s, when the issue was first addressed by the Department of Labor, pension plan assets totaled $500 billion.48 Since then, plan assets have increased nearly ten-fold. Although only a very small percentage of plan assets is invested in ETIs, this small percentage is expressed as billions of dollars. Certainly, billions excite politicians, the public, and reporters more than millions. Second, the failure of some public pension fund ETI programs has been highly publicized. Politicians have seized on these failures to justify changes to ERISA, a law which does not even govern public plans. 49 Third, times have changed. Over the last twenty years, the public has seen the effects of underfunded pension plans, savings and loan scandals, corporate takeovers and downsizing, insurance annuities invested in junk bonds, fund investments in derivatives, and state treasurers who adjust actuarial rates of return in order to reduce pension plan contributions. Most of these concerns have been addressed through legislative efforts, but the cumulative effects are great. With the help of the media, retirees are worried about their retirement security. Fourth, Republicans are suspicious that Robert Reich and Olena Berg, both appointed under Clinton, are encouraging pension funds to invest in ETIs to fill the gap created by reduced government spending. President Clinton, in his book, Putting People First,50 called for increased investment by pension funds and other institutional investors in infrastructure. Although the Department's issuance ofInterpretive Bulletin 94I simply restated the Department's long-standing position on the pennissiblity of considering collateral benefits, it was inevitable that a Republican-controlled Congress would move swiftly to quash the Department's efforts. The Saxton bill, H.R. 1594, initially languished despite Saxton's outraged cries, until the Republican leadership latched onto it apparently in an effort to divert attention from their proposals to cut Medicare spending. Suddenly, the Republican leadership started to take the Saxton bill seriously, leading some cynics to believe that it was used as a smokescreen to shield the 50 huge Medicare and Medicaid cuts proposed by the Republicans. 51 ETIs Defined Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 defines "economically targeted investments" as "investments selected for the economic benefits they create apart from their investment return to the employee benefit plan."52 Common examples of collateral benefits derived from ETIs include "expanded employment opportunities, increased housing availability, improved social service facilities, and strengthened infrastructure.',53 In a recent article published in the Berkeley Journal of Employment and Labor Law, Professor Edward Zelinsky criticized the Department's interpretive bulletin. Professor Zelinsky contended that "if the concept of collateral benefit is broad enough to encompass all of the externalities conceivably generated by traditional investments, then the ETI category loses meaning because it includes the entire universe of traditional investments."S4 This argument misses the critical point of the interpretive bulletin. Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 clearly states that economically targeted investments (i.e. those that create a collateral economic benefit other than the investment return to the plan) are pennissible investments "ifthe ETI has an expected rate of return that is commensurate to rates of return of alternative investments with similar risk characteristics that are available to the plan, and if the ETI is otherwise an appropriate investment for the plan in tenns ofsuch factors as diversification and the investment policy of the plan."55 This is an updated version of the all things being equal test: all things being equal, a plan may choose an economically targeted investment over a traditional investment. The interpretive bulletin makes clear that "[t]he fiduciary standards applicable to ETIs are no different than the standards applicable to plan investments generally.'156 Thus, the general fiduciary standards of ERISA section 404(a)(1)5? apply equally to ETIs. It is true that most investments can be categorized as economically targeted investments in a very general sense. However, the Department of Labor, in its interpretive bulletin, does not categorize ETIs as a particular class of investments. Instead, the Department defines ETIs through the investment selection process. An investment is deemed an economically targeted investment only if the investment was "selected for the economic benefits [it] create[s] apart from [its] investment return to the employee benefit plan.'158 Under the "all things being equal test," a fiduciary can choose an investment that offers a collateral benefit if the fiduciary has acted prudently and has received a competitive rate ofreturn. The test makes irrelevant the fiduciary's motivation for selecting the investment if otherwise "all things are equal". Instead, the focus is on the decision-making process under the prudence rule. The Kansas Journal of Law & Public Policy HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 50 1995-1996 Economically Targeted Investments For example, plan trustees might decide to invest in XYZ Corporation, a minorityowned business, simply because it has an expected investment return which is superior to all other available investment opportunities with similar risk characteristics. The trustees might not know or even care that it is a minority-owned business. In that case, the investment is not an ETI, even though it may indirectly create expanded employment opportunities for minorities. However, if the plan trustees choose to invest in XYZ Corporation because it is a minority-owned business which has an expected investment return which is equal or superior to all other investment opportunities with similar risk characteristics, then the investment is an ETI. The genesis for the interpretive bulletin is not the premise that investments which create collateral benefits should be classified differently than other investments. Rather, investments which create collateral benefits are regarded as ETls only if they are selected in part because they provide incidental or collateral benefits. If the investment is expected to earn a risk adjusted market rate of return, then the trustee's motivation is irrelevant. However, the prudence rule is always relevant; all investments, whether ETls or not, must meet ERISA's prudence rule. In his article critical ofETls, Professor Zelinsky concluded that the Department has ''wholehearted[ly] embracerd) incidental economic benefits as legitimate criteria upon which pension trustees can base their investment choices."59 This is simply not what the interpretive bulletin says. Instead, Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 states that investments that create incidental benefits are permissible only if the expected return is commensurate with alternative investments with similar risk characteristics. It is not necessary to quantify the economic value of the collateral benefit because the investment return must equal or exceed alternative investments with commensurate risk characteristics without regard to the economic value of the collateral benefit. not grant relief from the exclusive benefit rule. Prohibited transaction exemptions are not designed or authorized to exempt fiduciaries from compliance with the exclusive benefit rule. ERISA section 408(a) provides that the Department may provide relief only from the restrictions of ERISA sections 406 and 407(a), not the exclusive benefit rule. 63 Exemptions may not be granted with respect to the exclusive benefit rule, therefore, it is impossible for the Department to cite any exemptions that directly support its position that collateral benefits per se do not violate the exclusive benefit rule. Even though the Department cannot grant exemptions from the exclusive benefit rule, it would be unwilling to grant a prohibited transaction exemption if the proposed transaction would possibly violate the exclusive benefit rule.64 The Department cited exemptions that involved transactions that were designed to create collateral benefits. In each of the cited exemptions except the first one, the Department restated its position on the exclusive benefit rule: an incidental benefit cannot be considered unless the investment would be equal or superior, in economic value to the plan (apart from collateral benefit), to alternative investments with the same degree of risk available to the plan. The flip side ofthis rule is that an incidental benefit can be considered if the investment meets the "all things being equal test". The prohibited transaction exemptions thus clearly support the Department's statement that its position on incidental benefits has remained unchanged. 65 Likewise, the argument that the advisory opinions cited in the interpretive bulletin "provide, at most, limited support for IB 94-1"66 is unpersuasive. The advisory opinions were not cited to provide independent authority, but as examples of the Department's long-standing attitude on incidental benefits.67 Professor Zelinsky further maintains that the Department has unjustifiably diluted the exclusive benefit rule by "declaring that pension trustees must 'ordinarily' concern themselves with the retirement income interests of participants and beneficiaries.'>68 I suggest, however, that Professor Zelinsky has quoted this language out of context. The full text reads: The exclusive benefit rule establishes a duty of undivided loyalty an extremely high standard ofcare. Evidence of the Department's Long-Standing Position Critics of economically targeted investments such as Professor Zelinsky also maintain that the administrative rulings cited by the Department of Labor in Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 "belies any contention that IB 94-1 is the codification of wellestablished or convincing administrative precedent.'