AN ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS OF Mark Ross for the degree of Agricultural and Master of Science in Resource Economics presented on May 25, 1984. Title: Opportunity Costs: Irrigation vs. Hydropower Abstract approved: In ^- «' " 'Bruce'A'/ McttTrf recent years we have seen increasing the allocation of PNW water resources. are vs. conflicts debate In particular there over using the river system for electricity production. Denying over the irrigation hydroelectric system water implies higher costs to electricity consumers as producers substitute more expensive nonhydro resources. This on research looked at the impact of new PNW electricity consumers. assumptions pumping take This was done under varying demand response of irrigation water. difference to of irrigation and farmer payments for The study also examined the between the current policy of allowing all the water they need, and a policy farmers in withdrawals are limited in periods of low streamflow. which Simulations were run to determine the amount electricity production lost because of withdrawals. results of were then used in a series of These simulations to estimate the economic impacts under the various assumptions and policies. It was electricity order of found that consumers. $200/acre significantly irrigation caused losses to In some cases this loss was on the of irrigated land. The mitigated under the interruptible loss was policy. Farmer payments for irrigation energy also reduced the loss to consumers. Opportunity Costs: Irrigation vs. Hydropower by Mark Ross A THESIS submitted to Oregon State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science Completed May 25, 1984 Commencement June 19 85 APPROVED: Pro€'essor of Agricultural & Resource ETconomics in charge of Major _=;—v>^- ts 7 Head of Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics Dean of Graduates Schoo Date thesis .is presented May 25, 1984 AKNOWLEDGEMENT I would like to take this opportunity to thank the many people who have helped me in my program. My major professor, in Dr. Bruce A. McCarl, was crucial providing a funded project to enable me to complete program. His my insights and encouragement were very helpful (if at times frustrating). I would committee, Dr. like to A. thank the other members of my Gene Nelson, and Dr. Stanley F. Miller for their patience and understanding as the project dragged on through its many changes. A special thanks to the following people at the BPA: John Wilkins John Dillard Art Evans Pam Marshall Without their help, the project would not have been completed. To all of my fellow students and friends, thanks and warm feelings. Especially to Ann a heartfelt Wilson, Andy Gatti, and Kasi Beal who helped me through my operation and the ensuing depression. Most of all: thanks to my parents who always told me I could accomplish whatever I set out to do. You were right. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page I. INTRODUCTION II. BACKGROUND AND THEORY Physical Relationships Economic Relationships Interruptible Water Policy III.. METHODOLOGY Electricity Loss Economic Analysis: Inelastic Demand Noninterruptible Model Interruptible Model Economic Analysis: Elastic Demand Supply Conditions Demand Conditions Market Equilibrium Change in Consumers' Surplus IV. RESULTS AND CONCLUSIONS Energy Losses Economic Results General Results Noninterruptible Policy Interruptible Policy Comparison of Policies Conclusions and Implications 1 10 10 12 21 23 23 29 30 31 33 33 34 36 37 40 40 43 43 44 52 61 62 BIBLIOGRAPHY 74 APPENDIX 76 LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page 1-1 Annual Streamflov/ - Bonneville Dam 4 1-2 Hydro System Generation 5 II-l Demand Models 14 II-2 Average Price 18 III-l Map of Development Areas 25 LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1-1 Streamflow Probabilities 7 III-l Characteristics of Development Areas 24 IV-1 Generating Loss 41 IV-2 Noninterruptible Policy East High 47 IV-3 Noninterruptible Policy Umatilla II 48 IV-4 Noninterruptible Policy Horse Haven Hills I 49 IV-5 Noninterruptible Policy Grande Ronde 50 IV-6 Noninterruptible Policy Combined Areas 51 IV-7 Interruptible Policy East High 55 IV-8 Interruptible Policy Umatilla II 56 IV-9 Interruptible Policy Horse Haven Hills I 57 IV-10 Interruptible Policy Grande Ronde 58 IV-11 Interruptible Policy Combined Areas 59 IV-12 Comparison of Policies East High 66 IV-13 Comparison of Policies Umatilla II 67 IV-14 Comparison of Policies Horse Haven Hills I 68 Page IV-15 Comparison of Policies Grande Ronde 69 IV-16 Comparison of Policies Combined Areas 7 0 OPPORTUNITY COSTS: IRRIGATION VS. HYDROPOWER I. INTRODUCTION The valuable Columbia River resources in Northwest. however, the As major used increases development and economic uses of generation, fisheries support, is in tributaries the the growth and recreation. to one river irrigation, control continue, system are the dam In the future, use may well diminish the use of amount of hydroelectric the For example, increasing reduces the power that can be generated. recent years we have seen public concern regarding allocation of river waters in the region. The current debate over irrigation development in the East High of At transportation, levels for the needs of migratory fish In been Pacific Additionally, flooding. rivers for one or more other uses. water of have to these resources are being reached. time hydroelectric system the population limits present and its Washington Another is for irrigated agriculture is the continuing problem of one meeting region example. projected increases in electricity demand. Since much of the region's electricity is river, removal areas) will therefore sources. an produced at hydroelectric dams along of (or result water to develop East High in a increase loss of hydroelectricity in the need for power (Whittlesey et'al, from the other and other 1981). The Oregon legislature has recognized writing, that such conflicts exist. As of there is an effort underway to establish this minimum streamflows subject to competing uses as mandated by Senate Bill SB-225. establishes There is also a recently enacted bill a multiagency water planning group that among other things, water management plans, will, create basin and possible state including processes to that wide identify present and emerging water use conflicts (SB-523). Clearly, there are social tradeoffs between irrigation and hydroelectric generation. Water used in irrigation will usually result in hydroelectricity portion reduced will hydroelectricity. lead to higher prices, Lost since of the lost power will be replaced by more some costly thermal generating sources (Whittlesey and Gibbs, 1977). The question is then: "How is the welfare of society best served?" To answer that it is necessary to compare the costs and benefits irrigation. investment 1979). costs would society come from from due to Benefits The first the change would in increased the and from the higher prices paid by consumers methods. The accruing to irrigation electricity electricity come from two sources would be the increased supply production (Martin, of food grown on the now irrigated acreage. The second would be the change arise in to income from the land. those whose incomes are Costs and benefits affected by also increased irrigated production. This study will focus on the the cost in terms of the electricity consumers. Whittlesey and Whittlesey et Gibbs al (1977) , (1981), conditions of electricity prices. will This has been done Obermiller inelastic That is, assume of its price. electricity and problem demand under response they assume that continue to purchase the same amount regardless (1980) , all look at the perfectly before. of It would be more to consumers electricity realistic consumers would respond to to increasing prices by purchasing less electricity. Virtually additional Critical system all water withdrawals are at critical flow flow levels are those water levels in that are equivalent February 1932, above the river to the period August 1928 to the lowest flows on record. However, levels in the future. range of levels. critical flow are the norm and are to be most expected full studies which evaluate any effects This study will often incorporate of observed flows to better gauge the the actual be quite Over the thirty year period results of a given change. Streamflow variation across substantial (see Figure 1-1). from 1929 to 1958, averaged 177,421 time can the yearly discharge at Bonneville Dam cubic foot seconds. However, the distribution was fairly wide - the coefficient of variation was 19% (PNRBC, consumers, 1970) . The implications for and therefore society's welfare, electricity can be quite significant. Figure 1-2 shows the fluctuation in hydropower resulting from the BPA simulation model used as a source of ANNUAL STREAMFLOW - BONNE VILLE DAM (1000 CFS) 280 230 180- 130- Y.EAR FIGURE I-l. Annual streamflow — Bonneville Dam. HYDRO SYSTEM GENERATION (1000 ave. MW/year) 01 o ^t a> o in O) YEAR FIGURE 1-2. Hydro system generation, o ID o» 00 <D <n data within this study. The variation in streamflow (i.e. - amount of water in the river welfare. system) This electricity run the is is important in estimating because the average cost of varies with the amount of water hydroelectric turbines. increases, electricity expensive thermal hydroelectric generation, producing available As the amount producers generation societal can to switch the of lowering consumer water from less to more expensive prices. Thus the variation in water flows will be incorporated into this research. The generation levels computed probabilities due to of selected underlying hydropower streamflows were using BPA simulation data to gain a sense of the likelihood of seeing given streamflows (see Table 1-1). If the water levels drop low enough, the demand for electricity might exceed the available generating capacity. New thermal constructed, generating pushing plants would then need up the price of electricity to in be all years as the construction is amortized. The current cost of producing hydroelectricity is about one tenth of the cost of producing it with new thermal plants (NPPC, 1983). Under current law (BPA, 1980), consumptive uses of the river system, such as irrigation, have instream uses such as electricity generation. that of in periods of low streamflow, priority over This implies when the imputed value the water is higher to electricity consumers, farmers TABLE 1-1: STREAMFLOW PROBABILITIES Hydro Level(ave. MW) Probability (%) 11960 12960 13960 14960 15960 16960 17960 18960 5 14 29 50 70 85 94 98 (1) (2) (1) These are the annual hydropower generation of the present system for particular underlying streamflows. (Without withdrawals.) (2) These are the computed probability of seeing an underlying streamflow that is less than or sufficient to produce the indicated level of hydropower. 