Keith Cowling, Stephen P. Dunn, and Philip R. Tomlinson Global imbalances and modern capitalism: a structural approach to understanding the present economic crisis Abstract: The world economy is riven by very large imbalances, with the U.S. economy exhibiting high levels of consumption but low savings ratios and a high current account deficit while China provides the mirror opposite. In this paper, we explore the structural causes of these imbalances that underpin the current global economic crisis. A key focus here is on the corporate sector in the United States, which has been instrumental in creating unsustainable consumptionist tendencies through the use of excessive advertising strategies. In China, changing demographics and market reforms have led to a significant rise in precautionary saving. Correcting the current imbalances requires recognizing the underlying characteristics of both modern and nonmodern capitalist economies, with appropriate responses being structural in nature in addition to any macroeconomic adjustments. Key words: advertising, consumption and saving, corporate strategy, global imbalance, modern capitalism. The American citizen’s first importance to his country is no longer that of a citizen but that of a consumer. Consumption is the new necessity. (Lynd and Lynd, 1929, p. 88) Keith Cowling is Emeritus Professor of Economics at the University of Warwick. Stephen P. Dunn is Director of Strategy at NHS East of England. Philip R. Tomlinson is a lecturer in economics in the School of Management at the University of Bath. The authors are grateful for comments and suggestions from David Bailey, Rob Branston, Dan Coffey, Marc Cowling, Nick Crafts, Ben Ferrett, Ian Jackson, Mark Harrison, Dennis Mueller, Andrew Oswald, and Carole Thornley. They are also grateful for comments from participants at the Finance in Crisis/Finance in Question conference held at the University of Manchester, UK, April 12–14, 2010, and at the 12th European Union Network for Industrial Policy (EUNIP) conference, held at the University of Reus, Spain, June 9–11, 2010. The usual disclaimer applies. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics / Summer 2011, Vol. 33, No. 4 575 © 2011 M.E. Sharpe, Inc. 0160–3477 / 2011 $9.50 + 0.00. DOI 10.2753/PKE0160-3477330403 576 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS The world economy is riven by very large imbalances: the current account deficits on one side, with the U.S. economy the most prominent case, and current account surpluses on the other side, with China being a similarly prominent case. The engine of world consumption is being driven by the United States, and this is being financed by the savings of China. While some see this as a perfectly natural state of affairs, with the U.S. economy providing an efficient home for the savings of the surplus countries, most economists see this as quite fragile and not sustainable in the longer term; indeed, some see this imbalance as at the root of the present global financial crisis (see, e.g., Hung, 2008; Wade, 2009; see also Eichengreen, 2004, 2006a, 2006b, who forewarned about the dangers of global imbalances and the need for gradual readjustment). However, the solutions that dominate the current debate concentrate mainly upon macro-policy instruments and usually see large exchange rate adjustments as being necessary to eliminate the imbalance. Recent adjustments in the U.S. dollar have been observed, probably encouraged by the governments involved, but much more is seen to be called for, achieved preferably, as seen by the U.S. authorities, by a planned appreciation of the Chinese renminbi. Coming at the present time, when financial markets are so febrile, such large changes may magnify the impact of the shocks already being experienced. Moreover, in this regard, both Keynes and other economists in the heterodox tradition have long gone beyond the conventional wisdom, arguing that a more fundamental reform of the world’s international monetary institutions is required. Keynes, for instance, argued for a new international system that shifted the burden of adjustment toward surplus countries: “The object of the new system must be to require the chief initiative from the creditor countries, whilst maintaining enough discipline in the debtor countries to prevent them from exploiting the new ease allowed them in living profligately beyond their means” (1980, p. 30). A new financial architecture has yet to emerge to accommodate such necessary changes, and while it may be time once again to reconsider the management of international trade and currency realignment so as to enable nations to pursue full employment policies without fear of external shocks (see Davidson, 1994), it is also necessary to understand the underlying characteristics and economic processes that are driving these structural imbalances. It is this issue that the current paper specifically explores, and in doing so, provides an alternative perspective on the underlying roots of the current crisis. In particular, we seek answers to critical questions as to why the United States on one hand generates huge deficits and what has given rise to huge surpluses in China? What is it about these economies Global imbalances and modern capitalism 577 that leads to the present situation where the U.S. economy is so dedicated to consumption that Americans work relatively long weekly hours, take fewer vacations, are late to retire, and yet are also so reliant on the surpluses of other countries to continue to finance their own consumption? Conversely, why are the Chinese so prepared to save a large proportion of what they earn? In linking the present imbalances in the U.S. economy to the present financial crisis, Wolf states that “[a]ny country that receives a huge and sustained inflow of foreign lending runs the risk of a subsequent financial crisis because external and domestic financial fragility will grow” (2008, p. 13). Precisely such a crisis is now happening in the United States. Wolf’s explanation: “Cheap money encouraged an orgy of financial innovation, borrowing and spending” (ibid.). But this is not the whole story. At the same time hours of work per week in the United States rose, vacations fell, and retirement was delayed. While the easy availability of cheap money certainly enables people to consume more, it would seem that other forces were at work impelling people (Americans particularly) toward a different work–leisure choice in order to sustain a higher level of consumption: this increased pressure to consume felt by Americans would seem to offer the key to understanding the spending “orgy” leading to the “huge and substantial inflow of foreign lending” experienced by the U.S. economy. What is the distinguishing feature of the U.S. economy that can account for this behavior? The United States is the example of modern capitalism, par excellence: modern capitalism is characterized by large dominant corporations in active rivalry with each other where a key feature of such rivalry is investment in creating, sustaining, and developing the market by devices such as advertising, the retailing network, and product innovation (Galbraith, 1958, 1967). As a consequence, the level of advertising is much greater in the United States compared with other high-income countries; for instance, in 2007, total advertising expenditure was approximately $43 billion greater in the United States than in the economies of France, Germany, Italy, the United Kingdom, and Japan combined (World Advertising Research Centre [WARC], 2009). This undoubtedly induces greater pressure on Americans to consume and to work in order to sustain such consumption. Indeed, the higher degree of advertising intensity in the United States can largely explain the sharp differences in observed work–leisure patterns between Americans and their counterparts in Continental Europe (namely, France