>60 For example, Professor Zelinsky believes that the seven prohibited transaction exemptions cited in the preamble to Interpretive Bulletin 94_1 61 as support for the Department's long-standing position on collateral benefits are, "at best, unpersuasive and, at worst, disingenuous"62 because these particular exemptions did We have construed the requirements that a fiduciary act solely in the interest of, and for the exclusive purpose of providing benefits to, participants and beneficiaries as prohibiting a fiduciary from subordinating the interests of participants and beneficiaries in their retirement income to unrelated objectives. Thus, in deciding whether and to what extent to invest in a particular Winter 1996 51 HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 51 1995-1996 Zanglein investment, a fiduciary must ordinarily consider only factors relating to the interests of plan participants and beneficiaries in their retirement income. A decision to make an investment may not be influenced by [a desire to stimulate the construction industry and generate employment] unless the investment, whenjudged solely on the basis of its economic value to the plan, would be equal or superior to alternative investments available to the p1an. 69 Read in this context, the Department makes clear that plan trustees will ordinarily have no reason to consider collateral benefits. Trustees may consider collateral benefits only if the investment is economically equal or superior to alternative investments with risk-adjusted market rates of return. The "ordinarily" language does not dilute the statutory language; it is consistent with the Department's position on incidental benefits. Are Things Ever Really Equal? If the Department's position on economically targeted investments is susceptible to criticism, it is most susceptible on the "all things being equal" test. The question is: are things ever really equal? Economists tell us that risk and return can be quantified and compared, but are any two economically targeted investments ever really equal? Presumably, an investment in a six month certificate of deposit at 5.5% is equal to another certificate issued by the same bank at the same rate and with the same maturity date. But is it possible to say with certainty that an investment in affordable housing has the same risk and return characteristics as an investment in a private placement? Certainly economists can make such evaluations controlling for variables and assuming away real world choices. They are obligated to compare apples to oranges everyday. But the test defies logic and experience for most pension fiduciaries. Let us take an easy example. A pension fund is considering six possible real estate investments. Five of the six investments will use non-union labor; the sixth will use union construction. All six investments might be considered ETls in a very broad sense; however, only the sixth investment is likely to be regarded as an ETl by the Department of Labor. Suppose the fund hires an investment advisor who rejects potential investments two through five and concludes that the first and sixth potential investments have a commensurate risk-adjusted market rate of return. The trustees decide to invest in number 6 because not only is it economically equal to investment number 1, but it provides a collateral benefit of jobs for union members. Investment number 1 is not an ETl; investment number 6 is an ETI. Prospectively, the two are economically equivalent. Under the "all things being equal" test, the trustees can remain true to their first and foremost duty - the protection of retire- 52 ment income - while benefiting society through the positive externalities generated by the investment, the creation ofjobs, in this example. Suppose we followed these two investments, and it turned out that investment number 1 earned an annualized rate of return of 8.2% while investment number 6 earned an annualized rate of return of 9.1 %. This does not mean that the first investment would not have been prudent. Prudence is not measured by hindsight. 70 Of course, the mere fact that the investment number 6 earned 9.1 % does not mean it was more prudent. Prudence is measured in terms of procedural prudence. In other words, did the trustees adequately investigate the investment before making their decision to invest?71 Both investments were prudent. Investment number 6 was a better performer in dollars and cents and, incidentally, it provided a collateral benefit of union jobs. In hindsight, it might turn out that investment number 1 was more risky because it was picketed by union members. Again, while economists may be able to predict that two investments are equal in terms of risk and return, this is only a prediction. It may be possible to manipulate numbers to arrive at equal numbers. And what happens ifthe investments are substantially equivalent: investment number 1 is projected to return 9.058% and number 6 is projected to return 9.041 %? Is it permissible to choose investment number 6 anyway since the numbers are only a projection?72 These real concerns remain unaddressed. Filling Capital Gaps Opponents of ETls argue that if economically targeted investments are truly good investments then "market forces will clear such investments without consideration of their collateral benefits."73 This echoes the often-heard argument that "[I]fETls were solid, sound and prudent, they would attract investors on their own.,,74 This argument conveniently ignores market inefficiencies and informational asymmetries that render investors' decisionmaking more of an art than a science. It also refuses to recognize well-documented capital gaps.75 The ERISA Advisory Council has described the problem of capital gaps: ETI programs are structured with an awareness that underflnanced