Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review ES World Congress August 2010 Richard Blundell University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies © Institute for Fiscal Studies Empirical Evidence and Earnings Tax Design: L Lessons from f the h Mirrlees Mi l Review R i • The role Th l off evidence id is i loosely l l organised i d under d five fi headings: 1. Key margins of adjustment to tax reform 2. Measurement of effective tax rates 3 The importance of information, 3. information complexity and salience 4. Evidence on the size of responses 5 Implications 5. I li i for f tax design d i Increased empirical knowledge: – some examples • labour supply responses for individuals and families – at the intensive and extensive margins • taxable income elasticities – top of the income distribution using tax return information • consumer responses to indirect taxation – nonseparability with leisure and variation in price elasticities • income uncertainty – persistence & magnitude of earnings shocks over life-cycle • ability to (micro (micro-)simulate )simulate marginal and average rates – simulate ‘optimal’ reforms Key Margins of Adjustment • Extensive and intensive margins of labour supply – Both margins both matter – Theyy matter for tax p policy y evaluation and design g – And they matter empirically in different ways by age and demographic groups Employment for men by age – FR, UK and US 2007 100% 90% FR UK US 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) Extensive and intensive margins for women Female Employment p y byy age g – US,, FR and UK 2007 0.90 0.80 FR UK US 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) 66 68 70 72 74 Female Hours by age – US, FR and UK 2007 1600 FR 1400 UK US 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 Female Hours by age – US, FR and UK 1977 1600 FR 1400 UK US 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 0 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 The extensive – intensive distinction is important for a number n mber of reasons • Understanding responses to tax and welfare reform – Heckman, Rogerson, Wise, .. all highlight the importance of extensive labour supply margin • The extensive and intensive elasticities are also key parameters in the recent literature on tax design – referenced heavily in this Review. Why is this distinction important for tax design? • A ‘large’ extensive elasticity at low earnings can ‘turn around’ the impact of declining social weights – implying i l i a hi higher h ttransfer f tto llow earning i workers k th than those out of work – potentially a role for earned income tax credits • But how do individuals perceive the tax rates implicit in y - salience? the tax credit and benefit systems – are individuals more likely to ‘take-up’ if generosity increases? – suggests a move to a ‘single integrated family benefit’ – we argue g it is more difficult to integrate g benefits with the tax system g other than labour supply/hours y • Importance of margins – use of taxable income elasticities Focus first on tax rates on lower incomes P Possible ibl defects d f t in i currentt welfare/benefit lf /b fit systems t • Participation tax rates (PTRs) and effective marginal tax rates (EMTRs) at the bottom remain very high in UK and elsewhere • EMTRs are well over 80% for some low income working families – because of phasing-out phasing out of the various means means-tested tested benefits and tax credits – and overlap of these with the income tax system 40% 4 50% % 60% 70% 80 0% Average EMTRs across the earnings distribution for different family types 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000 1100 1200 Employer cost (£/week) Single, no children P Partner not working, ki no children hild Partner working, no children Lone parent P Partner not working, ki children hild Partner working, children Mirrlees Review (2010) What about the size of labour supply responses? Structural Model Elasticities – low education lone parents ((b)) Youngest g Child Aged g 4-11 Weekly Earnings 0 Density Extensive Intensive 0.380 0 380 ((.020) 020) 0.321 (.009) 0 172 ((.005) 0.172 005) 0.068 (.003) 0 820 ((.042) 0.820 042) 0.085 0 08 ((.009) 009) 0.219 (.025) 0 194 ((.020) 0.194 020) 0.102 (.010) 0.4327 50 0 01 0.1575 150 0.1655 250 0 1298 0.1298 350 0.028 Employment elasticity Blundell and Shephard (2010) Structural Model Elasticities – low education lone parents (c) Youngest Child Aged 0-3 Weeklyy Earnings Densityy Extensive Intensive 0 0.5942 50 0.1694 0.168 (.017) 0.025 (.003) 150 0 0984 0.0984 0 128 ((.012) 0.128 012) 0 077 ((.012) 0.077 012) 250 0.0767 0.043 (.004) 0.066 (.010) 350 0 0613 0.0613 0 016 ((.002) 0.016 002) 0 035 ((.005) 0.035 005) Participation elasticity 0.536 (.047) Blundell and Shephard (2010) • Differences in intensive and extensive margins by age and demographic composition can have important implications for the design of the tax schedule... Implications for Tax Reform • Change transfer/tax rate structure to match lessons from ‘new’ optimal tax analysis and empirical evidence: • Lower marginal rates at the bottom – means-testing should be less aggressive – at least for some key groups => • Age-based taxation – distinguish by age of youngest child for mothers/parents – pre-retirement ages – points to a ‘life-cycle’ rearrangement of tax incentives and benefit payments to match elasticities – empirical p results suggest gg significant g increases in employment