and Germany), with Americans electing to work longer hours and enjoy fewer vacations so as to engage in higher levels of consumption (see Cowling et al., 2011). The key to understanding the imbalance from the U.S. side 578 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS therefore lies in the nature of modern capitalism and the solution lies in addressing such structures. In exploring these issues, this paper considers the nature of modern capitalism and its consequences for the macroeconomy, with the focus first on the United States, as a principal player and the prime example of modern capitalism. Like Galbraith (1958, 1967) and others, our analysis here draws specific links among the industrial structure, advertising, and conspicuous consumption in the U.S. economy. We then turn to the major player on the other side of the crisis, China, and try to address some structural issues that may have to be faced there. Finally, we point toward some possible structural approaches that may provide long-term solutions to the global imbalances problem. Modern capitalism, advertising, and economic behavior Modern capitalism is characterized by large dominant corporations in active rivalry with each other using a variety of weapons. While other (smaller) production units exist in industrial economies, these “firms” exist within the strategic ambit of the dominant corporation; their autonomy is more apparent than real. The long-term aim of the dominant firms is the effective monopolization of specific industries through organic growth, merger, or effective coordination with rivals. Somewhat paradoxically, rivalry and collusion coexist in such concentrated markets, with tit-fortat strategies providing a useful interpretation of such behavior, on one hand eliciting and rewarding cooperation, and on the other providing rapid retaliation for noncooperation (for a review of the argument, see Cowling and Tomlinson, 2005). Rivalry, or competitive behavior, is then diverted from price competition toward product and advertising competition, with corporations induced to invest in the market as well as production. A key feature of such rivalry is investment in advertising, the retailing network, and product innovation. This form of competition is advantageous to corporations operating in oligopolistic markets given that, compared with competing directly on price, it takes longer for rivals to respond with their own competitive strategies and thereby allows monopoly profits to be made in the meantime. While market share can be gained, this strategy enables an extension of the market, thereby reducing competition: advertising should be seen as a characteristic of corporate power, which in turn sustains and enhances such power. If the capitalist system is seen to be prone to recession or depression, then corporations may be induced to choose such strategies in an attempt to ward off the implications for themselves. Such behavior has led to a Global imbalances and modern capitalism 579 surge in investment aimed at shaping and extending the market in the twentieth century. Over the period 1919–76, advertising expenditure per person in the United States rose 150 percent (Brack and Cowling, 1983), while more recently there has been a sevenfold increase in advertising expenditure per capita over the period 1945–2005 (Cowling et al., 2011). While we would expect that globalization will tend to lead to economies converging over time, for now huge gaps remain with the U.S. investment in advertising being 11 times that of France and twice the intensity. But the extremes are seen when we compare the United States with China, with advertising per capita in the United States being 50 times that of China (WARC, 2009). With this difference in the character of capitalism between the modern economies, such as the United States, and the other emerging capitalist economies, such as China, we expect distinct differences in behavior, differences that underpin the imbalance that has appeared and intensified in recent years. If advertising and product innovation, the marketing effort in total, is seen as part of a system for creating wants, then it can also be seen as creating a continuing dissatisfaction with current levels of consumption. But is there any supporting evidence for this thesis? Kenny (1999) presents evidence of declining levels of happiness in the United States, but Europe generally shows rising happiness, with the United Kingdom being the major exception. Blanchflower and Oswald (2004) report what they claim are the first microeconomic happiness equations to be estimated for the United States and reveal life satisfaction falling over time with rising income, providing (further) support for Easterlin’s (1974, 1995) earlier views that economic growth does not necessarily ensure greater well-being. More recently, Alesina et al. (2005) provide some very suggestive results on happiness: lifetime satisfaction appears to increase with the length of vacations, whereas it appears to fall with increases in hours of work, with the United States having the shortest vacations and the longest hours. While not providing evidence directly on advertising and happiness, by promoting continuing dissatisfaction with present consumption, specifically market consumption,1 advertising could explain these various observations, and the United States, by 1 Freeman and Schettkat in their “marketisation hypothesis” argue that “[b]y working longer hours and taking short vacations, Americans earn money to buy goods on the market. By working fewer hours and taking longer vacations, Germans have more time to produce goods at home” (2002, p. 6). Alesina et al. also show Americans “giving up sleep and food preparation time as a result of working longer” (2005, p. 62). Americans are being propelled toward market consumption, consistent with the pressure of advertising. 580 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS experiencing the most intensive advertising, could reveal these effects to the greatest degree. This fits in quite nicely with James Duesenberry’s (1967) theory of consumption, which may be coming back into fashion (Hopkins and Kanbur, 2009). The theory is based on interdependent preferences, the individual is the product of society: there is a “demonstration effect” such that the individual emulates the consumption of others. Duesenberry was asking the question, why are savings of households in the United States so low and why do Americans work such long hours: overall why the drive to higher levels of consumption? His “demonstration effect” presupposes the drive’s existence: emulation can go either way—conspicuous consumption or nonconsumption. Duesenberry relies on the “character of our culture”—American culture. The question we raise is whether American culture is, to some extent, endogenous to the economic system—does the character of modern capitalism feed into the development of American culture? Advertising in the broadest sense could provide the key to answering the questions posed by Duesenberry (1967). This argument is captured eloquently in Galbraith’s (1967) management of the consumer in what he terms the “revised sequence” (see also Anderson and Dunn, 2006). In the conventional wisdom, the firm is subservient to the given preferences of consumers. Galbraith argued, however, that consumer demand was not exogenous, but is shaped by institutional processes and by particular influences such as advertising (Dunn, 2011). By managing consumers, large firms are able to recoup any substantive investment monies undertaken and establish and maintain monopoly positions. The revised sequence is broader than just the management of specific consumer demand by the firm, encompassing the wider forces that reinforce consumerism: consumers must be able to buy goods as well as desire them, so the large firms have a vested interest in ensuring this