sectors of the economy do exist for reasons independent of whether profit opportunities exist. Traditional investors may avoid capital investments in certain sectors for various reasons, ranging from human nature reflected in express discrimination or lack of empathy, to dynamic shifts in savings patterns over the course of years and a transfer of capital assets from local banks to pension funds managed by national investment managers. ETls are The Kansas Journal of Law & Public Policy HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 52 1995-1996 Economically Targeted Investments investment opportunities that attempt creatively to address these capital gaps, while through financial engineering attempting to ensure that the pension fund is not absorbing unjustified risk or a compromised rate of return. 76 One commentator explains the problems created by an inefficient market: common, though erroneous, belief that ETIs are unlawful and fiduciaries fear personal liability; and (4) the widespread publicity that occurs when an investment goes bad. 82 The Department of Labor has attempted to alleviate some of these problems through the issuance of the interpretive bulletin and the creation of the ETI Clearinghouse. 83 However, problems still persist due to the nature and structure ofETIs. 84 A 1993 study by the Institute for Fiduciary Education concluded that economically targeted investing is growing only modestly and the subject still elicits strong opinions, both positive and negative, from the pension fund community.85 In the preamble to Interpretive Bulletin 94-1, the Department recognized that "a perception exists within the investment community that investments in ETIs are incompatible with ERISA's fiduciary obligations."86 The Department issued the interpretive bulletin "[i]n order to eliminate this misconception"87 and encourage investments in ETIs. In the survey on ETIs, the Institute for Fiduciary Education asked 119 public pension funds to list reasons why they have not made economically targeted investments. 88 Thirty-seven percents9 of the funds stated that the principal reason they did not invest in ETIs is because of perceived conflicts with fiduciary duties. 90 Eleven percent said that ETIs take too much staff time; 11 % said ETIs are not statutorily authorized; 8% said that they did not invest in ETIs because "no one asked us to invest in an ETI;" 4% said that their legal counsel had advised against ETIs; and 4% said they perceived no need for ETIs. 91 Thirty-eight percent of the funds surveyed invested in ETIs;92 50 ETI programs totaled $19.8 bi1lion. 93 The survey also found that liquidity of ETI investments and the procurement of a competent asset manager tied as the most difficult aspects ofETIs. 94 Over 14% of the funds experienced great difficulty in each of these two areas. Other difficulties included risk/return requirements,95 internal staff considerations,96 and political concerns. 97 Economist Teresa Ghilarducci notes, "The main problem economically targeted investors face is not the inherent riskiness or unprofitability of economically targeted investments, but the excessive information and transactions costs associated with an immature market."98 Lee Smith, Executive Director of Excelsior Capital Corporation, a New York not-for-profit corporation established by former Governor Mario Cuomo to encourage pension funds to make economically targeted investments, also describes the difficulties faced by pension funds who wish to invest in ETIs: [W]hile typically there is no capital gap in financing housing, there is a consistent capital gap with respect to financing affordable housing. Implicit in the concept of an ETI is the assumption that the market for ETIs is imperfect.... In a perfect market, the sponsors of a worthwhile project will be able to find qualified investors without inordinate investment opportunities that attempt creatively to address these capital gaps, while through financial engineering attempting to ensure that the pension fund is not absorbing unjustified risk or a compromised rate of return. 77 Numerous congressional hearings have been held on capital gaps and economic development. 78 A recent study on Venture Capital and Technological Innovation in Southern California found "a significant'capital gap' in venture funding available for companies based on Southern California."79 "[T]he study found that fewer companies in the region received venture backing than at any time in the past decade.,,80 New York also has taken steps to alleviate its capital gap by raising a $20 million venture capital fund. 81 Capital gaps sometimes exist only in certain segments of the market. For example, while typically there is no capital gap in financing housing, there is a consistent capital gap with respect to financing affordable housing. The capital gap exists because it is so difficult and time-consuming to put together an affordable housing deal. Although government subsidies and foundation investments make affordable housing possible, additional fmancing is usually needed. Pension funds can provide conventional market-rate fmancing to fill this gap, but it is not easy. They need a clearinghouse that can gather and disseminate general information about ETI consultants who specialize in