8 are implicitly being subsidized by electricity Therefore of consumers. consumers should be willing to pay some that subsidy available to farmers in order to for electricity production, eliminated the need have portion the water particularly if for construction of new it generating plants. Farmers, of course, would want that compensation to at least equal the benefits they would expect from irrigation. Such a payment would meet the criterion for the Kaldor - Hicks compensation test, policy which states: "...that a should be accepted if those who gain by the could policy fully compensate for the welfare losses of those who lose by the policy" The purpose (Freeman, 1979 p55). of this research is to gain greater insight into selected tradeoffs involved in allocating river water to competing uses. between Specifically, the tradeoffs hydroelectric generation and increased development will be PNW examined in terms of irrigation the costs to cost to electricity consumers. This will be done by estimating the social electricity consumers of new irrigation under streamflows and demand conditions. will also be examined. alternative Interruptible policies The social cost under the current noninterruptible policy will be compared to the social cost under an interruptible policy where limitations are placed on how much water farmers can take under low streamflows. The procedures to be used in meeting the objectives of this research are: 1. To construct an estimate of the loss of hydroelectricity associated with various proposed irrigation developments. 2. To construct an estimate of the new average price of electricity facing consumers, given the new irrigation development. This would be under both the current noninterruptible policy, as well as a potential interruptible policy and varying farm payments for pumping energy. 3. To construct an estimate of the new market clearing quantity of electricity in the region, given the irrigation development (under both policies and varying farm payments for pumping energy). 4. Estimate (2) and (3) under varying demand conditions. 5. Estimate (1) through (4) under varying streamflows. 6. Estimate the expected value of the change in consumers' surplus under the two policies. 7. Compare the change in consumers' surplus estimated in (6). 10 II. BACKGROUND AND THEORY Physical Relationships Underlying physical any economic relationship is relationships. In a the set of case of irrigation/hydropower tradeoffs, the physical relationships involve the amount of water diverted from instream use electricity generation, to use in developing in irrigated acreage. There are irrigation these a number of factors encouraging development in the Pacific further Northwest. One of is the Congressional mandate specifying "...that in those areas lying ... west of the 98th meridian, [instream] uses must not conflict with any beneficial consumptive use, present or future. consumptive uses irrigation." (BPA, Certainly from the one of Columbia the most River common System is 1980 p. 1-13) Such a regulation reduces the risk of those who wish to develop irrigated cropland. Economic well. The farmers' be costs. to develop irrigation include costs, pumping energy only as the costs, and The water itself is not paid for (King 1978). This means that any welfare loss incurred by electricity not costs capital application et al, incentives exist for farmers to irrigate consumers as a result of the diversions fully irrigating. reflected in the Certainly, costs farmers would incur in the strongest incentive to farmers 11 is the expected increase in profits that they would receive from irrigated over dryland farming (Whittlesey and Gibbs, 1977; Obermiller 1978,1980; Whittlesey 1981) . Although a farmer may or may not be aware of the other considerations, he must surely be aware of the results of his decisions on his profits. The magnitude of new development is potentially quite sizable. Over 2.2 million acres of current dryland in Pacific Northwest have irrigation (King et al, estimated that approximately been identified as 1978). 5.3 million suitable If fully developed, this would result in a acre-feet net of the for it is depletion water of annually (Whittlesey et al, 1981). The physical sequence of interactions resulting increased withdrawals straightforward. of the irrigation return flow, volume of is As withdrawals increase, (level of water in the river), of water most from conceptually the streamflow is decreased. Although some water comes back into of it is does not. water available for other the This uses. rivers reduces time since there are storage pools with most of the dams along the rivers. act as storehouses of potential cannot be stored directly, the Hydroelectric generation is not dependent upon natural streamflow at particular as any associated These pools partly electricity. but having the pools Electricity available allows electricity generation to coincide with demand. Lost water means that the turbine blades can be turned for a 12 shorter time, or in some cases, not at all. This of course, means a reduction in the total amount of electricity that can be generated. If for there were a substantial number of sites available construction of additional large projected such generate more electricity. is dams and reusing the The available water This was done for many no longer possible due to the sites. dams, shortfalls in electricity supply could be met by building but hydroelectric lack of to years, available shortfall must then be met by other sources of electricity generation. In practice this means some kind of thermal electricity generation. The range of choices includes: oil fired steam or turbine, coal fired steam, gas fired turbine, and nuclear fired steam. Engineering considerations would cause some combination of these kinds of plants to be chosen. Economic Relationships The factors influencing the demand for electricity the region are well identified, in although estimating their aggregate be difficult. As a consequence, previous analysts (Whittlesey and Whittlesey, 1981) electricity lost, Gibbs, have 1977; Obermiller, 1978, looked only at the value that is, 1980; of the at the opportunity cost of the withdrawn water. Opportunity cost is defined here to be the cost of producing substituting electricity the next for the lowest foregone cost method of hydroelectricity 13 generation. This is equivalent to looking at a perfectly- inelastic demand function. A price inelastic demand function is defined to be one for which the change in quantity demanded is less than one percent for each one percent change in the good's price. In the case of perfect inelasticity, the change in quantity is zero, regardless of the magnitude of the price change. This says that the amount of the good demanded is independent of its price. In contrast, inelastic a demand function that is not perfectly is one for which there is a change demanded with a change in the good's price. in quantity A graph of a demand function that is not perfectly inelastic will show a negative slope, while a graph of a perfectly inelastic demand function will show a vertical line (see Fig. Thus, show a a good that is not perfectly price inelastic decrease increases. II-l). in the quantity demanded as its will price This is what we observe with most market goods, including electricity. Given that lost hydroelectricity generation will, to some extent, be replaced by thermal generation, it is clear that overall costs of electricity generation will increase. This is because generating an new thermal generation costs more equivalent amount of electricity than with the between the current hydroelectric system. To price properly estimate the relationship of electricity and the amount utilities will supply. 14 PRICI DEMAND fl CHANCE IN CONUMERS' SURPLUS «2 QUAKIITil PRICI DEMAND #1 #2 \ V CHANGE INJ CONUMERS SURPLUS QUANTITV FIGURE II-l. Use changes in consumers' surplus. 15 we must specify an average cost function. free Most goods in a market economy can be modelled with a supply function derived from a marginal cost function. market is highly regulated however. The electricity The regulations allow to meet their costs without gaining any "excess1 utilities profits (i.e. - rents). The investor owned utilities allowed to add a modest profit to their costs 1979). Rates are then set at the (Mansfield, average cost production, including this uses an average cost function in lieu study the allowed 'profits. are of Consequently of the supply function usually used in comparative statics. Because of the large number of electricity producing facilities and the complex interutility sales that occur, is the it extremely difficult to relate production process to the final sale. are In often actual addition, there highly complex technological relationships that often change. In order to do the analysis it is therefore necessary to make some simplifying assumptions. The first is that all hydroelectric demand resources will be used to satisfy consumer before more expensive thermal and import resources. Although it is not to be strictly true, it reasonably assumed that decision makers will use relatively low cost hydropower in their power can as be much generating mix as possible (BPA, 1983a) . The second assumption relates to the cost factors used in the economic analysis. Due to the difficulty in 16 obtaining plants detailed in the cost data on all region, it relevant is not possible reasonably accurate estimate of the unit and associated with plant. each plant, Therefore, estimate (NPPC, for the generating to fixed nor even with each Northwest make the cost of producing costs type Power Planning hydropower a of Council was used 1983), and aggregate BPA data were used to estimate the cost of providing electricity from nonhydro sources and for estimating system fixed costs. (For details on sources and derivation of all input data for the economic analysis see the Appendix.) production, except administrative The result for is ancillary expenses that all fixed costs and transmission not likely costs of such as costs, are introduce much considered variable. This assumption distortion 'close' into to introduce the bias is the results when initial starting into to estimating conditions conditions, those analyses that but look extreme conditions of water level and diversions. be seen by function cost looking in the electricity market. components numerator. Three.) (The