AMERICAN UNIVERSITY Department of Economics Comprehensive Examination January 2013 Advanced Heterodox Theory Page 1 of 8 [Contains corrections of typos in Macro section] Instructions: This exam has two sections, Macro and Micro. You must answer both sections; follow the directions in each section carefully. Each section receives equal weight in the grading; therefore, you should spend an equal amount of time (about 2 hours and 30 minutes) on each section (Macro and Micro). Please make sure that all math and graphs are intuitively explained, all diagrams are clearly labeled, and all answers are responsive to the specific questions asked (no credit for extraneous material). The time limits suggest the expected length and depth of your answers. Only the calculators provided by the proctor are permitted; no other electronic devices are allowed. All answers are expected to demonstrate mastery of the material at the PhD level. MACRO SECTION (2 hours and 30 minutes total) Directions: Choose any two (2) questions. 1 hour and 15 minutes per question. 1. Answer the following questions concerning Hein and Stockhammer’s post-Keynesian “story” for a Phillips Curve/NAIRU model: a. On the aggregate demand side, the saving and investment functions are as follows: hz hz g g 0 g1 z g 2 i and i (1 sR ) v v where = S/K is the saving-capital ratio, h is the profit share, z is the utilization rate (ratio of output/potential output), v is the capital-potential output ratio, i is the interest rate, is the debt-capital ratio, sR is the rentiers’ saving rate (0 < sR < 1), and g = I/K is the investment-capital ratio (accumulation rate, or growth rate of capital stock). First, state the assumptions and explain the rationale for each equation. Then, find the stability condition, solve for the short-run equilibrium utilization rate z*, and find the effect of an increase in the interest rate z*/i. What are the “normal” and “puzzling” cases for this derivative, and what is the intuition for them? (In this part, you may ignore expected inflation and treat i as exogenously set by central bank policy.) b. On the aggregate supply (distribution and pricing) side of the model, p is the price level (so p̂ is the inflation rate, with superscripts e for expected and u for unexpected), expected inflation equals one-period lagged inflation ( pˆ e pˆ t 1 ), and e is the employment rate (which, for simplicity, is in a constant proportion to utilization e = xz with x > 0). The profit share is h = m/(1+m), where m is the mark-up rate on unit labor costs (there are no raw materials costs for simplicity). The firms’ target for the profit share is hFT h0 , and the actual (realized) profit share is h h0 h2 pˆ u . The workers’ target for the wage share is (1 h)WT W0 W1e , and the actual (realized) wage share is 1 h W0 W1e W2 pˆ u . Page 2 of 8 Solve for the short-run Phillips Curve and also find the solution for the medium-run equilibrium NAIRU employment rate, eN. Represent these on a pair of graphs showing income distribution (1 – h) and unexpected inflation ( pˆ u pˆ ) on the vertical axes. i. What is it that reconciles the distributional targets of the workers and firms when these are inconsistent in the short run? in the long run? ii. How does an increase in unexpected inflation p̂ u affect the distribution of income between wages and profits, and between rentiers’ and firms shares of the profits? c. What would be the effects of an increase in firms’ monopoly power (an increase in h0) on (i) inflation in the short run and (ii) the NAIRU employment rate eN in the medium run? What is the intuition for each of these effects? How would the economy adjust to the new medium-run equilibrium? Analyze graphically and explain what must be assumed about (1) monetary policy and (2) whether the short-run equilibrium is “normal” or “puzzling” in order for the economy to converge to the new steady state at a higher h0 (say, h0). d. Suppose that the firms’ target profit share is an increasing function of the interest rate, hFT h0 h1i . First, briefly discuss the rationale for this assumption. Then, analyze (graphically and intuitively) how this would affect the stability of the economy’s adjustment toward the NAIRU employment rate eN. 2. Analyze and explain the effects of an increase in the saving rate (either or s, depending on the notation of the model) on long-run economic growth in any three (3) of the following four models. If relevant to the model, also analyze and explain the effects on income distribution, and distinguish short-run versus long-run