putting these types of deals together. The opponents' argwnent also seems to ignore the historical reluctance of pension plans to invest in ETIs. Plans have been reluctant to invest in ETIs because: (l) they are typically time consuming and complex investments; (2) there is a lack of professional support to advise fiduciaries on ETIs; (3) there is a Winter 1996 53 HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 53 1995-1996 Zanglein ETIs have existed over a decade and their creation and implementation has often been a slow and arduous task. This type of capital market innovation is not a well developed practice nor is it well understood. . . . Especially when first created, the design and implementation ofETIs is labor intensive and a costly process. Often times ETIs require ... the coordination of several different parties that have previously not worked together. Coordinating these various groups is difficult work. And because of this necessary labor intensity and the scale, the net fees from these investments often cannot compete with those other more established investment products.... While it is widely believed that this barrier will be substantially reduced as vehicles become standardized, it is unlikely that this will occur in the near future.... While it is not necessary to "start from scratch with each investment," it is also incorrect to assume that all ETIs are easily transportable. A second impediment to full acceptance of the legitimacy of ETIs is the lingering presence of mixed signals from the DOL under previous administrations. Many pension fund managers remain skeptical about the legality ofETIs under ERISA. For fund managers the possible negative consequences of an ERISA violation far outweighed the potential benefits of making an ETI. 99 ETIs are less common than they otherwise would be as a result of the lack of a professional database or information exchange on these types of investments. The 1992 Work Group on Pension Investments to the ERISA Advisory Committee on Pension and Welfare Benefit Plans "recognized that since ETIs target investment opportunities reflecting inefficient markets, these investments by nature do not start out as generically standardized investments."IOO The Work Group further concluded that "[t]here is a lack of historical data on ETIs and relatively weak incentives for private markets to create this information. This gap hampers informed decision making and impedes efforts to make those markets more efficient.,,101 The Work Group recommended that "[t]he Department of Labor .. . take the initiative in gathering information about the investment performance and attributes to the pension community to aid its investment decisions."102 The Department of Labor has responded to these concerns by establishing the ETI Clearinghouse.103 The purpose of the Clearinghouse is to serve as a resource for funds who wish to develop an ETI program. The Clearinghouse plans to showcase successful ETI programs developed by public and private pension funds and prepare case studies of ETIs in the United 54 States, "cross-referenced by investment category and collateral benefIt."I04 The Clearinghouse will serve a valuable function as an information gathering center. This will help improve the market for ETIs. Greater information, of course, makes any market more efficient. Yet, through H.R. 1594 and the current appropriations bill, legislators are attempting to dismantle the Clearinghouse. If this happens, ETIs will remain an inefficient market. Prudence: The Bottom Line The bottom line is that all pension fund investments must be prudent. lOS Below-market returns are never acceptable and the Department recently reaffirmed that it will aggressively sue any plan fiduciaries that engage in below-market or otherwise imprudent investments. 106 This is another long-standing tradition of the Department of Labor. The prudence rule protects retirees by requiring that all plan investments be made ''with the care, skill, prudence, and diligence under the circumstances then prevailing that a prudent man acting in a like capacity and familiar with such matters would use in the conduct of an enterprise of a like character and with like aims." 107 According to regulations adopted by the Department, a fiduciary must act only after giving appropriate consideration to: facts and circumstances that, given the scope of such fiduciary's investment duties, the fiduciary knows or should know are relevant to the particular investment or investment course of action involved, including the role the investment or investment course of action plays in the portion of the plan's investment portfolio with respect to which the fiduciary has investment duties. los When considering an investment, the fiduciary must determine whether the investment reasonably furthers the purposes ofthe plan, taking into consideration the risk ofloss and the opportunity for gain. 109 The fiduciary must consider the following factors in relation to the entire portfolio: (1) the composition ofthe portfolio with regard to diversification; (2) the liquidity and current return of the portfolio relative to the anticipated cash flow requirements of the plan; and, (3) the projected return of the portfolio relative to the funding objective of the plan. I10 The Department of Labor has added a fourth factor: "consideration of the expected return on alternative investments with similar risks available to the plan."1l1 The Department clarified this factor in Interpretive Bulletin 94-1: The Kansas Journal of Law & Public Policy HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 54 1995-1996 Economically Targeted Investments [B]ecause every investment necessarily causes a plan to forgo other investment opportunities, an investment will not be prudent if it would be expected to provide a plan with a lower rate of return than available alternative investments with commensurate degrees of risk or is riskier than alternative investments with commensurate rates of return. 