Any generating increase costs at the nature as model increase sources the multiplicative an in the associated more This can average arguments relative with at cost It has the individual is presented formally overall average price. are overstated, of could in in Chapter amounts these the of costs the will Since the variable the greater the change in resource 17 mix due to estimated more extreme changes in conditions, the price and quantity greater than the would be addressing is expected with 'real' resource costs. One of whether the there generating questions this study will capacity withdrawals. This generating be a need for as a result of implies capacity will is a long more electricity increased run require irrigation context, that as new new thermal generating plants be constructed. To under determine conditions recognize the the equilibrium prices of varying demand it and is quantities necessary that the amount of electricity purchased to equals amount of electricity sold and that the price paid by consumers is the price received by utilities. As water production withdrawals from nonhydropower, cause a shift lower cost hydropower to as electricity more expensive the average cost will be greater to produce a given amount of electricity (see Fig. cost in II-2). The average will be affected by natural variations in well as by any water withdrawals. streamflow Figure I1-2 is drawn assuming a given streamflow in order to isolate the effect of withdrawals. Given that both the demand and average cost functions have two variables for which values need to be price and unknowns quantity, can determined, the system of two equations be solved simultaneously. This is in two done by first solving the two functions separately for price. This 18 e. Nith MithdPAyah \ Without ^C^V Uithdrawals ""-\: \ Quantity AVERAGE PRICE FIGURE II-2. Price change due to withdrawals, 19 results in: supply price, demand price, P = f[quantity supplied] P, = f[quantity demanded]. and Since the supply price equals the demand price in equilibrium: P = P-,. This then f[quantity implies that f[quantity supplied] = demanded]. Further details and derivations will be found in Chapter Three. One measure consumers will of how much the welfare change under of increased electricity irrigation provided by the change in consumers' surplus. a direct measure of the change in utility, measured in any case, Although not which cannot be the change in consumers' surplus is nonetheless a widely accepted measure associated with change utility in experience is that electricity with increased irrigation the consumers would withdrawals. (Just, Hueth, and Schmitz, 1982). Consumer's between what the is defined to be the area difference what is In a geometric analysis this is represented area above the price line and to the left demand function (see Fig. areas the the consumer is willing to pay and actually paid. by surplus II-l). of In the aggregate, the these for individuals are summed. Therefore, in looking at market demand function, above function. the same measure the price line and to the left of It should be noted that this holds: the the demand assumes that individual consumers are not associated with specific units of the good purchased. then the The change in consumers' surplus is difference between the area measured before the 20 price change and the area after. When looking at the change in consumers' electricity consumers, surplus to it is important that new irrigators not be included in with them. To do so would understate the change in the electricity market. However, the electricity that farmers pay for should be included when estimating the new average price if farmers are charged the market clearing price along with other consumers. Farmers pumping upon In may in fact pay for differing amounts of energy used. How much they pay for would depend the particular arrangements in the development some cases, they would pay for all of the area. pumping energy. In others, others, they might only pay for the energy required to get the water This is they might not pay for any. the from the 'farm gate' to the common crops In still themselves. in land developed with support from the Bureau of Land Management. Once is made, an estimate of the change in consumers' surplus it would then be necessary to compare the loss to consumers with irrigation the gain to irrigators to see if withdrawals are beneficial to the society new as a whole. The this. Kaldor/Hicks Simply put, compensation test can be this test asks if the irrigation are able to compensate the losers, electricity compensation, consumers. It does only the potential for not used gainers for from in this case require compensation. actual Thus, 21 the gainers must get more from irrigation than those lose because of the irrigation. If this were not the case, there would be a net loss to society as a whole. be noted that' the Kaldor/Hicks test and the consumers' surplus can only measure pecuniary society's welfare. Kaldor/Hicks This who paper does not It should change in changes in make the test since the agricultural benefits are estimated. (Readers interested in the background of the Kaldor/Hicks test are referred to not assumptions and Just, Hueth, and Schmitz, 1982, or Freeman, 1979.) Ihterruptible Water Policy If excess electrical generating capacity does not exist, the increases in irrigation withdrawals might construction of new generating facilities. This would happen when water flows were sufficiently low for enough period that hydroelectric and thermal require a long generating capacity would not be enough to meet projected demand. This involves the concept of critical flows mentioned in the previous chapter. Thus as electricity demand and irrigation withdrawals increase, the limits of electrical generating capacity may be reached. As withdrawals lower the effective streamflow, critical flow levels may be approached. If in fact they are reached, new thermal plants will be needed to supply the projected shortfall. If, however, the shortfall could be eliminated or 22 reduced by denying irrigation withdrawals, the new capacity would not be necessary. electricity market. arrangements with Such a precedent exists in the PNW Some utilities certain have customers contractual that allow the utilities to reduce the amount of electricity sold to those customers when possible shortfalls exist. contracting In return, the customers are charged less for that portion of their power they purchase as "interruptible." This suggests an analogy to the peak load pricing model in the electricity market where "...peak users should pay marginal operating costs plus marginal capacity and off-peak users should pay only marginal costs operating costs." (Joskow, 1976 p. 198) This leads to the second policy to be examined. This is an interruptible policy where irrigation withdrawals are limited to electricity. levels In hydroelectricity that this will model, not cause power used shortfalls for of replacing lost due to irrigation is not charged at the average cost, but at the marginal operating costs of an average PNW coal plant. This will have the reducing the losses to electricity consumers. effect of 23 III. METHODOLOGY Electricity Loss There are development in his research. Umatilla II, III-l). possible in the PNW. independently: would many sites for Whittlesey identified High, Horse Haven were chosen on the basis of from the mouth of the river, (TDH). the possible Hills of those I (HHH), and Grande Ronde (see Table III-l and Figure impact hydroelectric generation: head forty-four This study will look at four East These distance irrigation factors size of the and total The larger the development area, acreage to be put under that area, dynamic the greater irrigation and therefore the greater amount of water required. The further upstream the withdrawals occur, flows through, the fewer dams the resulting in a greater loss of water electricity generation. TDH is the total pump lift required to take the water from height the river to the cropland. It depends on and distance the water is pumped, operating as well pressure of the irrigation system. The the as the greater the TDH, .the greater the loss of generated electricity used in pumping. The volume of constant over time. control short primarily This flow water flowing in the river not Although storage pools can be used run fluctuations, the yearly has an impact on the to streamflows depend upon the precipitation during that variation is year. amount of TABLE III-l: firea State(s) CHARACTERISTICS OF DEVELOPMENT AREAS Acres Pump Lift (ft) Diversions (1) Return Flowsd) 794,392 31,817 196,350 John Day, McNary John day 25.8 109,300 10,933 98,367 John day John Day 13.5 74,068 7,410 66,658 Lower Granite Lower Granite 13. 1,643,602 487,335 1,156,267 310,000 690 1,242,067 447,175 norse Haven Hills Washington 70,000 865 218,167 Uniatiila II Oregon 40,000 900 Grande fonde Oregon 38,000 380 458,000 1. Acre - feet oer year 2. Average oegawatts per year. This figure is the amount of electricity reouired to PUED the indicated diversion. SOURCE: Mhittlesey et al., 1981 Pumping loss(d) HcNary<50<) Priest RaDids(50X) Washington Washington, Oregon Point of Return Grand Coulee East High Combined Areas Net Point of Depletiond) Diversion 143.0 25 LEGEND: 1 2 3 4 - EAST HIGH HORSE HAVEN HILLS UMATILLA GRANDE RONDE FIGURE III-l : DEVELOPMENT AREAS (After Whittlesey et al, 1981) 26 electricity generated at the dams. streamflow, the This study will use the yearly flows, uses, over the The less electricity that can period 1929-1968 for lower be the generated. adjusted for sample data 1983 (BPA, 1983c) . To determine the loss for each of the study areas, is necessary to identify those dams that would reduced the of 1981) . A portion percolates area. The water withdrawn for irrigation is not equal amount lost for hydroelectric generation into experience water because of withdrawals from that amount of the water applied it to (Whittlesey, to the crops into the water table and ultimately comes the river system as return flows (Table back III-l). The return flow may or may not enter the river at the pool from which the it was drawn. area subtract dams in This will depend upon the geology which it is applied. is necessary the return flows coming in above the from the withdrawal figures. depletion It affecting the of to appropriate This will yield the net appropriate dams (Whittlesey, 1981) . Withdrawals nor even require are not made evenly throughout the throughout the growing season. varying amounts of water at different their life cycle (Soil Cons. total Ser., crops points water on a monthly basis gives the a given month. in 