effects (and show adjustment dynamics). NOTES: Mathematical solutions and graphs are expected for parts a. and b.; answers to c. and d. can be mostly graphical and intuitive, but you should define the variables and explain key equations as needed. For all models, be sure to discuss intuitively why the long-run equilibrium growth rate rises, falls, or remains unchanged (i.e., explain the causal mechanism). Typo fixed in 2.c. below: a. A Classical-Marxian model (Foley & Michl version) with full capacity utilization (u = 1) and full employment or a constant unemployment rate (gK = n). The saving function is gK + = (r +) – (1–)(1– ). where gK is the rate of capital accumulation, 0 < < 1is the depreciation rate, r is the net profit rate, and 0 < < 1 is the weight on future consumption in the capitalists’ intertemporal consumption function. b. An investment-constrained neo-Keynesian growth model—use the Foley & Michl version, in which u < 1 is the ratio of actual output to potential or full-capacity output, the investment function is giK + = + (r +), and are positive parameters, and the saving function is the same as in part a. The distributional closure is w (1 )ux . Be sure to include an analysis of the stability condition in your solution. c. Dutt’s (2006) model of growth determined by both aggregate demand and aggregate supply, with endogenous “animal spirits” ˆ (l n) and productivity growth aˆ (l n) ; the saving function is gs = su and the investment function is gi = + u. d. Aghion and Howitt’s model of endogenous growth with neo-Schumpeterian technological change, in which the saving function is g = s–1 – (0 < s < 1, 0 < < 1) and the innovation or R&D function is g g~ ( ) ( g~ 0 ). Page 3 of 8 3. Suppose a country’s economy is described by the following functions (with all variables in growth rate form): imports: m = m(e + p* p) + my exports: x = x(e + p* p) + xy* y ( x x a a) prices: p=+w–q output: labor productivity (Verdoorn’s Law): q = q0 + y balance-of-payments equilibrium (assuming no capital flows): p x p* e m a. First, show how the appropriate equations can be used to solve for the export-led, cumulative causation (ELCC) growth rate yE. Which equations and what assumptions are required to obtain this solution? Which equation(s) is (are) ignored and why? i. Find and interpret the condition for stability of the equilibrium at y = yE. ii. What is implicitly assumed about the balance of payments in this model? What would have to happen if the country’s growth led to a current account deficit? b. Second, show how the appropriate equations can be solved for the balance-of-paymentsconstrained growth (BPCG) rate yB. Again, be sure to indicate which equations and what assumptions are required, and discuss which equation(s) is (are) ignored and why. i. If the real exchange rate is constant in the long run (i.e., long-run relative purchasing power parity [PPP] holds), which equations do not matter to the long-run solution and why not? ii. What is implicitly assumed about (the growth rate of) domestic expenditures a in this model? c. Suppose the country succeeds in increasing the income elasticity of its export demand x through export-promotion efforts. What are the predicted effects on growth in each of the two models, ELCC and BPCG (assuming PPP in the latter case)? Even if the growth effects are similar, are the causal mechanisms different? Discuss in depth. 4. Consider a “conflicting claims” model of inflation combined with a neo-Kaleckian model of aggregate demand. The wage share is = a0W/P, where W is the nominal wage, a0 is the labor coefficient (hours per unit of output), and P is the price level. The profit share is = 1 – . The price is set via mark-up pricing: P = (1 + z)a0W (labor is the only variable cost, there are no raw materials, and the mark-up rate is z > 0). The capacity utilization rate is proxied by the output-capital ratio, u = Y/K. Answer the following questions: a. First, assume that wage and price increases are governed by the reaction functions Wˆ ( w ) u and Pˆ ( f ) , where w and f are the workers’ and firms’ respective targets for the wage share, with ,, > 0. Briefly explain the behavior represented by these equations and especially the rationale for the u term. b. Suppose that labor productivity grows at the exogenously given rate â0 . Find the equation for the “distribution curve” (DC, or ˆ 0 ) and determine its slope in u space. Does DC necessarily slope upward or downward, or can it slope either way, and if so what is the condition for a positive or negative