112 The prudence rule sufficiently protects retirees from inappropriate, below-market investments. Withdrawal of Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 will not give retirees any additional protections. Conclusion Because Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 simply restates the Department's long-standing policy on collateral benefits, it should not be repealed by Congress. The repeal of the interpretive bulletin would only confuse the issue. The enactment ofH.R. 1594 or S. 774 would be unworkable and would threaten many transactions entered into over the last twenty years based on statutory, individual, and class exemptions. The ramifications of such legislation would be far-reaching and undesirable. 1I3 A reversal of Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 is neither desirable nor necessary. ERISA makes clear that all pension investments must be prudent. The Department has made clear that the "protection of retirement income ... [must] ... be the overriding social objective governing the investment of plan assets" and the Department has aggressively sued trustees who violate ERISA's fiduciary rules. No further protections are necessary. Notes * The author would like to thank Professor Thomas E. Baker who provided incisive comments on this article. 1. 29 U.S.C. § 1102. 2. The Department of Labor's position dates back to at least 1980, when Ian Lanoff, then Pension Administrator for the Department of Labor stated that while ERISA "does not exclude the provision of incidental benefits to others, the protection of retirement income is, and should continue to be, the overriding social objective governing the investment of plan assets." Ian D. Lanoff, The Social Investment ofPrivate Pension Plan Assets: May It Be Done Lawfully Under ERISA?, 31 LAB. L.J. 387, 389 (1980). 3. See PWBA Advisory Letter from Department of Labor to Gregory Ridella (Dec. 19, 1988) (A.a. 88-16A) (stating that in making investment decisions, plan fiduciaries may be influenced by factors unrelated to the plan's expected investment return only if such investments "would be equal or superior to alternative available investments"). 4. Economically Targeted Investments: Hearings on HR. 1594 Before the Joint Economic Comm., 104th Congress, 1st Sess. (May 18, 1995) [hereinafter ETI Hearings] (statement of Olena Berg, Asst. Sec. of Labor, Pension and Welfare Benefits Administration). 5. GAO, PUBLIC PENSION PLANS: EVALUATION OF ECONOMICALLY TARGETED INVESTMENT PROGRAMS (1995). 6. /d. at 28. 7. See Federal Document Clearing House Congressional Testimony (May 18,1995). 8. H.R. 1594, 104th Congress, 1st Sess. (1995). 9. Republicans. Democrats Clash over ETIs at Hearing of Joint Economic Committee, PENS. REp. (BNA), Vol. 22, No. 21, at 1240 (May 22, 1995). 10. Economically Targeted Investments: Hearings on HR. 1594 Before the Subcomm. on Employer-Employee Relations of the House Comm. on Economic and Educational Opportunities, 104th Congress, 1st Sess. (1995). 11. S. 774, 104th Congress, 1st Sess. (1995). 12. See Administration Attacks JEC Report That Calls ETIs 'Risky Investments', PENS. REP. (BNA), Vol. 22, No. 37, at 2046 (Sept. 18, 1995). 13. THE BACKGROUNDER, No. 1058, (The Heritage Found.) Oct. 19,1995. 14. Id. at 3. 15. Id. at 20. 16. 29 U.S.C. § 1104(a)(1)(A)(1995). 17. Id. 18. Fiduciaries must act "with an eye single to the interests of participants and beneficiaries." Donovan v. Bierwirth, 680 F.2d 263, 271 (2d Cir. 1982), cert. denied, 459 U.S. 1969 (1982). They may not place themselves in a position in which they are required to compromise their duty of undivided loyalty to plan participants. Id. 19. I.R.C. § 401(a) (1995). 20. Labor Management Relations (Taft-Hartley) Act § 302(c)(5); 29 U.S.c. § 186(c)(5) (1995). 21. I.R.C. § 401 (a)(2) (1995). 22. Id. 23. Winger's Dep't Store, Inc. v. Commissioner, 82 T.C. 869 (1984). 24. 26 C.F.R. § 1.401-2(a)(3) (1995). 25. Rev. Rul. 69-494, 1969-2 C.B. 88. 26. Id. 27. Rev. Rul. 71-391, 1971-2 C.B. 186. 28. Id. 29. Central Motor Co. v. United States, 583 F.2d 470,490 (10th Cir. 1978); see also Bing Management Co. v. Commmisioner, 36 T.C.M. (CCH) 1633, 1636 (1977). 30. Donovan v. Walton, 609 F.Supp. 1221, 1245 (S.D. Fla. Winter 1996 55 HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 55 1995-1996 Zanglein 1985), ajJ'd sub nom. Brock v. Walton, 794 F.2d 586 (11th Cir. 1986). 