1970). Multiplying the net depletion for a given year by the proportion applied for Different year, net of depletion Since the water year is divided into 27 fourteen months (there are two April and two August periods of fifteen days each), application the SCS data for monthly irrigation percentages were modified. For those months that are divided, the percentages were also divided. Having determined the net depletions associated with the given area, at each dam the generation loss can be computed. Each dam is operated according to a 'rule curve1. This rule curve is designed to operate both the dam and the river system account which as efficiently as possible. It takes both the available water and the various it will be put. This study will not into uses to attempt to investigate changes in rule curves, but only the changes in electricity generation associated with incremental changes in water availability caused by irrigation. Thus, the rule curve is assumed to be given and constant. This will result in each dam in the simulations being operated in the same way regardless of the amount irrigation withdrawals. The generating loss is computed by multiplying the net depletion at a dam by its is a figure generation water gained and the yields over K' factor (H/K). the or lost for an availability. month, from that 'H amount Columbia Rivers. electricity incremental change Each H/K is specific to a given streamflow in the study. BPA of The H/K H/K's were for nineteen major dams on the in dam, obtained Snake and There are 560 H/K's for each dam, ordered by month (14) and year (40). The data for withdrawals and return flows were taken 28 from Whittlesey et al (1981). They were converted from acre-feet to cubic foot-seconds in order to give the proper units when used in the model. To determine the total generating loss associated with a given development area and a given yearly streamflow, the losses from those dams streamflow are summed. loss is associated with that area The expected size of the generating useful in estimating the pecuniary value diverted water. and of the It is defined to be the average generating loss taken over the forty year study period. The generating loss model for a given area is: a) GENLOS y = IT. [ (HK ) • (MOPROP )•[ (D )■ (DIVER )] md myd m Id d .-[ (D ) • (RETURN ) ] ] 2d d where: GENLOS = generating loss at the streamflow y associated with water year y [ave. MW/year] HK (y = 1929...1968) = H/K for dam d and streamflow y in myd month m [KW/cubic foot-second] (d = 1. . .19, y = 1929...1968, m = 1...14) MOPROP = the proportion of the yearly withdrawal m in month m (m = 1...14) DIVER = amount of withdrawal from dam d d (d = 1. . .19) RETURN [cfs] = return flow through dam d (d = 1...19) d [cfs] 29 D-]^ = 1 if dam d is downstream from point of withdrawal, 0 otherwise 09^ = 1 if dam d is downstream from point of return, 0 otherwise b) AVLOS = (1/40)•( GENLOSy) where: AVLOS = average generating loss for the given area over the 40 year study period GENLOSy = as defined above Economic Analysis: Inelastic Demand In order to estimate the societal cost of the lost hydropower, it is necessary to compute the change in price. An average pricing scheme was used for reasons explained in the previous chapter. In the case of completely inelastic demand it is not necessary to compute a new quantity, since under the assumption of inelasticity, the will be demanded regardless of its price. lost gas same quantity In the PNW, hydropower will be replaced with some combination or oil fired turbine, coal fired steam, or the of nuclear powered steam. The levelized cost of this new generation is estimated to (NPPC, 1983) . be approximately 40 mills/KwH, on average 30 Noninterruptible Model The average pricing model for the noninterruptible policy is: PI = (FC + CH-(H - AVLOS) + CN-(NI + AVLOS))/(QF + d-PUMP) where: PI = new average price of electricity [mills/Kwh] FC = system fixed costs CH = average levelized cost of hydropower [mills/Kwh] H = net amount of hydropower given streamflow without withdrawals [Kwhs] AVLOS = average generating loss over the study period [Kwhs] 40 year (see Generating Loss, above) CN = average levelized cost of nonhydro resources [mills/Kwh] NI = net amount of nonhydropower (= QF + PUMP - H) [Kwh] QF = forecast electricity demand [Kwh] d = the proportion of pumping energy paid for by farmers PUMP = the pumping energy used by farmers in getting water from the river to the cropland [Kwh] (Whittlesey et al, 1981) (For derivaion and sources of input data, see the Appendix.) 31 This formula is a weighted average of the fixed costs, the value of nonhydropower practice, some also used to there This meet the and the value region's of the needs. (In is sufficient hydropower holds to meet all for the remaining models as well.) takes into account the amount of pumping energy farmers model at hydropower, the model is slightly more complicated, since in cases needs. the actually pay for. It should be noted the market clearing price is included in that that assumes that pumping energy not paid for by It this farmers the average price paid by all consumers, including farmers. Interruptible Model The interruptible different approach, average of simulation requires a somewhat although the model is still a weighted different costs. In this model, the maximum amount of generation is fixed at the total hydrogeneration available the nonhydro at the given streamflow plus amount power necessary to meet the region's needs of under critical conditions. First, the simulation tests to determine if the farmers can take any withdrawals. forecast that demand would This is done by subtracting for electricity plus the generating arise from withdrawals from the generation at the given streamflow. total the loss system If the system can meet all needs for power and irrigation, the farmers are allowed to take the water. The amount that they are allowed depends 32 upon the capacity of the system at the given streamflow. The simulation then computes the amount of nonhydropower resources that will be required. This is done by subtracting the amount of hydropower plus the generating loss from the forecast electricity demand. The interruptible model has an additional category power. This power. It is is what will be referred to the power that the as of replacement electrical generating system must produce in order to replace the hydropower lost to irrigation. take water streamflow In those years that farmers are allowed it is equal to the generating situations needs from hydropower. it loss. may be possible to If this is the case, In supply high all there will be no need for either replacement power or nonhydropower. The average price is then found by: PI = (FC + CH-(H - AVLOS) + CN-NI + CR-R)/(QF + d-PUMP) where: CR = cost of replacement power [mills/Kwh] (see Appendix) R = QF + PUMP - (H -AVLOS) - NI = the amount of replacement power [Kwh] All other variables are as defined in the previous model. to 33 Economic Analysis: Elastic Demand It the would be more realistic if the simulation quantity average of electricity demanded to decrease price increases. as the This is what we would expect happen in the electricity market itself. necessary allowed to To do this, it is to examine the relationship between the supply and demand sides of the market under assumptions of elastic demand. Supply Conditions The electricity currently sold in the region comes from several sources: publicly owned hydropower and thermal plants, privately owned hydropower and thermal plants, with minor supplies from long term import contracts and wind generated power. As in the previous analyses, a weighted average of the different is costs incurred in generating the region's used to estimate the new supply price for power electricity. Under the elastic assumption the quantity to be supplied is no longer fixed, term to simulate so the model must incorporate a variable the consumers' accomodation to price changes. The model is: PE = (FC + CH-(H - AVLOS) + CN- (QF - H - AVLOS) ) / (QE - ((1 - dpPUMP))) where: 34 PE = average cost with given streamflow and withdrawal [mills/Kwh] FC = fixed system costs CH = average cost of hydropower [mills/Kwh] H = net available hydropower given streamflow, without withdrawals [Kwh] AVLOS = average generating loss due to withdrawals [Kwh] (see Generating Loss) CN = average cost of nonhydro resources [mills/Kwh] QE = market clearing quantity of electricity [Kwh] QF = QE + PUMP [Kwh] d = proportion of pumping energy farmers pay for PUMP = amount of pumping energy farmers use in getting irrigation water to the cropland [Kwh] Demand Conditions Although for there is no widely accepted demand electricity in the PNW, a number of function estimates are available. Given the wide range of range of functional forms for electricity demand in the literature (EPRI, equally wide elasticity, variation it was in decided estimates to use 1982), and the of three own levels price of 35 elasticity in the study: Elasticity Reference(s) -0.1 Charles River Assoc. -0'. 54 Dept. of Energy -1.0 Elec. Power Res. Inst., Bonneville Power Adm. An unknown simple linear demand function can be approximated by demand function of the form Q = a - b a P (where Q = quantity demanded, P = price of electricity, and a,b are constants). regardless general, short This is a reasonable approximation of the form of the "true1 demand any function. functional form can be approximated range by a linear function. over In a It should be noted that the elasticity of a linear demand function does not remain constant throughout its range. The was slope found by of the demand function in each rearranging the formula for simulation own price elasticity and solving for the slope value: E = -(dQ/dP)•(P/Q) = b-(P/Q) => b = (E-Q)/P where: E = own price elasticity of demand dQ = change in quantity demanded from Q dP = change in unit price from P P = original unit price at average streamflow, before withdrawals Q = original quantity demanded at average streamflow, before withdrawals 36 b = slope of the demand function The demand function can be rearranged to function. obtain This inverse function is an inverse demand then equated to the average price function to solve for the new market equilibrium. The inverse demand function is: P = (Q - a)/(-b) = [(H + NE) - a]/(-b) = [a - (H + NE)]/b Market Equilibrium The inverse equals average demand the identically equation price function can be function since price consumers supply pay and equated price the equals the quantity purchased. then has only one unknown to identically quantity The variable, the sold resulting the market clearing quantity of electricity. P = P