and earnings Top tax rates and taxable income elasticities A revenue maximising top bracket tax rate: t = 1 / (1 + a·e) a - is the Pareto parameter e - taxable income elasticity Pareto distribution as an approximation to the income distribution Pro obability density ( log scale ) 0.0100 0.0010 Pareto distribution Actual income distribution 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 £100 000 £150,000 £100,000 £150 000 £200,000 £200 000 £250,000 £250 000 £300,000 £300 000 £350,000 £350 000 £400,000 £400 000 £450,000 £450 000 £500,000 £500 000 Pareto parameter quite accurately estimated at 1.8 Taxable Income Elasticities at the Top (UK) Simple Difference (top 1%) 1978 vs 1981 0.32 1986 vs 1989 0.38 1978 vs 1962 0.63 2003 vs 1978 0.89 Full time series 0.69 (.12) DiD using (top 5-1% 5 1% as control) 0.08 0.41 0.86 0.64 0.46 (.13) => revenue maximising tax rate for top 1% of ≈ 55%. - Note also the key relationship between the size of elasticity y and the tax base => capital gains tax reforms, etc Implications for Tax Reform • Key role of labour supply responses at the extensive and intensive margins – both matter but differ by gender, age, ed. and composition • Results suggest gg lower marginal g rates at the bottom – means-testing should be less aggressive – at least for some key low income groups • Reduce complexity of benefit and tax credit system – move to a single integrated family benefit • Taxable income elasticities at the top – limited room for tax rate rises without changes to tax base • Endogenous family composition and dynamics? Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: L Lessons ffrom th the Mi Mirrlees l R Review i Five building blocks for the role of evidence in tax design design…. • Key margins of adjustment to tax reform • Measurement of effective tax rates • The importance of information information, complexity and salience • Evidence on the size of responses • Implications for tax design • Additional role for earnings tax design to undo the distributional effects of the rest of the reform package … S hhttp://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesReview See // if k/ i l R i © Institute for Fiscal Studies Some Additional References (in addition to papers in the Dimensions volume) Besley, T. and S. Coate (1992), “Workfare versus Welfare: Incentive Arguments for Work Requirement in Poverty Alleviation Programs”, American Economic Review, 82(1), 249-261. Blundell, R. (2006), “Earned income tax credit policies: Impact and Optimality”, The 2005 Adam Smith Lecture, Lecture Labour Economics, Economics 13, 13 423 423-443. 443 Blundell, R, Bozio, A. and Laroque, G.(2010), “The extensive and intensive margins of labour supply: Hours worked in the US US, UK & France" France , mimeo, mimeo IFS IFS. Blundell, R.W., Duncan, A. and Meghir, C. (1998), "Estimating Labour Supply Responses using Tax Policy Reforms", Econometrica, 66, 827-861. Blundell, R. and Hoynes, H. (2004), "In-Work Benefit Reform and the Labour Market", in Richard Blundell, David Card and Richard .B. Freeman (eds) S ki a P Seeking Premier i L League E Economy. Chicago: Chi U University i it off Chi Chicago P Press. Blundell, R. and MaCurdy (1999), "Labour Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches", in Ashenfelter and Card (eds) Approaches (eds), Handbook of Labour Economics, Economics Elsevier North-Holland. Blundell, R., Meghir, C., and Smith, S. (2002), ‘Pension incentives and the pattern of early p y retirement’, Economic Journal, 112, C153–70. Blundell, R., and A. Shephard (2008), ‘Employment, hours of work and the optimal taxation of low income families’, IFS Working Papers , W08/01 Brewer, M. A. Duncan, A. Shephard, M-J Suárez, (2006), “Did the Working Families Tax Credit Work?”, Labour Economics, 13(6), 699-720. Card, David and Philip K. Robins (1998), "Do Financial Incentives Encourage Welfare Recipients To Work?", Research in Labor Economics, 17, pp 1-56. Chetty, R Chetty R. (2008) (2008), ‘Sufficient Sufficient statistics for welfare analysis: a bridge between structural and reduced-form methods’, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Working Paper 14399 Diamond, P. (1980): "Income Taxation with Fixed Hours of Work," Journal of Public Economics, 13, 101-110. Eissa, Nada and Jeffrey Liebman (1996), "Labor Supply Response to the Earned Income Tax Credit", Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXI, 605-637. IImmervoll, ll H H. Kl Kleven, H H. K Kreiner, i C C, and dS Saez, E E. (2005) (2005), `W Welfare lf Reform R f in i European Countries: A Micro-Simulation Analysis’ Economic Journal. Keane, M.P. and Moffitt, R. (1998), "A Structural Model of Multiple Welfare Program g Participation p and Labor Supply", pp y International Economic Review, 39(3), 553-589. Kopczuk, W. (2005), ‘Tax bases, tax rates and the elasticity of reported income’, J Journal l off Public P bli E Economics, i 89 2093 89, 2093–119. 119 Laroque, G. (2005), “Income Maintenance and Labour Force Participation”, Econometrica 73(2), Econometrica, 73(2) 341-376 341-376. Mirrlees, J.A. (1971), “The Theory of Optimal Income Taxation”, Review of Economic Studies,, 38,, 175-208. Moffitt, R. (1983), "An Economic Model of Welfare Stigma", American Economic Review, 73(5), 1023-1035. Saez, E. (2002): "Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive versus Extensive Labor Supply Responses," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1039 1073 1039-1073.