31. CONF. REp. No. 1280, 93d Cong., 2d Sess. 302 (1974), reprinted in 1974 U.S.C.C.A.N. 5038, 5083. A fiduciary who meets ERISA's exclusive benefit rule will be deemed to have met the IRC's parallel provision. Id. 32. Letter from Department of Labor to Helmuth Fandl, Chairman of the Retirement Board of Avon Products, Inc., at n. 4 (Feb. 23, 1988), reprinted in PENS. REP. (BNA) Vol. 15, No.9, at 391 (Feb. 29, 1988). 33. Dennis Kass, Assistant Secretary of Labor, Pension and Welfare Benefits Administration, Current Developments at the Department of Labor, Address at the Annual Conference in Las Vegas, Nev., sponsored by the Int'l Found. ofEmployee Benefits Plans (Nov. 1986), reprinted in INT'L FOUND. OF EMPLOYEE BENEFITS PLANS, EMPLOYEE BENEFITS ANNuAL, 235, 236 (1987). 34. Lanoff, supra note 2, at 389. 35. See. e.g., Donovan v. Walton, 609 F. Supp. 1221 (S.D. Fla. 1985). 36. Lanoff, supra note 2, at 389. 37. Letter from Ian D. Lanoffto George Cox (Jan. 16, 1981). 38. Advisory Opinion 81-12. 39. Letter from Robert A.G. Monks to Olena Berg (May 8, 1995) (quoting a speech given before the Florida Labor/Management Council on December 7, 1984). See Loans Must Be Appropriate For Plans Before Looking to Social Goals. Monks Says, DAILY REpORT FOR EXECUTIVES (BNA), No. 240, at A-I (Dec. 13, 1984). 40. Letter from Jeffrey N. Clayton to Daniel E. O'Sullivan (Aug. 2, 1982). 41. See ETI Hearings (Prepared statement of Olena Berg. Assistant Secretary ofLabor (quoting Dennis Kass )), supra note 4, at 6. 42. Pension Investments: Public Hearing Before the New York State Pension Investment Task Force, 190-91 (Mar. 3, 1989) (testimony of David Walker, Assistant Secretary for Pension and Welfare Benefits, U.S. Department of Labor). 43. Letter from David George Ball to Preston Robert Tisch, Chairman of New York City Partnership, Inc. (Jan. 30, 1991). 44. Id. 45. Department of Labor Interpretive Bulletin 94-1 on Economically Targeted Investments, 59 Fed. Reg. 32,606 (June 23, 1994) (to be codified at 29 C.F.R. § 2509.94-1) [hereinafter Interpretive Bulletin 94-1]. . 46. Id. 47. Id. 48. Jack Eagan, Pension Fund Managers Maintain Cautious Attitude on Stock Market, WASH. POST, Nov. 12, 1978, at L4. 49. Public pension funds are not governed by ERISA. They are governed by state law but are subject to the Internal Revenue Code's exclusive benefit rule. S6 50. See BILL CLINTON, PUTIING PEOPLE FIRST (1992). Anti-ETI Bill Picks Up Steam in the Senate Appropriations Process, PENS. REp. (BNA), Vol. 22, No. 37, Sept. 18, 1995, at 2044,2046. 52. Interpretive Bulletin 94-1, supra note 45. 53. Hearing on Pension Investments and Economic Growth Before the Joint Economic Committee on Economically Targeted Investments, 103 Cong., 2d Sess. (1994) (testimony of Olena Berg, Assistant Secretary of Labor), reprinted in Federal Document Clearing House Congressional Testimony (June 22, 1994). 54. Edward A. Zelinsky, ETL Phone the Department ofLabor. Economically Targeted Investments. IB 94-1 and the Reincarnation ofIndustrial Policy, 16 BERKLEY J. EMP. & LAB. L. 333, 341 (1995). 55. Interpretive Bulletin 94-1, supra note 45. 56. Id. 57. 29 U.S.C. § 1104(a)(1) (1995). 58. Interpretive Bulletin 94-1, supra note 45. 59. Zelinsky, supra note 54, at 343. 60. Id. at 344. 61. Interpretive Bulletin 94-1, supra note 45, at n. 3. 62. Zelinsky, supra note 54, at 345. 63. 29 U.S.C. § 1108(a) (1995). 64. ERISA § 408(a) requires the Department to make a fmding that the exemption is in the interests of the participants and beneficiaries and adequately protects their rights. In recent congressional testimony, Assistant Secretary ofLabor Olena Berg said, "If ERISA were interpreted to state that the exclusive purpose requirements of ERISA were per se violated by a plan entering into a transaction that requires a section 408 exemption because it provides an incidental benefit to a party in interest, the exemption would be ineffectual and a trap for the unwary." ETI Hearings (prepared statement ofOlena Berg. Assistant Secretary ofLabor), supra note 4, at 13. 65. The Department's position has remained unchanged; however, the Department's encouragement ofETI investments has clearly changed. 66. Zelinsky, supra note 54, at 345. 67. Professor Zelinsky argues that Advisory Opinion 80-33A is not supportive because it did not give an opinion on the legality of the agreement between Chrysler and the United Auto Workers to establish a committee to recommend certain investments to the Chrysler pension plans. Id. The Department responded that the agreement itself would not violate ERISA's fiduciary provisions. However, the Department refused to opine on any particular transaction. The Department's statement that the agreement between Chrysler and the UAW did not violate ERISA's fiduciary provisions implies that the individual transactions could not be a per se violation of the exclusive benefit rule. Advisory Opinion 88-16A (Dept. of Labor, 1980). 51. The Kansas Journal of Law & Public Policy HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 56 1995-1996 Economically Targeted Investments 68. Zelinsky, supra note 54, at 345-346. 69. Advisory Opinion 88-16A (Dept. of Labor). This language is virtually identical to the preambles for the prohibited transaction exemptions cited in the interpretive bulletin. 70. See DeBruyne v. Equitable Life Assurance Society, 720 F. Supp. 1342 (N.D. Ill. 1989), affd. 920 F.2d 457 (1990); GIW Industries, Inc. v. Trevor, Stewart, Burton & Jacobsen, Inc., 10 Employee Benefits Cas. (BNA) 2290 (S.D. Ga. 1989), affd, 895 F.2d 729 (11th Cir. 1990). 