supply demand rearranging this equation yields: QE2 + QE-[b-CN - a - PUMP - (1 - d)-PUMP] + [b-FC + b-CH- (H - AVLOS) - b-CN- (H AVLOS) + a-PUMP - d-a-PUMP + (1 - d)-PUMP2] = 0 where: QE = market clearing quantity of electricity [Kwh] H = quantity of available hydropower given streamflow, without withdrawals [Kwh] 37 a = intercept term of the demand function PUMP = amount of pumping energy used by farmers in getting irrigation withdrawals to the cropland [Kwh] (Whittlesey et al, 1981) d = proportion of pumping energy paid for by farmers b = slope of the demand function CH = average cost of hydro resources [mills/Kwh] AVLOS = average generating loss [Kwh] (see Generat- ing Loss) CN = average cost of nonhydropower [mills/Kwh] FC = system fixed costs The simulation then finds the solution to this equation by applying the quadratic formula: QE = [-NB + (NB2 - 4-NC)1//2]/2 where: QE = market clearing quantity of electricity [Kwh] NB = b-CN - a - PUMP - (1 - d)-PUMP NC = b-FC + b-CH- (H - AVLOS) - b-CN- (H - AVLOS) + a-PUMP - d-a-PUMP + (1 - d)-PUMP2 It then remains to compute the new equilibrium This price. is done by using the average price function for which all values are now known. Change in Consumers' Surplus The change in consumers' surplus is estimated using 38 the Hicks procedure (Brokken et al, computing the 1981). This is done by the area bounded by the old average price new average price line, the ordinate, line, and the demand curve. In the case of a completely inelastic demand the function change in consumers' surplus would be represented by a rectangle. Mathematically: CS = dP-QO = (PO - Pnew>-Q0 where: CS = change in consumers' surplus Pnew = new average price given streamflow withdrawals PO = old average price without withdrawals QO = amount of electricity marketed Under the assumption of less than perfectly demand, the perfectly boundaries estimation is inelastic case. as before, but similar to that inelastic under The area computed has the the demand curve now negative slope. The formula is: CS = dP •[(QO + QE)/2] where: CS = change in consumers' surplus dP = change in average price (= PO - PE) QO = original guantity of electricity marketed, without withdrawals QE = quantity marketed at new equilibrium PO = average price without withdrawals the same has a 39 PE = average price given withdrawals 40 IV. RESULTS AND CONCLUSIONS Energy Losses It should be noted that the distribution of energy losses show a very narrow dispersion (Table IV-1). not surprising dam system - flood control, needs. This This is in light of the major purposes behind will and water storage for the later tend to smooth out the distribution of water through time, even over a period of years. This would result i.e. in a lessened effect from a change in - an irrigation storage facilities. 'years' in withdrawal, It water flow, than if there were should be kept in mind this study are water years and no that the therefore run from October to September. The area with the greatest loss, was East High at 114.4 ave. expected on a yearly MW/year. basis, This is as would be since East High is the largest area in the study, with the largest withdrawals, and is the farthest upriver. This total is about consumption of .6% of the the region. forecast The area with yearly loss was Umatilla II at 2.1 ave. not with the smallest MW/year. Although the area with the smallest withdrawals, the second smallest withdrawals. electricity it is the one Grande Ronde has a net depletion approximately 68% of that in Umatilla, but is further upstream Because it is and shows a loss of further upstream, 4.3 the ave. water MW/year. lost to > I MMMMHJMMHJhJMMMhJMh^MMMHJhJMHJMMMH'Mt-'l-'l--'l--'H'l--'l--'l--'l--'H,|--'l--'l--' I I I I I | 1 1 1 i 1 ^« UIOJ CO • ^JH' O • LTlCTi h-1 vo ro ai ai M • tri I I *^ O • 4^^(^03U^^^UJUJOLnu^M^a^u>^4^u^^£>ooo^v£lvDC^lV04iCX)cr^wco^M^M^a^^^a^U) MI-'h-'h-'l-'l-'h-'i-'H'h-'l-'l-' l-» I-1 M (-' I-" K-* M l-'l-'l-'l-'l-'l-'l-'l-'l-'K'l-'l-'l-'l-'t-'l-'l-'l-'l-' UJO(^MMU>tOMMrOMM^H'MMMOK'NJCONJMUJUJMWl^U>CaNJOJMU>M[SJU)*.^=-UJ U)^OTMU5^UlLO^^U)hJl^aiU1Cr\<»COMOCQOVD^^^^^(X>a\^MDVr)Ln^MOOOOO VDU3O^OOOUl^C^(^hJC^CriCnM00V0^0JUJr0OOLnO|--'Ot--'00l--'C0O0,l0Ja3l--'l--'O (^0:U>H'C0C^L0MMMOUD4iMMM^^00OU1OOU)U)MUJ4^W0JNJ4^U)U)NJOM4^*-U) UlCT\C0^C^U1LnM^MOC00JUlMOC»00^MMU)Ji.LnOO0000--J~JNJ004^VDCriO-~J00~0O ^4^Mcr^M<DCi^u^oo^J^l^^U)c^lL^^XlVDvoL^lOOOU)MUJ^J^^u^a^Mcrl^o^L^o^^-'U^o^.o l-'l-'ll-'l-'l-'l-'l-'H'l-'MI-'l-'t-'l-' I-4 (-* h-* (-' h-'l-' H'l-'l-'l-'MI-'l-'h-'l-'l-'t-'l-'l-'l-'h-'l-'l-'t-'l-' MH' t hJOr0MMNJMOhJMhJOCX3OOMOVDOM00MONJMI--'MrvJNJK)l--'ro(-'NJI--'l--'l-'tOMNJ Cri4^ I MOU>MOU1U)^C^LOU)NJUn^^aiC»OOMOOOU3^ljn^U1^a^^C»-~J--JUJMNJOOCDOOcri I n 1 1 i i I 1 > H C5 t-a > tr1 l-H > t"1 M M H t-H M 1 s 1 s 1 E 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 c s » 50 C) > 25 2 O a w w 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 K M M > O en K t-3 1 1 1 1 I K I w i > I Jd (D 0) \ a S ro < (u ^—^ o m en tr1 a o H 5H3 W W •• 1 h-' < H w bs ^ > ^. I--1 42 irrigation causes Horse is denied to more dams along the a greater loss of electricity generation in Haven Hills I of Grande Ronde', has river. a This total. (HHH) shows a loss very close to at 4.6 ave. that MW/year. This is because HHH net depletion much larger than either Umatilla Grande Ronde but is about the same distance from the or mouth of the river as Umatilla. On a per acre-foot basis, the losses show an identical pattern. East High has a loss of about 1261 KwH per acre- foot, while Umatilla has a loss of about 187 KwH per acre- foot. HHH and Grande Ronde have losses of 205 and 565 KwH per acre-foot respectively. These height results above Grand 1167 feet. be compared to sea level of each of the water is taken. behind could would Obviously, pools cumulative from which East High uses water from the highest pool Coulee Dam which has a cumulative height of Grande Ronde would take its water from the pool behind Lower Granite Dam at 710 feet. both the take the Umatilla II and water from John Day pool greater at 242 the cumulative height of the from which the water is taken, the greater the HHH feet. dam generating loss. In addition to the loss of potential hydropower due to withdrawals, from the region also loses generated electricity the pumping required to move the water from the river to the cropland (see Table III-l). In the case of East High this is 98.8 ave. MW/year., about 1/2 of one percent of the 43 forecast demand of 18672 ave. MW/year for the region as a whole. Economic Results General Results The results consistent of the economic with economic theory. simulations were This was assured by the nature of the models. As the amount of available nydropower diminished and was nonhydropower, quantity the wholly or partially replaced with equilibrium price increased while decreased (except for the inelastic the demand scenarios). Changes in consumers' surplus showed the expected decrease with streamflows below the average streamflow, and the expected increase with streamflows above the average. This is due to the resource mix shifting from nydropower to nonhydropower reduced. as This reduction, the amount of water in the either irrigation withdrawals expected value of changes in consumers' less than is will happen regardless of the source of the or streamflow variation caused by precipitation. the river the change in consumers' natural In addition, surplus surplus at were low streanflows. At all streamflows, the effects due to irrigation withdrawals were dwarfed by those due to natural changes in 44 streamflows. However, irrigation caused a loss to strong in This is electricity consumers in all situations. Changes response to in consumers' surplus were quite farmer payments for pumping energy. true for all elasticities and for both policies. The change in consumers' surplus dropped quickly as payments increased from none to 100%. Since East High, as the largest area, has the greatest generating loss among the areas in the study, used to illustrate the magnitude of effects as it will be withdrawals are varied. The patterns exhibited in East High are similar to those in other areas. For details on other areas the reader is referred to the tables below. Noninterruptible Policy The in all results from these simulations will be terms of the weighted average (expected streamflows. The elasticity assumptions: elasticities simulations were discussed value) run under four completely inelastic and the three mentioned previously (-0.1,-0.54,-1.0). of these was also run under three assumed levels of payments for pumping energy: pay across Each farmer none, all, and one where they only for the energy required to apply the water to the crops (assumed to be equal to 100ft. of the total dynamic head). In this last case, the energy used to get water from the river to the farm gate is implicitly assumed to be paid for by all electricity consumers. 45 Relative changes in the quantity of electricity marketed due to withdrawals were not extreme. The greatest effect was observed in the simulations at an elasticity of one. The quantity fell to slightly over 17000 ave. MW/year from the base decrease case of 17411 ave. of about 2.5 percent. MW/year. in the level is a The remaining elasticities showed less of an effect (see Tables IV - 2 Changes This of hydropower constant across all elasticity levels. to IV - 6). produced This is the are result that would be expected, since the amount of hydropower is a function only exception of streamflow and is streamflow. the Here meet demand, case of withdrawal inelastic level. demand and there is more than enough hydropower so demand is the limiting factor rather The high to than water availability. The greatest change in price due to withdrawals occurs under similar conditions: an elasticity of one when farmers don't pay for any pumping energy. The expected value price increases from 31.864 mills/Kwh to 32.232 This of mills/Kwh. a relative change of about 1.4 percent. (see Tables IV - 2 to IV - 6). Changes pattern, elastic in consumers' that is, the Four measures of a different the change were total change to consumers due to effects of natural streamflow variation only, irrigation showed the greatest changes occur in the least simulations. computed: surplus only, the total change due to the change per acre of farmland due to READING TABLES IV-2 TO IV-6 NOTE: all entries are expected values PROPORTION - the proportion of pumping energy paid for by farmers PRICE - market clearing price of electricity, given withdrawals [rnills/Kwh] DEMAND QUANTITY - market clearing quantity of electricity, given withdrawals [ave. MW/year] HYDRO QUANTITY - amount of hydropower produced [ave. MW/year] NON HYDRO - amount of nonhydropower produced [ave. MW/year] CHANGE IN CONSUMERS' SURPLUS DUE TO STREAMFLOW - the change in consumers' surplus caused by natural streamflow variation only [$1000's] DUE TO IRRIGATION - the change in consumers' surplus caused by irrigation withdrawals only [$1000,s] PER ACRE - the change in consumers' surplus caused by irrigation on a per acre basis [$'5] PER ACRE-FT - the change in consumers' surplus caused by irrigation on a per acre-foot basis (i.e.