occurs such as through the provision of credit (Galbraith, 1967). The bias toward consumerism fuels the emulatory processes that drive the rat race—what Stanfield (1983, 1996) calls the “treadmill syndrome”—resulting in people working harder and harder in order to consume more and more (Folbre and Bittman, 2004; Schor, 1991). This pressure to work and earn even higher levels of income also explains the increased demand for childcare, which has exploded in recent times.2 2 As Eric Schlosser points out in Fast Food Nation: “Adjusted for inflation, the hourly wage of the average U.S. worker peaked in 1973 and then steadily declined for the next twenty-five years. During that period, women entered the workforce in record numbers, often motivated less by a feminist perspective than by a need to pay the bills. Global imbalances and modern capitalism 581 Many economists had anticipated that the twenty-first century may be dominated by issues of market saturation. Some saw this propelling the development of new industries, including those that promote consumption (Ono, 1994). Krugman has stressed the present return of such problems: “For the first time in two generations, failures on the demand side of the economy—insufficient private spending to make use of the available productive capacity—have become the clear and present limitation on prosperity for a large part of the world” (1999, p. 155). And yet this may seem strange coming from an American economist speaking with the American experience all around him. The United States has been the most significant exception to this current generality. The global lack of adequate demand has only been ameliorated by the great engine of consumption as has distinguished the U.S. economy in recent years. We see this exceptional behavior of the U.S. economy as being rooted in the enormous and growing investment in advertising, in the broader sense—all forms of the selling effort in the U.S. economy. Again, as Galbraith described it: “Advertising and its related arts thus develop the kind of man the industrial system requires—one that reliably spends his income and works reliably because he is always in need of more” (1967, pp. 209–210). Thus, Krugman’s concerns about the demand side of the economy relate to the world capitalist market economy in general, but in the case of the United States, they appear to have met a massive, if inherently fragile, response. From this perspective, we can see the world’s present economic crisis as emanating from imbalances initially created in the United States and implicit in its modernity. The structural roots of the present imbalance The influence of advertising in the United States In a sense, the present imbalance and the present crisis has its origin in the characteristics of the modern capitalist economies, the U.S. economy being the prime and most important example. Within them the nature of oligopolistic rivalry provides the basis for very high and increasing In 1975, about one-third of American mothers with young children worked outside the home; today almost two-thirds of such mothers are employed. As the sociologists Cameron Lynne Macdonald and Carmen Sirianni have noted, the entry of so many women into the workforce has greatly increased demand for the types of services that housewives traditionally perform: cooking, cleaning, and child care. A generation ago, three-quarters of the money used to buy food in the United States was spent to prepare meals at home. Today about half of the money used to buy food is spent at restaurants—mainly at fast food restaurants” (2002, p. 4). 582 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS levels of advertising expenditure. While it is the case that advertising plays a role in interfirm rivalry to induce brand switching between consumers, it is also true that the pressure of advertising and the continual, if minimal, new product innovation associated with it can be expected to induce a higher level of consumption out of current income, via creating continual dissatisfaction with present consumption. In this latter respect, there has been limited exploration of the direct effect of advertising on consumption, but when research has been done, it has tended to reveal a positive effect on the propensity to consume (Keir, 1993; Metwally and Tamaschke, 1981; Peel, 1975; Taylor and Weiserbs, 1972). However, related work on the impact of advertising on labor supply (hours of work and participation rates in market work) can be interpreted in the same way (Brack and Cowling, 1983; Cowling et al. 2011; Fraser and Paton, 2003; Giulietti and Meschi, 1991). It is probably true that the impact of advertising on consumption is more difficult to identify than that of advertising on labor supply because consumption and advertising are very much trend dominated. It is also probably true that, partly because of advertising, consumption has been very much constrained by income and the pressure to consume is reflected in this work–leisure choice; the choice of a lifestyle that demands high hours of work, high family participation in market work, restricted vacations, and delayed retirement, all characteristics of modern consumers, with the United States as the prime example.3 More widely, Galbraith (1967) demonstrated the impact of sophisticated marketing techniques on consumption and work patterns, particularly in the food, tobacco, pharmaceutical, automobile, and alcohol industries, arguing that the resulting augmented consumption patterns have similar social and economic pressures to increase working hours and augment incomes to consume more and more, which has been linked to the increase in psychological disorders. It might appear surprising that advertising can have such an impact on household behavior, particularly in an era that has been defined by some economists as the “great moderation,” a term used to describe the reduction in the volatility of (aggregate) economic variables in the mod3 In putting forward this view, we acknowledge that other factors may also be important in shaping work–leisure choices in the U.S. economy. For instance, there has been a privatization of welfare services and a noticeable retrenchment in the provision of social goods over the past 30 years (see Hacker, 2004). Such moves have raised income and wealth inequalities within the United States, and workers may be working longer to pay for their own private provision of public goods. Combined with the corporate sector’s drive to higher levels of material consumption, this has led to greater levels of indebtedness (see below), particularly among the lower social classes. For many, this is often the complex reality of chasing the “American dream.” Global imbalances and modern capitalism 583 ern economies since the early 1980s (Bernanke, 2004). Yet this “great moderation” does not appear to transcend to the micro level, where there has actually been a moderate increase in individual and household economic uncertainty and volatility, particularly with regard to income uncertainty and consumption decisions (see Davis and Kahn, 2008). While the tentative explanations here are that greater flexibility and insecurities in largely the U.S. (and the UK) labor markets may explain household behavior, recent work in behavioral economics has intriguingly unearthed some of the psychological mechanisms that may also be at play. In this respect, following a comprehensive review of recent studies in this field, DellaVigna concludes “the preference for immediate gratification (captured in these studies) appears to have identifiable neural underpinnings . . . (and) inter-temporal preferences with these features capture self-control problems” (2009, p. 318). In essence, although individuals make plans to, say, save (more) for the future, as the future gets near, they seek immediate gratification in present consumption, thus, making allowances for future