71. See Marshall v. Glass/Metal Assoc. & Glaziers & Glass Workers Pension Plan, 507 F.Supp. 378 (D. Haw. 1980); Donovan v. Mazzola, 2 Employee Benefits Cas. (BNA) 2115 (N.D. Cal. 1981), ajJ'd, 716 F.2d 1226 (9th Cir. 1983), cert. denied, 464 U.S. 1040 (l984); Donovan v. Walton, 609 F. Supp. 1221 (S.D. Fla. 1985), ajJ'd sub nom., Brock v. Walton, 794 F.2d 586 (11th Cir. 1986); Whitfield v. Tomasso, 682 F.Supp. 1287 (E.D.N.Y. 1988); Andrade v. Parsons Corp., 12 Employee Benefits Cas. (BNA) 1954 (C.D. Cal. 1990), ajJ'd, 1992 U.S. App. LEXIS 18220 (9th Cir. July 31, 1992). 72. The economic benefit received as a result of the externality cannot be factored into the rate of return. 73. Zelinsky, supra note 54, at 348. 74. Penelope Lemov, Paving the Way With Pension Funds, ROCKY MOUNTAIN NEWS, Mar. 28, 1994, at 39A. See also Teresa Ghilarducci, US. Pension Investment Policy and Perfect Capital Market Theory, CHALLENGE, July 1994, at 4. 75. The Advisory Council Work Group on ETIs states that one of ETI's three identifying characteristics is that they target a capital gap. U.S. DEP'T OF LABOR ADVISORY COUNCIL ON EMPLOYEE WELFARE AND PENSION BENEFIT PLANs, A CLEARINGHOUSE ON NETWORK FOR ECONOMICALLY TARGETED INVESTMENTS 7 (Nov. 1993) [hereinafter ADVISORY COUNCIL ETI REpORT]. 76. Id. at 8. 77. Id. at 8. 78. See Legislative Proposals to Provide Financing Assistance for Projects Fostering Economic Development and Job Creation. Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Economic Growth and Credit Formation, 103d Congo 2d Sess. (June 22,1994); Pension Fund Investments for Economic Growth. Hearing of the Comm. on Labor and Human Resources, 102d Cong., 2d Sess. (Sept. 29, 1992). 79. New Study Finds 'Capital Gap' in Venture Funding for Southern California, PRNEWSWIRE, Dec. 13, 1994. 80. Id. 81. Abby Livingston, Venture Fund Debuts to Aid Tech StartUps: Capital Goals May Face Capital Roadblock, CRAIN'S N.Y. BUS., Feb. 27, 1995, at 14. 82. CENTER FOR POLICY ALTERNATIVES, ECONOMICALLY TARGETED INVESTING BY STATE-WIDE PUBLIC PENSION FUNDS, 19-20,22-23, 28 (1993). 83. ETI Hearings (prepared statment ofOlena Berg. Assistant Secretary ofLabor), supra note 5; see also ADVISORY COUNCIL ETI REpORT, supra note 75. 84. For a more detailed examination of these problems see Jayne Elizabeth Zanglein, High Performance Investing. Harnessing the Power ofPension Funds to Promote Economic Growth and Workplace Integrity, 11 LAB. LAW. 59, 62-68 (1995). 85. INSTITUTE FOR FIDUCIARY EDUCATION, ECONOMICALLY TARGETED INVESTMENTS, A REFERENCE FOR PUBLIC PENSION FUNDS (1992). 86. Interpretive Bulletin 94-1, supra note 45. 87. Id. 88. INSTITUTE FOR FIDUCIARY EDUCATION, supra note 85, at Executive Summary. 89. Id. at B-2 (Table B-8). 90. The survey asked the respondents to list and rank reasons; therefore, some funds reported more than one reason. Id. 91. Id. 92. Id. at B-1 (Table B-4). 93. Id. at B-2 (Table B-6). 94. Id. at 18 (Table 16). 95. Id. (10.2% reported great difficulty). 96. Id. (6.1 % reported great difficulty). 97. Id. (6.0% reported great difficulty). 98. Teresa Ghilarducci, u.s. Pension Investment Policy and Perfect Capital Market Theory, CHALLENGE, July 1994 at 4. 99. Hearing on Pension Investments and Economic Growth Before the Joint Economic Committee on Economically Targeted Investments, 103d Cong., 2d Sess. (1994) (testimony of Lee Smith, Executive Director of Excelsior Capital Corporation), reprinted in Federal Document Clearing House Congressional Testimony (June 22, 1994). 100. ADVISORY COUNCIL ETI REpORT, supra note 75, at 2. 101. Id. at 5. 102. Id. 103. Hearing on Pension Investments and Economic Growth, supra note 100 (testimony of Robert B. Reich, Secretary of Labor). See also ADVISORY COUNCIL ETI REpORT, supra note 75, at 10-25. 104. Id.; see also Hamilton Securities Gets DOL Contract to Establish First Clearinghouse on ETIs, 21 PENS. & BENEFITS REp. (BNA) 1925 (Oct 10, 1994). 105. ERISA § 404(a)(I)(B); 29 U.S.C. § 1104(a)(I)(B) (1995). 106. Assistant Secretary OJena Berg recently stated: There should be no doubt in the minds of fiduciaries as to their absolute obligation to satisfy all of ERISA's fiduciary requirements on every investment made with pension funds including investments in ETIs. The law requires it; the Winter 1996 57 HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 57 1995-1996 Zanglein Administration is sworn to uphold it; and we at the Labor Department are committed to bringing the full force of law against pension plan fiduciaries who compromise that obligation. ETI Hearings (Prepared statement of Olena Berg, Assistant Secretary of Labor), supra note 4, at 4. 107. ERISA § 404(a)(I)(B); 29 U.S.C. §1104(a)(1)(B) (1995). 108. Preamble to Rules and Regulations for Fiduciary Responsibility; Investment of Plan Assets under the "Prudence" Rule, 44 Fed. Reg. 37,221 (June 26, 1979). 109.Id. 110.Id. 111. Interpretive Bulletin 94-1, supra note 45. 112. Id. 113. For example, a transaction involving employer-owned stock would become impermissible because it involves a collateral benefit. S8 The Kansas Journal of Law & Public Policy HeinOnline -- 5 Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 58 1995-1996