-per acre-ft of net depletion) [$'s] ** TABLE IV-2: NONINTERRUPTIBLE POLICY EAST HIGH DEKftND HYDRO PRICE QUflNTITY QUflNTITY CHAN6E IN CONSUOS' SURPLUS: DUE TO DUE TO PER PER STRMFL. IRRIG. ACRE flCRE-FT NON HYDRO Proportion: 0 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 32.241 32.240 32.245 32.232 18672 18020 17612 17193 14757 14760 14760 14760 3450 3355 2947 2529 -191464 -186519 -178376 -167902 -64441 -65802 -60863 -56475 -207.87 -212.26 -196.33 -182.18 -78.46 -82.78 -76.57 -71.05 32.216 32.215 32.221 32.209 18672 18021 17619 17207 14757 14760 14760 14760 3450 3357 2955 2542 -191464 -186519 -178376 -167902 -60398 -61826 -57166 -53031 -194.83 -199.44 -184.41 -171.07 -73.51 -77.78 -71.92 -66.71 32.071 32.072 32.084 32.076 18672 18029 17663 17286 14757 14760 14760 14760 3450 3365 2399 2621 -191464 -186519 -178376 -167902 -36684 -38523 -35508 -32868 -118.34 -124.29 -114.54 -106.03 -44.4E -48.47 -44.67 -41.35 Proportion: .145 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 Proportion: 1 INELASTIC aASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 ! i ! ! TABLE IV-3: NONINTERRUPTIBLE POLICY UMATILLA II DEMAND HYDRO PRICE QUANTITY QUANTITY NQN HYDRO DUE TO STRMFL. DUE TO IRRI6. PER PER ACRE ACRE-FT -191464 -186519 -178376 -167902 -4937 -5027 -4642 -4300 -123.42 -125.67 -116.05 -107.50 -48.57 -51.10 -47.13 -43.72 Proportion: 0 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 i ! i ! i ! ! ! 31.877 31.867 31.890 31.891 18672 18042 17725 17394 14858 14869 14869 14869 3267 3186 2869 2538 31.874 31.864 31.888 31.889 18672 18042 17726 17396 14858 14869 14869 14869 3267 3186 2870 2540 -191464 -166519 -178376 -167902 -4518 -4617 -4261 -3947 -112.% -115.42 -106.53 -98.67 -44.43 i -46.93 i -43.32 i -40.12 i 31.854 31.844 31.869 31.871 18672 18043 17732 17407 14858 14869 14869 14869 3267 3187 2876 2551 -191464 -186519 -176376 -167902 -1170 -1334 -1216 -119 -29.24 -33.35 -30.40 -27.99 -11.23 -13.56 -12.36 -11.38 Proportion: .111 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 Proportion: 1 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 ! i ; ! 00 TABLE IV-4: NONINTERRUPTIBLE POLICY HHH I DEMAND HYDRO PRICE QUflNTITY QUflNTITY NDN HYDRO CHANGE IN CONSUICRS' SURPLUS: DUE TO DUE TO PER PER STRMFL. IRRIG. ACRE flCRE-FT Proportion: 0 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 31.905 31.8% 31.918 31.918 18672 18040 17716 17379 14856 14867 14867 14867 3290 3198 2827 2537 -191464 -186519 -178376 -167901 -9576 -9756 -9006 -8344 -136.80 -139.37 -128.65 -119.20 -47.20 -49.69 -45.87 -4249.00 31.900 31.981 31.913 31.913 18672 18040 17718 17382 14856 14857 14867 14867 3280 3198 2876 2540 -191464 -185519 -178376 -167901 -8739 -8935 -8245 -7637 -124.85 -127.65 -117.78 -109.10 -43.05 -45.51 -41.99 -36.90 31.861 31.852 31.876 31.878 18672 18042 17729 17402 14356 14367 14867 14867 3280 3201 2887 2561 -191464 -185519 -178376 -167901 -2375 -2692 -2455 -2260 -33.92 -38.46 -35.08 -32.29 -11.49 -13.71 -12.51 -11.51 Proportion: .116 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 Proportion: 1 INELASTIC ELASTICITY -0.1 ELASTICITY -0.54 ELASTICITY -1.0 ! ! ; ! >H u J H PQ ^ o a< w H EH CU D « « H EH w Q 2 O (X w Q 2 Z H O $ S 2 O ID I > H W En < crt oe Ui a. a: or ra ui en a. XXL in Z UJ a1- ii IJ- ^ Sj UJ XXL CJ CX . CD a -J (X. en rp ac o a »—* z ►—• CE: fe S '" 3: C3 C> z >• >3: o CM l£) in IT> ren in uo cu <<-I T ^ O R S s?« • oi <)• IS ¥ I ¥1 i^j i~i OJ 1 I I i I I I UD I UD I r- oj -3- OJ O UO m r~- n- o .... eo co UT ro ro ro ro ro I I I I U3 WD I —< O CO CO ro CU UT OJ n OJ 1 cu n en -^ i er> u3 t— <y in in U3 *-• II II 1^ir> co r~- co —•'-•—•—• U3 CO CO r- "da OJ i g £ OJ -<iU3 •<r s? rCO CO OJ o co —• ro o t— M S ro oj « S3 o i en —« \n co co r- 50 en i <j•*r in O.I i '.-"J CT> Ml rxi co *-> r- o ro en CO i— r~- vo m o in <-o ro oj 6^ en -a- in ro oj —•—..-•-■• i -aco -a^-< m i-O ^-^ ,-« m t.O OJ II n n II II 1 1 1 n ro r^- r- r-Ul tn t-O »T3 oa Ul -;r <r -sr -sr I--J utt in -.o I'U in -«r- r- r*•^1 1:0 co ca Li) U-] oj <-j -• tj3 •.xi ro ti II II II n n ro r-i r-i I 1 cr 1— I.J liJ II n u3 o- i~- -*• r^- L) 1- - II i-3 o i r.j f- r^ rCO d) CO co a5 an -T r- -3—.*-.—. f^ CO 'fz vo r— r-- t— in ua ifl eo en co co ao xr ■*• -a- -a- OJ en •*-. -a- oj o co r- i~- I-J o r~- ■•»■ IO kXI •J3 CO CO cu rin co ro 1 J ^ 4 1 ce ..j UJ to LJ I.J II n I.J tj tj >•>->- sr ro co en ud ui r- r^ co co ta co tn ex: i UJ >■- »". J ro ro ro e-i •-• in o o o -5 i— t— u IJJ o •—• i— en i— I— CJ til en i-t >-« er h— i— _j en en bW CU 5 LU 3 "i •-^ TABLE IV-6; NONINTERRUPTIBLE POLICY COMBINED AREAS DEMAND HYDRO PRICE QUANTITY GUMITY NGN DUE TO 3TRMFL. DUE TO IRRIG. PER PER HYDRO ACRE ACRE-FT Proportion: 0 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 ; ! i ! 32.347 32.348 32.348 32.332 18672 18013 17579 17134 14749 14750 14750 14750 3502 3402 2968 2523 -191464 -186519 -178376 -167901 -81756 -83467 -77254 -71724 -178.51 -182.24 -168.68 -156.60 -68.43 -72.19 -66.81 -62.03 ! : ! ! ! i i 1 32.312 32.314 32.316 32.300 18672 18015 17589 17153 14749 14750 14750 14750 3502 3404 2978 2542 -191464 -186519 -178376 -167501 -76130 -77938 -72102 -65919 -166.22 -170.17 -157.43 -146.11 -63.69 -67.40 -62.36 -57.87 ! ! ! i , 101 18672 18027 17653 14749 14750 14750 3502 3417 3042 -191464 -41544 -186519 -43951 -176376 -40483 -90.71 -95.96 -68.39 -34.57 -38.01 -35.01 Prcaortion: .133 INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY: -0.54 ELASTICITY: -1.0 i-rooortic-rii : INELASTIC ELASTICITY: -0.1 ELASTICITY -0.54 rjlSTICITY -1.0 52 withdrawals, and the withdrawals. The last total the change per acre-foot two are computed by due dividing to the change due to withdrawals by the number of acres and the net depletion in the study area respectively. The expected value of the losses due varied considerably. million about to irrigation They ranged from a high of about $66 when farmers pay for no pumping energy to a low of $33 million when they paid for all of their energy. pumping This translates into a difference of about $42 per acre-foot (see Tables IV - 2 to IV - 6). Interruptible Policy As expected, amount of the interruptible simulation limited the withdrawals farmers could make under low streamflow conditions. Since the probability of seeing such a low streamflow is only about 5 percent, we would expect to see denials in five years out of 100. at which some quantity of in market) the interruption will occur is the electricity demanded (without new minus the available The only level forecast irrigators nonhydro system generation (assumed fixed under this policy). This is 18672 MW - 6341 MW = 12331 ave. MW/year. This is within about two percent under of published figures for average critical flows (PNUCC, 1983a). hydrogeneration As mentioned 53 previously, the model assumes available water and demand. be implemented perfect Clearly, forecasting of the policy could not in exactly the same manner as the model suggests. Because of the simplicity of the model, it was not possible to run the simulations for elastic conditions. The nature of the replacement Therefore, examined model is such that it supplies power before it uses expensive only the completely nonhydropower. inelastic scenario and the total quantity demanded remains at the forecast quantity of 18672 ave. cheap was constant MW (see Tables IV - 7 to IV - 11). Hydrogeneration equal the follows the expected pattern. It to the amount of power that would be generated natural streamflow minus the withdrawals. streamflow there are no withdrawals, is from At the so these two low values are equal. At high streamflows, where there is enough water to supply all needs from hydropower, there including irrigation, is more hydropower than is needed. (Note: data on individual streamflows are not presented in the tables.) Nonhydro generation follows a regular pattern as streamflow is varied. For each 1000 ave. MW that streamflow is increased, the amount of nonhydropower decreases by 1000 ave. MW. The exception is at the high streamflow, where no nonhydropower is produced at all. The replacement power, that is, the power used in this simulation to replace the generating loss due to 54 READING TABLES IV-7 TO IV-11 NOTE: all entries are expected values ALLOWED DIVERSION - the percentage of irrigation withdrawal allowed under the new policy DIVERSION - the generating loss associated with the allowed diversion [ave. MW/year] PUMP LOSS - the pumping energy associated with the allowed diversion [ave. MW/year] NEW PRICE - see Tables IV-2 to IV-6 NON-HYDRO - " REPLACED - the amount of electricity needed to replace that lost to irrigation withdrawals and pumping energy [ave. MW/year] HYDRO GENERATION - see Tables IV-2 to IV-6 TOTAL QUANTITY - same as demand quntity in Tables IV-2 to IV-6 CHANGE IN CONSUMERS' SURPLUS TOTAL - change caused by natural streamflows only [$1000,s] IRRIGATION - change caused by irrigation withdrawals [$1000,s] PER ACRE - see Tables IV-2 to IV-6 PER ACRE-FT - " 55 TABLE IV-7 : INTERRUPTIBLE POLICY EAST HIGH Proportion Paid by Farmers: NONE .145 ALL 91 91 91 Diversion 104.1 104.1 104.1 Pump loss 89.9 89.9 89.9 New price 31.947 31.924 31.791 Non-hydro 3252 3252 3252 194 194 194 Hydro gen. 14764 14764 14764 Total quant. 18672 18672 18672 -191464 ■191464 ■191464 Irrigation 916361 -12649 9121 Per acre -52.78 -40.80 29.42 Per acre-ft -19.88 -15.34 11.27 Allowed div. Replaced Change in consumers' surplus: Total 56 TABLE IV-8 : INTERRUPTIBLE POLICY UMATILLA II Proportion Paid by Farmers: NONE .111 ALL 91 91 91 Diversion 1.8 1.8 1.8 Pump loss 12.3 12.3 12.3 New price 31.855 31.853 31.834 Non-hydro 3252 3252 3252 14 14 14 Hydro gen. 14858 14858 14858 Total quant. 18672 18672 18672 -191464 •191464 ■191464 -1399 -1012 2088 Per acre -34.97 -25.29 52.20 Per acre-ft -13.74 -9.91 20.71 Allowed div. Replaced Change in consumers' surplus: Total Irrigation 57 TABLE IV-9 : INTERRUPTIBLE POLICY HHH I Proportion Paid by Farmers NONE .116 ALL 91 91 91 Diversion 4.2 4.2 4.2 Pump loss 23.5 23.5 23.5 New price 31.863 31.859 31.823 Non-hydro 3252 3252 3252 28 28 28 Hydro gen. 14857 14857 14857 Total quant. 