needs is postponed. We would suggest that the desire for such immediate gratification is largely induced through increased advertising expenditures that make present needs more pressing. Indeed, as people procrastinate we observe low levels of saving, high levels of debt, and pension crises. Again, this is most acutely observed in the United States. Here saving rates have fallen to very low levels, with saving only taking place to help finance consumption of household durables (Ruggles, 1993). Personal savings as a proportion of disposable income in the United States have, for instance, fallen from an average of 10 percent between 1974 and 1984 to around 5 percent in 1994, and 0.6 percent in 2007 (Organisation for Economic Co‑operation and Development [OECD], 2008). At the same time, the debt of U.S. households has grown considerably over recent years, with the real level of debt rising by approximately 35 percent over the period 2001–5, leaving the total level of debt as a percentage of after-tax income at the highest level since U.S. Federal Research records began (see Mishel and Eisenberry, 2005). In this regard, it is also noticeable that the largest U.S. advertising expenditures are incurred in the automotive and finance industries with, in 2006, U.S. advertising expenditures being approximately $16.5 billion in the automotive sector, and $8.5 billion in finance (TNS Media Intelligence, 2009). Both of these sectors promote expensive purchases such as new cars and house purchase and rely heavily on debt finance to sustain consumption. Such observations, of course, neatly coincide with the Duesenberry story and Galbraith’s hypothesis: the creation and exacerbation of new desires and demands through 584 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS excessive advertising expenditures drives conspicuous consumption and in the United States (and also the United Kingdom) this has contributed to rising and unprecedented levels of public indebtedness.4 The rise in consumption in the United States has contributed to the creation of a very large current account deficit with the United States absorbing no less than 70 percent of the current account surpluses of the rest of the world, largely those of China and Japan. The global economy is seen by many as being increasingly vulnerable to these imbalances, with the U.S. current account deficit at almost 6 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2006 and the associated potential risks of a collapse in the dollar (see, e.g., International Monetary Fund [IMF], 2006; Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2004). For a long period, the United States has been in a largely unique position in being able to manage this ongoing deficit by selling U.S. assets to foreign buyers and increasingly through international borrowing, particularly from China; Kitson (2005), for instance, points out that the Chinese central bank holds approximately $1 trillion in U.S. government bonds.5 Such a situation is not sustainable in the long term, with Obstfeld and Rogoff (2004) regarding the current trajectory as “particularly precarious,” seeing close parallels with the 1970s, when the Bretton Woods system collapsed. Moreover, they stress that an easy rebalancing is more difficult with the deficit equal to 20 percent of U.S. traded goods production. Some economists now believe that a sustained adjustment in the U.S. current account deficit cannot be achieved through a temporary nominal deflation of the dollar alone, but also requires action to redress the internal imbalances (government and household) within the United States and an increase in the savings rate (El‑Ayd et al., 2005; McKinnon, 2007). Achieving this broader rebalancing requires us to recognize that the strategies of Corporate America, interacting with a compliant govern4 Galbraith anticipated such concerns back in the 1950s when he recognized that in order to sustain its production and planning processes, a large corporation requires consumers to be able to buy the goods that are produced: “The process of persuading people to incur debt, and the arrangement for them to do so, are as much a part of modern production as the making of the goods and the nurturing of wants” (1958, p. 167). This results in lower savings rates and higher levels of indebtedness for the household. It is no surprise, as Stanfield notes, that “[e]asier credit checks, lower down payments, longer repayment terms, and other inducements for people to go further and further into debt are permanent and necessary fixtures of the consumer society described in The Affluent Society” (1983, p. 591). 5 The influx of foreign capital has occurred within more liberalized U.S. financial markets and has been concomitant with the large rise in U.S. consumer borrowing. In essence, it has exacerbated the boom, particularly in real estate. Global imbalances and modern capitalism 585 ment, have been critical in creating this situation. The structural, longterm solution calls for a rebalancing of the industrial base of the U.S. economy, likely involving an increase in the importance of the export sector. This will no doubt happen as the dollar depreciates in value, as is now happening, but this is perhaps easier to achieve with appropriate industrial policies aimed at bringing about the necessary changes in infrastructure in the widest sense to include educational and scientific investment, to enable a change in industrial structure which is sustainable. In commenting on the appropriate international macro-policy package, Brittan has argued that “[i]t would need a world political authority to enforce the whole package necessary for success, ignoring the informational requirements of an appropriate macro-policy mix” (2005, p. 15): a suitable industrial policy for the United States could be a critical complementary policy. We have begun with the characteristics and consequences of modern capitalist economies like the United States. It is their modernity, their reliance on marketing investment, such as advertising, which gives rise to the inordinate pressure to consume and delay saving in these economies which in turn gives rise to the external and internal imbalances observed. The appropriate, long-term, policy response is a structural one to be adopted by these economies, but we must also look at the nonmodern economies, such as China. Within this world, the nonmodern economies take on certain characteristics, but they are led to it partly as a result of the behavior of the modern world. Whereas the United States currently has a high trade deficit, China’s current account surplus is approximately 10 percent of its GDP (IMF, 2008). Behind this pressure of external imbalance lies a huge contrast in saving rates and the intensity of advertising in the two countries: the household saving rate (as a proportion of income) in China is approximately ten times the rate in the United States (OECD, 2008), while the intensity of advertising (per capita) in China is less than one-tenth that of the United States (WARC, 2009). It is to China that we now turn. China’s high savings and market transition China’s high savings rates have not surprisingly attracted significant attention in recent years. Notwithstanding reported difficulties in relation to the adequacy and quality of available data and the coverage rates of household surveys (see Kraay, 2000), most conservative estimates of Chinese household saving indicate that it has averaged around 25 percent of income since the millennium, having reached 34 percent during the mid-1990s (Kuijs, 2005). This, of course, not only contrasts sharply 586 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS with the extremely low household savings rates discussed above for the United States (and similarly, the United Kingdom, 1.1 percent), but is also approximately twice that of France (13.3 percent), Germany (12.9 percent), Spain (13.9 percent), and three times that of Italy (8.4 percent) (see OECD, 2008). In comparing savings rates between economies, there is a temptation to view the Chinese case as reflecting long-standing differences in culture between societies. Indeed, Asian economies have tended to have higher savings rates with Japan once being the notable example6: China might therefore be exemplifying the Asian tradition. Modigliani and Cao (2004), however, suggest this is not the case. They note that historically, household saving in China has been much lower: between the 1950s and late 1970s, it averaged around 5 percent. So why the substantial increase in saving, given that China’s income per capita remains well below the major industrialized nations, and indeed its Asian neighbors (see, e.g., IMF, 2006, 2008)? Employing an error correction model, Modigliani and Cao find support for the life cycle hypothesis, with higher national income growth (as opposed to per capita income) since the late 1970s and (politically induced) demographic factors being especially important in determining China’s higher savings rate. With regard to changing demographics, the main focus is on the so-called dependency ratio, which measures the nonworking population, primarily consisting of minors and the elderly and which tend to consume rather than produce income (and so reduce national household saving), to the working population. Over the past 30 years, China’s dependency ratio has fallen significantly, and Modigliani and Cao attribute this largely to China’s birth control measures and the controversial one child per family policy introduced in the mid-1970s. They argue that this measure not only reduced over time the number of minor dependents but “it also undermined the traditional role of the [Chinese] family in providing old age support to the parents by the children, thus encouraging provisions through individual accumulation” (Modigliani and Cao, 2004, p. 166). Further evidence for the life cycle model is provided by Meng (2003), who finds that greater income uncertainty in Chinese urban areas has led to a significant rise in precautionary saving and general consumption smoothing.7 Meng traces the rise in income uncertainty to China’s 6 From the late 1960s to the mid 1980s, Japan’s household savings rate averaged 24 percent. It has subsequently fallen and is now around 3.5 percent of income (OECD, 2008). 7 Disturbingly, Meng (2003) finds that Chinese urban households are unable to smooth their education expenditure; where income falls, education consumption tends Global imbalances and modern capitalism 587 market reforms, initiated by Deng Xiaoping in the late 1970s and subsequently expanded upon, and which have led to a significant reduction in social welfare provision with, in particular, the free state provision of health and education services being replaced by market-oriented pay-per-use principles. Underdeveloped credit markets and poor credit access has resulted in a greater tendency for Chinese consumers to now save for such large purchases, which were previously freely provided. Moreover, changes to Chinese pension arrangements with moves from state-sponsored defined benefit schemes have also placed a greater onus upon individual saving (see also Feldstein, 1999). In addition, deregulation of state enterprises—now exposed to market competition—and the labor market have effectively ended China’s lifetime employment guarantee, and rising unemployment in some urban districts has become a new social and economic problem: in the late 1990s, approximately 15 million state employees were made redundant (Meng, 2003; see also Hung, 2008). Greater income and economic uncertainty in China have contributed to a higher (precautionary) savings rate, and while Meng’s study focused on urban households, Qin (2003) also reports a higher effect among rural communities, where the declining state provision of services is even more pronounced. Interestingly, in further work, Meng et al. (2005) find that the rise in precautionary saving among poorer households, combined with wider inequality, has led to such a reduction in their current consumption patterns that it has effectively increased the level of (expenditure-defined) poverty within these groups.8 These observations are both interesting and undoubtedly useful in exploring the impact of economic reform and the transition to a market economy in China upon both macro variables such as national savings rates and also the micro behavior and living standards of Chinese households. Yet what is also interesting is that the (global) corporate sector has to be reduced. This is obviously a policy concern since it affects intergenerational mobility. 8 Meng et al. provide a vivid description of the impact of the economic reforms upon Chinese society, noting between 1988 and 2002 that “housing rental subsidies were reduced, free universal health coverage fell from 66% to 22% of the population, school fees (at all levels of education) were introduced and significantly increased, while changes in the state pension system meant a decreased pension coverage for a larger segment of the population” (2005, p. 719). Meng et al. (ibid.) compare and contrast the various definitions of poverty but suggest that the expenditure-based measure is most appropriate in the Chinese case given data availability and that it accounts for the “cost of basic needs” such as food, clothing, and shelter, whereas income-based measures tend to ignore price differentials and local and regional living costs (see also Ravillion, 1994). 588 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS largely regarded China as a production base through which to exploit lowcost labor conditions primarily to export manufactures across the globe. Indeed, in this latter respect, Naughton (2007, pp. 377–423) provides a lucid and highly documented account of China’s extraordinary growth in inward foreign direct investment (FDI) and involvement in international trade over the past 20 years. In particular, Naughton notes that China has become one of the prime locations for international investment and “now accounts for a third of total so-called developing country FDI . . . with an unusually large proportion in FDI inflows in manufacturing, as opposed to services or resources” (ibid., p. 401). This growth has followed liberalization and generally more favorable Chinese policies toward transnational corporations, with the government providing investment protection agreements, a moderate tax regime and facilitation of the repatriation of profits as well as significantly less stringent approval procedures for inward FDI than observed in other East Asian economies. The predominance of manufacturing FDI clearly reflects China’s abundant supply of low-cost labor and since the early 1990s, transnationals have increasingly shifted production from other previously low-cost bases (such as in Taiwan) in East Asia to China (ibid., p. 416).9 With China’s FDI inflows averaging around 4 percent of GDP (and being twice that of neighboring South Korea, Japan, and Taiwan; see Naughton, 2007), China’s economic trajectory has become especially entwined with those of the large transnationals. In summary, while globalization might have brought some benefits for China, most notably in terms of access to new technology and the creation of new manufacturing jobs, these gains are qualified somewhat with a growing suspicion that liberalization and the market reforms have largely benefitted the (global) corporate sector and the West, which has, in particular, enjoyed low-cost Chinese imports (and low inflation) predominantly based on cheap Chinese labor. Moreover, while a rising middle class in relatively affluent cities such as Shanghai and Beijing offers corporate firms a potentially profitable consumer market, China has yet to become a major consumer society. Indeed, the data