slope? Solve and draw all possible cases on an appropriate graph (or graphs), given the functions as specified in part a.; explain the intuition for each possible case. (Question 4 continues and Question 5 is found on the next page) Page 4 of 8 c. On the aggregate demand side, the economy is closed (no trade), and there is no government or depreciation of capital for simplicity. There are positive savings out of wages, but at a lower rate than out of profits, so the saving function is = S/K = [sr + sw(1)]u with 0 < sw < sr < 1. The investment function is g = I/K = + + u, with , , > 0. i. Solve the aggregate demand side of the model for the goods market equilibrium condition (“IS curve”). Find an explicit (reduced form) solution for the equilibrium utilization rate u as a function of the profit share . ii. What do you have to assume for stability of the goods market and an economically meaningful solution? iii. Is aggregate demand (measured by u) wage-led or profit-led, or can it be either? If it can be either, find and interpret the condition for wage-led vs. profit-led demand. Explain your result in terms of the parameters of this specific model. d. Combine the two curves (IS and DC) on a series of diagrams in u space. Show all possible cases (in terms of the relative slopes of the curves) given the functions specified above (show only possible cases). Analyze (graphically) the conditions on the slopes of the two curves for the economy to be stable or unstable, assuming that output (goods market) adjustment is instantaneous but wage/price (distributional) adjustment is slow and gradual. What is the intuition for the unstable case(s), if any are possible? e. Suppose that the labor union movement is weakened by new legislation, so that the workers’ target for the wage share w falls. Analyze the effects using IS and DC curves for all possible, stable cases, and explain. 5. First, explain in detail (a) the original neoclassical-Keynesian synthesis model of the 1940s60s, and (b) a typical “new consensus model” (NCM) of the 1990s-2000s. How do they each model key features of the macroeconomy such as aggregate demand, aggregate supply, labor markets, and monetary policy? (You may limit your discussion to closed economy versions of these models.) Be sure to compare and contrast these synthesis/consensus models: what do they have in common and how do they differ? Then, discuss in depth the main criticisms that post-Keynesian or heterodox (PKH) economists would make of these models (both old synthesis and new consensus). What kind of automatic adjustment mechanism does each model have for restoring full employment or a NAIRU? Without developing a full-blown alternative model, indicate how PKH economists would modify the key equations of the modern NCM approach (what different assumptions would they introduce?). Are there any parts of the NCM that have moved closer to a PKH point of view? [You need not give an exhaustive list of criticisms and alternatives; rather, you should focus on a few of the most important points and modifications for each relationship from the PKH perspective.] (The Micro Section starts on the next page) Page 5 of 8 MICRO SECTION (2 hours and 30 minutes total) This section has two parts A and B; you must answer both parts A and B and there is some choice in each part. Part A - Problems. Choose one (1) of the following questions. [1 hour and 30 minutes] 1) Bargaining and Institutions: PLAYER A PLAYER B Left Right Left ΔA, ΔB X, x+εB Right x+εA, x ΔA, ΔB The above box represents a typical coordination problem, where ΔA, ΔB < x represent the “breakdown” values which occur when the coordination fails, and εA, εB represent the relative advantage of player A and B, respectively, when they succeed in an (asymmetric) bargain, and ΔA > ΔB. Let p be that probability A will play Right. a) Find p*, the probability that makes B indifferent between playing Left and Right. When will B play left? b) Explain and show the relationship between the breakdown value and p*. c) Explain how, according to Knight, this situation of an individual actor playing Left, or Right, might be turned into a general expectation of behavior, an institution that generates a “class”-type pattern of inequality. d) Use this model to explain any one empirical outcome seen in a reading in the course. e) Suppose that a new institution is available such that the payoffs are now: PLAYER A PLAYER B Left Left’ Right’ ΔA, ΔB x+ εA’, x Right x+εA, x ΔA, ΔB And εA’> εA, p = probability that B will play L’. Will A always adopt the new institution? Explain. (Question 1 continues on the next page) Page 6 of 8 f) Suppose that a different new institution is available such that the payoffs are now as below, and p = probability that A adopts the new institution (plays L’): PLAYER A PLAYER B Left Right’ Left’ ΔA, ΔB X, x+ εB’ Right x+εA, x ΔA, ΔB Will B ever be able adopt the new institution? Explain. g) Compare the two cases. Which player is more likely to switch institutions? Give an intuitive explanation of this outcome. 