18672 18672 18672 -191464 •191464 •191464 -2704 -1930 3958 Per acre -38.63 -27.57 56.54 Per acre-ft -13.30 -9.47 19.66 Allowed div. Replaced Change in consumers' surplus: Total Irrigation 58 TABLE IV-10: INTERRUPTIBLE POLICY GRANDE RONDE Proportion Paid by Farmers: NONE .208 ALL 91 91 91 Diversion 3.9 3.9 3.9 Pump loss 4.5 4.5 4.5 New price 31.851 31.850 31.844 Non-hydro 3252 3252 3252 8 8 8 Hydro gen. 14856 14856 14856 Total quant. 18672 13672 18672 -191464 -191464 -191464 -726 -463 540 Per acre -19.11 -12.19 14.20 Per acre-ft -10.52 -6.69 7.93 Allowed div. Replaced Change in consumers' surplus: Total Irrigation 59 TABLE IV-11: INTERRUPTIBLE POLICY COMBINED AREAS Proportion Paid by Farmers NONE .139 ALL 91 91 91 Diversion 114.1 114.1 114.1 Pump loss 130.1 130.1 130.1 New price 31.976 31.945 31.751 Non-hydro 3252 3252 3252 244 244 244 Hydro gen. 14756 14756 14756 Total quant. 18672 18672 18672 -191464 ■191464 •191464 Irrigation -21189 -16036 15642 Per acre -46.26 -35.01 3 4.15 Per acre-ft -17.70 -13.37 13.25 Allowed div. Replaced Change in consumers' surplus: Total 60 withdrawals, ave. MW. farmers is The constant across most streamflows at exceptions are at the low streamflow are denied any water, where none is needed. and at the high 114 where streamflow In both of these cases the amount of replacement power is zero. Price amount changes of hydropower increased, decreased. This farmer payments. when showed the expected farmers mills/Kwh. was the price of As the electricity true under all three assumptions The greatest expected value of price paid The pattern. for no lowest pumping energy, of was about 31.95 all their was when they paid for pumping energy, about 31.791 mills/Kwh. Changes in consumers' surplus witdrawals showed a wide variation. due to irrigation At the low streamflows there was no loss or gain to consumers, that is, the change was zero. This is because the farmers in the simulation were not allowed any withdrawals. There was proportion a strong response to the change in of pumping energy paid for by the farmers. The greatest expected value of loss was in the case where did not pay, pay for all electricity farmers about $16.4 million. that they use, In contrast, there is consumers of about $9 million. a they when they net gain In this to case, are paying more for the electricity they use than the loss from irrigation withdrawals. The acre change in consumers' surplus computed on a and per acre-foot basis followed similar patterns per as 61 those for total change due to withdrawals. change varied The per acre from a loss of about $53/acre to a gain about $29/acre. The per acre-foot change went from a of loss of about $20/ac're-foot to a gain of about $ll/acre-f oot. Comparison of Policies Since under the interruptible policy was simulated the assumption of completely inelastic only demand, the only possible comparison is at this elasticity. The total simulations was consistent with demand. quantity of electricity marketed constant the at 18672 assumption of ave MW. by both This completely is inelastic (See Tables IV - 12 to IV - 16.) The differed amount of hydropower produced in the simulations by about 114 MW at the low streamflows. This is the amount of the generating loss at East High. This is due to the different assumptions underlying the two models. the noninterruptible model the irrigation withdrawals assumed to be taken under all streamflow conditions, In are while in the interruptible model withdrawals do not take place at low streamflows. At all other streamflows the amount of hydropower was identical in both models. It is not possible to make a direct comparison between the two policies nonhydropower. class The in terms of noninterruptible the production model has of nonhydropower while the interruptible of only one model has two: nonhydro power and replacement power. However it would 62 be instructive to noninterruptible nonhydropower compare the nonhydropower model with the combined in the interruptible streamflows there was no difference. in the replacement model. and At most The exception was at the low streamflow. Here the difference was 213 MW, the sum of for the generating loss and pumping energy. This accounts the differences of about 200 MW in the expected values of the amount of nonhydropower in the two models. Prices were generally higher in the than in the interruptible simulations. at the (under high all streamflow scenario where farm payment assumptions.) noninterruptible The exceptions were they were equal This pattern of higher price is followed by the expected values as well. Differences relatively in the change in consumers' surplus sizable. When farmers do not pay for were pumping energy, the loss to consumers is about four times higher in the noninterruptible model than in the interruptible model. At the other extreme, pumping energy, consumers when farmers pay for all of there is a loss' of about $33 their million to under the noninterruptible policy compared to a gain of about $9 million under the interruptible policy. Conclusions and Implications Before study, it drawing is any particular conclusions from necessary to caution the reader that this any 63 economic analysis approximation of can, at simulations is no exception. able to available to only be to the situation being modeled. were made about' the data used. be best, Some the gross This series strong assumptions These were made in order to obtain some estimates, do a research. given the resources Additionally, a highly aggregated series of models was used. Nonetheless, although doubt. the Thus, some exact the clear conclusions can be stated, magnitudes of the effects may reader is advised to use be in caution in evaluating and using these results. Examination assumptions are of the results suggest not as strong an that elasticity influence as those involving farmer payments. Although the losses to consumers are generally less under the more elastic assumptions (in the noninterruptible scenarios) vis-a-vis the less elastic, the amount of change is considerably less than that due to farmer payments. For example, in East High, when farmers do not pay for any pumping energy the greatest change elasticities is about $26/acre, across or about 10%. In contrast, the change from no farmer payments to full farmer payments is on the order of $80/acre, or about 60%. The results of these simulations suggest that electricity consumers in the Pacific Northwest would, an extended period, limit seen over be better off with a policy that would consumptive uses of the river system. This can be by the comparison of the change in consumers' surplus 64 due to irrigation withdrawals between the two policies. Farmers policy would obviously prefer to have the maintained. This is a case where the Kaldor-Hicks compensation consumers, test as policy, could farmers. The debate, might gainers applied. under the compensate amount but be of The proposed the losers, current electricity interruptible in this case the compensation would be open for amount of economic theory suggests that the compensation would not exceed the gain from the new policy. That would be the consumers' surplus. not be expected Clearly, of the change electricity consumers expected to pay farmers more than they from the new policy. at value in would would get On the other hand, farmers would want least as much as they would be giving up under the new policy. As an example, the difference between the two policies studied $48.1 had an expected value of between $45.8 million and million inelastic East demand. electricity amount in to This consumers limit High under suggests, the that assumption on average, would be willing to pay up to farmers' withdrawals in years of of this low streamflow (see Tables IV - 12 to IV - 16). The question arises as to how this payment might be made. Given that it would not be possible to make long term forecasts of streamflow further ahead than a few months at best, it would be extremely difficult to time payments. One possibility would be an insurance program. The electric READING TABLES IV-12 TO IV-16 NOTE: all entries are expected values PROPORTION - the proportion of pumping energy paid for by farmers DIFFERENCE - the change in consumers' surplus under the interruptible policy minus the change under the noninterruptible policy TOTAL - the change in consumers' surplus due to irrigation [$1000ls] PER ACRE - the change in consumers' surplus due to irrigation on a per acre basis [$'s] PER ACRE-FT - the change in consumers' surplus due to irrigation on a per acre-foot basis (i.e.-per acre-ft of net depletion) [$'s] en en TABLE IV-12: COMPARISON OF POLICIES EAST HIGH CHANGE IN CONSUMERS' SURPLUS Noninterruptible Policy Interruptible Policy Difference total per acre acre-ft -64441 -207.87 -78.87 -16361 -52.78 -19.88 -48080 -155.09 -58.99 total per acre acre-ft -60398 -194.83 -73.51 -12649 -40.80 -15.34 -47749 -154.03 -58.17 total per acre acre-ft -36684 -118.34 -44.46 9121 29.42 11.27 -45805 -147.76 -55.73 Proportion 145 0"\ TABLE IV-13: COMPARISON OF POLICIES UMATILLA II CHANGE IN CONSUMERS' SURPLUS Proportion Noninterruptible Policy Interruptible Policy Difference 0 : total : per acre : acre-ft -4937 -123.42 -48.57 -1399 -34.97 -13.74 -3538 1 -88.45 -34.83 .111 : total : per acre : acre-ft -4518 -112.96 -44.43 -1012 -25.29 -9.91 -3506 -87.67 -34.52 1 : total : per acre : acre-ft -1170 -29.24 -11.28 2088 52.20 20.71 -3258 -81.44 -31.99 1 TABLE IV-14: COMPARISON OF POLICIES HHH I CHANGE IN CONSUMERS' SURPLUS Noninterruptible Policy Interruptible Policy total per acre acre-ft ' -9576 -136.80 -47.20 -2704 -38.63 -13.30 -6872 -98.17 -33.90 total per acre acre-ft -8739 -124.85 -43.05 -1930 -27.57 -9.47 -6809 -97.28 -33.58 total per acre acre-ft -2375 -33.92 -11.49 3958 56.54 19.66 -6333 -33.92 -11.49 Proportion 116 Difference TABLE IV-15: COMPARISON OF POLICIES GRANDE RONDE CHANGE IN CONSUMERS' SURPLUS Noninterruptible Policy Inte'rruptible Policy total per acre acre-ft -2802 -73.75 -40.69 -726 -19.11 -10.52 -2076 -54.64 -30.17 total per acre acre-ft -2518 -66.27 -36.54 -463 -12.19 -6.69 -2055 -54.08 -29.85 total per acre acre-ft -1435 -37.77 -20.72 540 14.20 7.93 -1975 -51.97 -28.65 Proportion 208 Difference TABLE IV-16: COMPARISON OF POLICIES COMBINED AREAS CHANGE IN CONSUMERS' SURPLUS Noninterruptible Policy Proportion .139 Interruptible Policy Difference total per acre acre-ft -81756 -178.51 -68.43 -21189 -46.26 -17.70 -60567 -132.25 -50.73 total per acre acre-ft -76130 -166.22 -63.69 -16036 -35.01 -13.37 -60094 -131.21 -50.32 total per acre acre-ft -41544 -90.71 -34.71 15642 34.15 13.25 -57186 -124.86 -47.96 o 71 utilities would pay a fixed amount, i.e. the insurance fund on a regular basis. be - a premium, This premium incorporated into the rates consumers pay. low streamflow', the