suggests the reverse is occurring, with Chinese consumption as a proportion of GDP gradually falling from 46 percent in 1995 to 37 percent in 2007 and now half that recorded in the United States (IMF, 2008). Furthermore, the rise in income and economic uncertainties and inequality for Chinese 9 An indication of the attractiveness of China as a low labor cost location is provided by Kobayashi (2004), who notes that Chinese wage costs are one-thirtieth of those in Japan. China has become the prime location for Japanese FDI in Asia. Global imbalances and modern capitalism 589 households over the past 20 years have contributed to the unprecedented rise in (precautionary) saving rates and the global imbalances that we now observe. Addressing the global imbalances In light of the problems surrounding global imbalances, the emphasis of much economic analysis has tended to focus on coordinating international macro-level economic policies, such as engineering exchange rate adjustments. There have, for instance, been calls for a real appreciation in the renminbi, amid accusations that China has been pursuing a deliberate policy of suppressing the real value of its currency vis-à-vis the dollar (see, e.g., Bergsten, 2007; Goldstein, 2007).10 However, even if such large exchange rate adjustments are achievable, they are likely to cause considerable disruption to the world economy and will only provide short-term respite unless they are accompanied by longer-term structural measures.11 While greater international coordination and reform of the world’s monetary system is clearly needed, it is important to acknowledge some of the underlying processes of the new industrial state that drive 10 It has been suggested that since the dollar is widely held as the reserve international currency, the United States is saddled with a new “Triffin” paradox, whereby the world’s central banks are induced to support the dollar since their own dollar holdings and exposure to U.S. markets are relatively large; thus, in facilitating international liquidity, the United States has to incur a trade deficit (see Morgan, 2009). Notwithstanding that such problems were largely a feature (and led to the breakdown) of the Bretton Woods era, any positive demand for dollars (as a reserve currency) would tend to be offset by a counterveiling falling demand for dollars as established by a trade deficit, at which point the exchange rate becomes relatively stable (ceteris paribus). This situation does, however, illustrate the difficulties the United States has in devaluing its currency, a point considered by Howes (2000, p. 192), who notes that during a period of constant real effective exchange rates in the 1990s, the U.S. trade deficit (in manufactures) worsened due to an uncompetitive (particularly on nonprice factors) U.S. manufacturing sector and unfavorable income elasticities of demand for imports and exports, with the United States having a relative higher propensity to import foreign goods. While the high demand for imports may be due to excessive advertising and the drive to higher levels of material consumption in the United States, the combination of these factors exacerbate industrial decline in the United States. Like us, Howes (ibid.) advocates a rebalancing away from consumption toward manufacturing investment in the U.S. economy. 11 One might also recall the Plaza Accord in 1985, which sought a “managed” devaluation of the dollar vis-à-vis the yen and the deutschemark. The accord was subsequently regarded as being a major contributing factor in the global asset price inflation that followed, particularly in Japan. Moreover, the Plaza Accord largely failed to fulfill its primary objective of alleviating the U.S. trade deficit with Japan because this deficit was structural (rather than being a product of monetary policy). 590 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS the global imbalance. Addressing the global imbalance, therefore, will require more than the fine-tuning of macroeconomic policy. It will require fundamental reform of international monetary arrangements (Davidson, 1972, 1994, 2007). But it also requires a more fundamental consideration of wider social and industrial policy. In the United States, it may be an opportune time to reconsider the Galbraithian debate on the wider effects of excessive advertising expenditures and material consumerism within the economy. At a fundamental level, we would suggest that in the United States (and also the United Kingdom), there is a central role for industrial policy in rebalancing the economy toward investment and production activities as well as investing in the cultural and educational base to counter the relentless advance of consumerism.12 Since the early 1980s, both the United States and the United Kingdom have largely neglected their industrial bases and have relied far too heavily on imports to satisfy their high domestic consumption. Addressing deficiencies in these economies’ domestic industrial bases will therefore be especially important in reducing their large trade deficits. It is beyond the scope of this paper to explore the precise form that industrial policies might take, although it is perhaps preferable that policy is geared away from the present oligopolistic structures that have had such a destabilizing effect. The form of competition chosen by oligopolistic firms, implying high and growing levels of advertising expenditure, in turn shapes consumer preferences and thus work–leisure choices. While providing a stimulus to the service sector, this generates unwanted side effects such as the unsustainable consumptionist tendencies at the root of the current imbalances. Less-concentrated structures, however, may negate such tendencies because advertising expenditures will tend to fall; see, for instance, Sutton (1991), who finds an inverted “U” relationship between levels of advertising and concentration. In sharp contrast to the United States, where unbridled consumerism has fueled the economy, China has depended (to an unprecedented degree) on export-led growth combined with a high savings ratio and low domestic consumption (see also Hung, 2008). Indeed, there is a certain irony in that bloated U.S. consumerism has been largely financed by the (largely precautionary) savings of Chinese households: these savings being channeled through the global financial system to U.S. borrowers. 12 We are not alone in calling for a renewed emphasis upon industrial policy. Wade (2009) also makes the point that there is a positive role for (Western) industrial policy to play in re-addressing the current global imbalances. Global imbalances and modern capitalism 591 Such a situation has now been shown to be untenable, and the current crisis thus offers opportunities for a careful readjustment. While a managed appreciation of the Chinese renminbi is probably now desirable, it is clear that this will lead to a painful readjustment for the Chinese economy given its heavy reliance on exports. It is therefore important that the negative effect of any such currency appreciation is mitigated through a domestic and publicly funded economic stimulus. Moreover, and aside from economic reasons, there is a strong social case for restructuring the composition of growth in China through active state intervention, if only to alleviate the rising income inequalities that have been particularly evident between urban and rural districts and are a (unintended) consequence of the market reforms (see Hung, 2008; Meng et al. 2005).13 In this vein, rural inequality might be reduced through a program of rural industrialization linked to public educational policies (Benjamin et al., 2002), which are largely nonexistent in rural areas (see Lin et al., 2002). As Galbraith (1964, 1979) argued, an active public educational program is not only social welfare enhancing, but it will also improve human capital.14 For the rural Chinese economy it may increase the transfer of rural labor into the township and village enterprise (TVE) sector for manufacturing. Such movement may in turn raise agricultural prices and incomes, thus further reducing rural inequalities. A further (global) benefit of such a scenario is that China’s level of agricultural imports subsequently rise from countries with a comparative advantage in agriculture, such as the United States: in fact, the United States has been suffering from an oversupply of agricultural produce for some time (Burfisher et al., 2001). By utilizing each country’s comparative advantage, greater (global) allocative efficiency may be achieved, while easing the bilateral trade deficit between the United States and China (Guo, 2007). At the same time, rural households in China benefit from better education and higher incomes. Such an interventionist policy approach is not as controversial as it might seem, with widespread acceptance among leading economists. 