2) Contract Enforcement A population of individuals faces a prisoners’ dilemma-type situation, with payoffs as in the box below and a > b > c > d. One possible solution to this dilemma is to “inspect” the possible trading partner and use local information on player reputation to decide how to play. PLAYER 1 PLAYER 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate b, b d, a Defect a, d c, c Players who inspect are called “Inspectors.” They pay a cost of δ to inspect and find a cooperator. The alternative behavior is to play defect. There are α Inspectors in the population. a) Write down the expected payoffs for each type of individual (Inspectors and nonInspectors). b) Find the equilibrium share of Inspectors in the population. c) Is this equilibrium stable? How many total equilibria are there? Explain. d) What can you say about the Pareto efficiency of this equilibrium? e) What happens to the equilibrium if δ increases? What does this imply for which equilibrium is likely to be achieved and Pareto efficiency? f) Could δ be a quasi-parameter as defined by Avner Greif. Explain. g) Relate this model to one historical example from Greif or another relevant source. Page 7 of 8 3) Chris (C) and Pat (P) are partners in a household with one child. Chris earns an income of $400 per week and Pat earns an income of $200 per week. They are each trying to allocate 50 hours of free time weekly between play time with their child (K), and personal leisure (L) (time spent working in the market is exogenous). Thus, the time constraint is given by 50= Ki + Li . Play time is a public good, i.e., Chris and Pat derive utility from the amount of time each parent spends playing with their child. In the event of divorce, social norms require that Chris and Pat individually spend 20 hours of play time with their child. Each no longer derives utility from their partner's play time with their child (i.e. play time is no longer a public good). Their utility functions take the following form: 1 m 1 U C ln 400 ln K C ln K P ln LC , 4 4 2 1 m 1 U P ln 200 ln K P ln K C ln LP , 2 4 4 where m is an indicator variable which takes the value 1 if the couple stays married, and 0 if the couple decides to divorce. a) What are the divorce threat points (m = 0, those that would be used for the cooperative Nash game)? b) What is the equilibrium allocation under a non-cooperative marriage? Compare to the divorce threat points. Why are these different? c) How will the threat points change if Pat is altruistic, giving a weight of 0.3 to Chris’ utility? How will this change the Nash bargaining equilibrium (in general, do not attempt to solve for it)? Explain this outcome. d) How can a Nash Cooperative Bargaining model of marriage be used to explain rising US and British divorce rates as women entered the labor force in the 1970s? Explain. e) How might women’s increased labor force participation affect non-cooperative bargaining outcomes? Explain. f) Compare conclusions you would draw from two different Nash Cooperative bargaining models of the US/Britain dynamic in d) —one using a divorce threat point and one using the non-cooperative equilibrium as a threat point (the so-called “harsh words and burnt toast” equilibrium). (Micro Part B is on the next page) Page 8 of 8 Part B - Essay. Choose one (1) of the following. [1 hour] 1) Explain the importance of the “Constitutional Conundrum” to economic analysis. Explain the implications for this for neo-classical microeconomics. Under which conditions would the neo-classical model be expected to accurately predict outcomes? Under which conditions not? Make explicit reference to models and evidence in the area of heterodox microeconomics. 2) In 1981, Douglass North wrote “competition in the face of ubiquitous scarcity dictates that the more efficient institutions will survive and the inefficient ones will perish.” Evaluate this proposition in such a way as to offer an explanation of persisting underdevelopment. Make explicit reference to the concepts, models, and evidence in the area of heterodox microeconomics.