to would In years of fund would pay farmers not to take water. This explicitly recognizes the risk in setting for the use of the river system. policy To a significant extent, much of the risk faced by electricity consumers is taken into account. This can be seen in the relatively stable prices that have been charged in the past. there have been numerous price increases, already Although there have not been fluctuations in response to changing river conditions. This is policy not to suggest that introducing an would not make the rate interruptible setting process more complicated. Quite obviously, it would. An interruptible policy would serve to shift risk from electricity consumers to farmers. However, farmers could in turn those shift risk to there customers. To the customers lie outside the region, those customers lie within the that the risk will transferred away from the Pacific Northwest. that extent be To the extent region, and are electricity consumers, the risk will be transferred back to electricity consumers. Society may wish to limit the development could take place. locations in which It is clear that the further upstream withdrawals take place, society. The the greater the cost loss to consumers under the to noninterruptibe 72 policy for and inelastic demand is about seven East High than Umatilla II, This times greater on a per acre-foot basis. suggests that areas downstream be developed prior to those upstream.' Although much water focused the law now states that farmers can take as they need, attention possible on the recent the public increasing users of the river system. debate competition as has among It would however, be more complicated to institute an interruptible water policy than might first seem to be the case. Water law has a long and sometimes colorful history of confrontation. be It would likely that proposal of an interruptible policy in the region would contribute to these ongoing confrontations. Under current practice new users of surface water must apply for permits to make withdrawals. There may be denials of requests, for many reasons. Those who receive permits later than others are known as 'junior' users. Senior users have priority when there are low streamflows. This would be consistent with an interruptible water policy. implement an interruptible policy would One way be to to grant hydroelectric producers permits that would be senior to new irrigation development areas. could be granted Additionally, in such a way as to these limit rights irrigation withdrawals only under noncritical conditions. The situation. permit In system does not fully describe the addition there are many legal jurisdictional questions that arise. An area might fall under the aegis of 73 a local irrigation government, these. district, federal government, county government, or some state combination of The objectives of each level of government, and its constituency, might well differ in any given area (NADP, 1979) . It is remaining water quite clear that there are many questions to be answered before any substantial change policy implemented. such that studied here of them are economic in could be nature. Those mentioned in regard to the models used here could be dealt with Some as in by building more comprehensive models or running some of the existing simulations available in the region with an eye to testing proposed policies. This study has only considered the question of what happens to electricity consumers under the proposed policy. The agricultural side of the issue has not been dealt with. There to are social benefits to be had from allowing irrigate additional acreage in the region farmers (Obermiller, 1980,1981). Some the further insights might be gained from agricultural benefits from issues, with an eye to irrigation development. examining estimating A the cost/benefit comparison could then be made. It might also prove valuable to incorporate these analyses into a larger framework, that is, examine other river uses simultaneously. 74 BIBLIOGRAPHY Bonneville Power Administration. "Role of the Bonneville Power Administration in the PNW Power Supply System", Final Environmental Impact Statement (DOE/EIS-0066), Washington, 1980. "Supply Pricing Model Documentation for the ShortTerm Nongenerating Public Utility Load Forecast and the 1983 Wholesale Rate Environmental Impact Study." Portland, 1983a. "Wholesale Power Rate Design Study: 1983 Initial Rate Proposal." Portland, 1983b. Brokken, Ray F., D. Cory, R. Gum, and Wm. E. Martin. "Simplified Measurement of Consumers Welfare Change." Am. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63(pg. 715717) , 1981 Electric Power Research Institute. "Price Elasticites of Demand for Energy - Evaluating the Estimates." Palo Alto, 1982. Freeman, A. M. The Benefits of Environmental Improvement: Theory and Practice. Johns.Hopkins University Press; Baltimore, 1979. Garfield, P. J. and W. F. Lovejoy. Public Utility Economics Prentice- Hall; Englewood Cliffs, 1964. Joskow, P. L. "Contributions to the Theory of Marginal Cost Pricing." The Bell Journal of Economics, 7(pg. 197206) , 1976 Just, Richard E., D. L. Hueth, and A. Schmitz. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy. Prentice Hall; Englewood Cliffs, 1982. King, Larry D., M. L. Hellicksen, W. E. Schmisseur, and M. N. Shearer. "Projected Energy and Water Consumption of Pacific Northwest Irrigation Systems." Dept. of Energy (PNL-RAP-3 3); Oct. 1978. Mansfield,Edwin. Microeconomics: Theory and Applications. W. W. Norton; New York, 19 79 Martin, Wm. "Returns to Public Irrigation Development and the Concomitant Costs of Commodity Programs" American Journal of Agricultural Economics,61 (pg. 1107-1114), 1979 75 Northwest Agricultural Development Project. "An Analysis of Agricultural Potential in the Pacific Northwest with Respect to Water and Energy" (Working Paper III) Vancouver, 1979. Northwest Power Planning Council. "Northwest Conservation and Electric Power Plan." Portland, 1983. Obermiller, Frederick W. "Agriculture and Ilydropower: Costs, Benefits, and Tradeoffs" from a seminar: Conflicts Over the Columbia River, conducted by the Water Resources Research Institute, Oregon State University, 1930. "Evaluating the Social Benefits and Social Costs of Irrigation Development" Paper presented to the Water Policy Advisory Committee, State of Oregon Legislative Committee on Trade and Econoraic Development, 1973 Pacific Northwest River Basins Commission. "Comprehensive Framework Study" Portland, 1970. Pacific Northwest Utilities Conference Commitee. "Northwest Regional Forecast of Power Loads and Resources" Portland, 1983a. "Projection of Utlity Power Loads and Resources" Portland, 1983b. "Thermal Resources Database" Portland, 1982. Soil Conservation Service. "Irrigation Water Requirements." Technical Release No. 21. Washington, 1970. Whittlesey, Norman K., J. R. Buteau, W. R. Butcher, and D. Walker. "Energy Tradeoffs and Economic Feasibility of Irrigation Development in the Pacific Northwest" College of Agriculture Research Center, Washington State University Bulletin 0896; Pullman, 1981. Whittlesey, Norman K. and K. C. Gibbs. "Energy and Irrigation in Washington." Western Journal of Agricultural Economics, 3(pg. 1-9), 1973 APPENDIX 76 DERIVATION OF INPUT VALUES The test models in the analyses are run using 1985 as year. quantities That is, of the the current forecasts of prices electricity for 1985 are used as a and base against which changes due to new irrigation withdrawals and differing precipitation levels are made. It should be noted that all prices are inflated or deflated to 1983 dollars as necessary. Some readily of the values used as model parameters were available in published reports of regional utility agencies or industry groups. They were: PO: forecast price of electricity, 31.625 mills/Kwh (NPPC, 1983) QO: forecast quantity of electricity, 18672 ave. MW (PNUCC, 19 8 2a) CH: unit levelized cost-of producing hydropower 4 mills/KwH (NPPC, 1983) Average hydropower production 159 6 0 ave MW (PNUCC, 1983b) Note: this is not a model parameter, but is one of several levels of hydropower capability examined in the analyses. It is useful as a 'best guess1 for predicting hydro generation and also as a benchmark against which to compare other levels of capacity. The minimum and maximum levels of capacity are 119 6 0 ave. MW 77 and 18960 ave. MW. These correspond closely to values obtained from the BPA. It is also used to derive the cost of nonhydro resources. Some of the identifiable generating not have jointly values. inputs utilities in the PNW, owned by do the have easily In addition, several utilities. same type may of and that many of them do to allocate the costs among of not This is due to the large number available data. possible plants other have many It plants is not owners. very are always Also, even different cost structures depending upon age and other factors. Since the representative BPA of uses all several ages and types price of resources structures, and supplies a large proportion of the region's electricity, it was decided to use BPA costs as the basis of allocating costs for the region. Specifically, BPA costs broke down as follows (BPA, 1983w): Resource Hydropower generation Cost % 263,494,492 9.5 533,413,602 19.3 1,972,631,398 71.2 2,769,539,492 100.0 Nonhydro generation + purchased power Nongenerating costs Total Regional costs/revenues are found as follows: Total Revenue: 78 (18672 MW) (8.76) = 163566.72 gigawatt hours (163556.72 GwH) ($31625/GwH) = $5172797520 Fixed Costs: ($5172797520) (.712) = $3683031834 Hydrogenerating Costs: (15960 MW) (8.76) = 139809.6 GwH (139809.6 GwH) ($4000/GwH) = $559238400 Nonhydro Costs: Total costs - Fixed cost -Hydrogenerating costs = Total nonhydro cost $5172797520 - $3683031834 - $559238400 = $930527286 Per Unit Nonhydro Costs: Quantity of nonhydro resources: Total quantity - Hydro capability = (18672 MW) (15960 MW) = 23757.12 GwH Unit cost: ($930527286)7(23757.12 GwH) = $39168/GwH [or 39.168 mills/KwH] The mills/KwH percent mills/KwH cost of (NPPC, greater for resources is estimated 1983). than the However, derived as to this is estimate be only of 40 two 39.168 of nonhydro resources projected to be on line in the test year, rate new it was decided to use the nonhydro resource both. The projected capacity of the nonhydro resources is 6341 ave. MW (PNUCC, 1983b). The as the variable costs of operating a PNW coal plant used cost of replacement power in the interruptible 79 simulation were estimated from average figures current plants in the region (PNUCC, 1982) : Fuel cost; Operating _& maintenance Total 10.60 mills/KwH 1.53 mills/KwH 12.13 mills/KwH of all