13 In this vein, it is worth noting that Galbraith first raised the issue of “insular poverty” in American Capitalism (Galbraith, 1952, ch. 8), where he pointed out that the affluence created by technological advance can cause problems for those who do not benefit from the new technology, and who are relegated to receiving low wages for work that is no longer in widespread demand. 14 Galbraith (1964, p. 66) noted that the first stage of development requires education, communication, and transportation to be provided by the state. In The Nature of Mass Poverty, Galbraith (1979, pp. 115–116) argued for a third way between unfettered capitalism and state socialism, setting out the essence of what later became identified with the notion of a “developmental state” (see Johnson, 1982). 592 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS Eichengreen (2004, 2006b), for instance, has suggested that China increase public spending on health and education, while Woo (2009) has recently suggested that such expenditures might be directed toward import-intensive investments such as overseas scholarships and the technological upgrading of China’s capital stock to that of G7 levels. Such an approach, with relevant safeguards, would fit in well with a structured approach to China’s readjustment. At a macro level, such moves should reduce China’s domestic savings rate and increase domestic consumption (thus alleviating any downward pressures on domestic demand from any currency adjustments) while at the global level, such moves would militate against the current global imbalances. Conclusion Modern and nonmodern capitalist market economies give rise to very different macroeconomic positions in the present century. Such imbalances can, of course, be sustained in the short and possibly medium term, but in the longer term many economists have questioned whether they can. The present economic crisis would suggest that such a view is probably the right one. In this paper, we suggest that the response to such a situation has to recognize the underlying characteristics of the economy and has to be structural in character, seeking a change in the structure of the underlying system in each case. The central thrust of this paper is to suggest that the global imbalances created by modern capitalism and the ensuing economic crisis requires something much deeper than simply adjustments in macroeconomic policy. In the United States and the United Kingdom, in particular, there needs to be a refocusing of policy away from an overreliance on the consumer toward raising levels of investment and production. This may imply a positive role for industrial policy to reestablish productive capacity in these economies, possibly one that steers away from promoting oligopolistic structures. In China, while market reforms have helped to generate impressive levels of economic growth, it has also led to greater economic uncertainty and rising inequality and a reduction in public service provision. Along with changing demographics, these factors have contributed to extraordinary levels of precautionary saving among households and since the mid-1990s, lower levels of consumption (as a proportion of GDP). While exchange rate adjustments are likely to be painful, Chinese domestic policy might be directed to reducing inequalities and poverty, particularly through the provision of health and education services to the poor so as to aid intergenerational mobility (see Meng, 2003; Meng et Global imbalances and modern capitalism 593 al., 2005). Such measures may go some way to reducing China’s high savings rate and allow more of the populace the opportunity to participate in the benefits of economic growth. At the global level, these structural changes in both modern and nonmodern capitalist economies may go some way toward correcting the global imbalances problem. References Alesina, A.F.; Glaeser, E.L.; and Sacerdote, B. “Work and Leisure in the U.S. and Europe: Why So Different?” Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper no. 5140, London, 2005. Anderson, S.J., and Dunn, S.P. “Galbraith and the Management of Specific Demand: Evidence from the Tobacco industry.” Journal of Institutional Economics, 2006, 2 (3), 273–296. Benjamin, D.; Brandt, L.; Glewwe, P.; and Li, G. “Markets, Human Capital and Income Inequality in an Economy in Transition: The Case of Rural China.” In R. Freeman (ed.), Inequality Around the World. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2002. Bergsten, C.F. “Currency Misalignments and the U.S. Economy.” Statement to the Trade, Ways and Means Committee, U.S. House of Representatives, Washington, DC, May 9, 2007. Bernanke, B.S. “The Great Moderation.” Address to the meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, Washington, DC, February 20, 2004 (available at www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2004/20040220/default.htm). Blanchflower, D., and Oswald, A. “Well-Being over Time in Britain and the USA.” Journal of Public Economics, 2004, 88 (7–8), 1359–1386. Brack, J., and Cowling, K.G. “Advertising and Labour Supply: Work Week and Work Year in U.S. Manufacturing, 1919–1976.” Kyklos, 1983, 36 (2), 285–303. Brittan, S. “Comment.” Financial Times, London, January 21, 2005, 15. Burfisher, M.E.; Diao X.; and Somwaru A. “WTO Negotiations: Potential Gains from Ag Policy Reform.” Agricultural Outlook, January–February 2001 (available at www .ers.usda.gov/publications/Agoutlook/Jan2001/AO278F.pdf). Cowling, K., and Tomlinson, P.R. “Globalisation and Corporate Power.” Contributions to Political Economy, 2005, 24, 33–54. Cowling, K.; Poolsombat, R.; and Tomlinson, P.R. “Advertising and Labour Supply: Why Do Americans Work Such Long Hours?” International Review of Applied Economics, 2011, 25 (3), 283–301. Davidson, P. International Money and the Real World. London: Macmillan, 1972. ———. Post Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory: A Foundation for Successful Economic Policies for the Twenty-First Century. Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar, 1994. ———. John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan, 2007. Davis, S.J., and Kahn, J.A. “Interpreting the Great Moderation: Changes in the Volatility of Economic Activity at the Macro and Micro Levels.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2008, 22 (4), 155–180. DellaVigna, S. “Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field.” Journal of Economic Literature, 2009, 47 (2), 315–372. Duesenberry, J.S. Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behaviour. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1967. Dunn, S.P. The Economics of John Kenneth Galbraith: Introduction, Persuasion and Rehabilitation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011. 594 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS Easterlin, R.A. “Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence.” In P.A. David and M.W. Reder (eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honour of Moses Abramowitz. New York: Academic Press, 1974, pp. 89–125. ———. “Will Raising the Incomes of All Increase the Happiness of All?” Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 1995, 27 (1), 35–47. Eichengreen, B. “Global Imbalances and the Lessons of Bretton Woods.” Economie Internationale, 2004, 100, 39–50. ———. “Global Imbalances: The New Economy, the Dark Matter, the Savvy Investor, and the Standard Analysis.” Journal of Policy Modelling, 2006a, 28 (6), 645–652. ———. “The Blind Men and the Elephant.” Issues in Economic Policy, 2006b, 1, 1–24. El-Ayd, A.; Barrell, R.; and Pomerantz, O. “Correcting U.S. Imbalances’ Prospects.” National Institute Economic Review, 2005, 192, 33–38. Feldstein, M. “Social Security Pension Reform in China.” China Economic Review, 1999, 10 (2), 99–107. Folbre, N., and Bittman, M. Family Time: The Social Organization of Care. London: Routledge, 2004. Fraser, S., and Paton, D. “Does Advertising Increase Labour Supply? Time Series Evidence for the UK.” Applied Economics, 2003, 35 (11), 1357–1368. Freeman, R.B., and Schettkat, R. “Marketisation of Production and the U.S.—Europe Employment Gap.” Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper no. 559, London, 2002. Galbraith, J.K. American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power. London: Hamish Hamilton, 1952. ———. The Affluent Society. Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin, 1958. ———. Economic Development. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin, 1964. ———. The New Industrial State. Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin, 1967. ———. The Nature of Mass Poverty. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1979. Giulietti, M., and Meschi, M. “L’Offerta di Lavoro Femminile: Persistenza e Partecipazione.” Economia e Lavoro, 1991, XXV, 57–71. Goldstein, M. “A (Lack of) Progress Report on China’s Exchange Rate Policies.” Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper no. 07‑5, Washington, DC, 2007. Guo, J. “Explaining Income Inequality in Rural China: A New Perspective.” Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry, UK, 2007. Hacker, J.S. “Privatising Risk Without Privatising the Welfare State: The Hidden Politics of Social Policy Retrenchment in the United States.” American Political Science Review, 2004, 98 (2), 243–260. Hopkins, E., and Kanbur, R. “Relativity, Inequality and Public Policy.” Paper presented at the Edinburgh University Conference on Relativity, Inequality and Public Policy, June 5–7, 2009. Howes, C. “U.S. Competitiveness and Economic Growth.” In C. Howes and A. Singh (eds.), Competitiveness Matters: Industry and Economic Performance in the U.S. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2000, pp. 180–205. Hung, H.F. “Rise of China and the Global Over-Accumulation Crisis.” Review of International Political Economy, 2008, 15 (2), 149–179. International Monetary Fund (IMF). World Economic Outlook. Washington DC: IMF, 2006. ———. World Economic Outlook. Washington DC: IMF, 2008. Global imbalances and modern capitalism 595 Johnson, C. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy 1925–1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1982. Keir, T. “The Aggregate Advertising—Consumption Relationship Revisited.” M.Sc.Econ. thesis, University of Warwick, Coventry, UK, 1993. Kenny C. “Does Growth Cause Happiness, Does Happiness Cause Growth?” Kyklos, 1999, 52 (1), 3–26. Keynes, J.M. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Volume XXV: Activities 1940–1944: Shaping the Post-War World: The Clearing Union. London: Macmillan, 1980. Kitson, M., and Primost, D. “Corporate Responses to Macroeconomic Changes and Shocks.” Report to the Economic and Social Research Council, Swindon, UK, 2005. Kobayashi, H. “Responses of South Korea, Taiwan and Japan to the Hollowing Out of Industry.” Waseda University, Tokyo, 2004. Kraay, A. “Household Saving in China.” World Bank Economic Review, 2000, 14 (3), 545–570. Krugman, P. The Return of Depression Economics. London: Penguin, 1999. Kuijs, L. “Investment and Saving in China.” World Bank Policy Research Paper no. 3633, Washington, DC, 2005. Lin, J.Y.; Tao, R.; Liu, M.; and Zhang, Q. “The Problem of Taxing Peasants in China.” Working paper, China Centre for Economic Research, Beijing University, 2002. Lynd, R.S., and Lynd, H.M. Middletown: A Study in American Culture. New York: Harcourt Brace and Company, 1929. McKinnon, R.I. “Review of Eichengreen B., Global Imbalances and the Lessons of Bretton Woods, Cambridge, MIT Press (2007).” Journal of Economic Literature, December 2007, XLV, 1038–1042. Meng, X. “Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing, and Precautionary Saving in Urban China.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 2003, 31 (3), 465–485. Meng, X.; Gregory, R.; and Wang, Y. “Poverty, Inequality and Growth in Urban China, 1986–2000.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 2005, 33 (4), 710–729. Metwally, M.M., and Tamaschke, H.U. “Advertising and the Propensity to Consume.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics, 1981, 43 (3), 273–285. Mishel, L., and Eisenberry, R. “What’s Wrong with the Economy?” Economic Policy Institute, Policy Memorandum, Washington, DC, December 21, 2005. Modigliani, F., and Cao, S.L. “The Chinese Saving Puzzle and the Life-Cycle Hypothesis.” Journal of Economic Literature, March 2004, XLII, 145–170. Morgan, J. “How Should We Conceive the Continued Resilience of the U.S. Dollar as a Reserve Currency?” Review of Radical Political Economics, 2009, 41 (1), 43–61. Naughton, B. The Chinese Economy: Transitions and Growth. Cambridge: MIT Press, 2007. Obstfeld, M., and Rogoff, K. “The Unsustainable U.S. Current Account Position Revisited.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 10869, Cambridge, MA, 2004. Ono, Y. Money, Interest and Stagnation: Dynamic Theory and Keynes’ Economics. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). Economic Outlook, December 2008, 84 (2). Peel, D. “Advertising and Aggregate Consumption.” In K.G. Cowling, J.C. Cable, M.K. Kelly, and T. McGuinness (eds.), Advertising and Economic Behaviour. Houndmills, UK: Macmillan, 1975. 596 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS Qin, D. “Determinants of Household Savings in China and Their Role in Quasi-Money Supply.” Economics of Transition, 2003, 11 (3), 513–537. Ravillion, M. Poverty Comparisons. Switzerland: Harwood Academic, 1994. Ruggles, R. “Accounting for Saving and Capital Formation in the United States 1947–1991.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1993, 7 (2), 3–17. Schlosser, E. Fast Food Nation: What the All-American Meal Is Doing to the World. London: Penguin, 2002. Schor, J.B. The Overworked American: The Unexpected Decline of Leisure. New York: Basic Books, 1991. Stanfield, J.R. “The Affluent Society After Twenty-Five Years.” Journal of Economic Issues, September 1983, XVII (3), 589–607. ———. John Kenneth Galbraith. London: Macmillan, 1996. Sutton, J. Sunk Costs and Market Structure: Price Competition, Advertising and the Evolution of Concentration. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1991. Taylor, L.D., and Weiserbs, D. “Advertising and the Aggregate Consumption Function.” American Economic Review, September 1972, 62 (4), 642–655. TNS Media Intelligence. “U.S. Advertising Expenditures.” 2009. Wade, R. “From Global Imbalances to Global Reorganisations.” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 2009, 33 (4), 539–562. Wolf, M. “Comment on Global Imbalances.” Financial Times, October 7, 2008, 13. Woo, W.T. “China and the Current Global Economic Crisis.” Testimony before the U.S.–China Economic and Security Commission, Washington, DC, February 17, 2009. World Advertising Research Centre (WARC). “World Advertising Data.” 2009 (available at www.warc.com).