THE IMPLIED COVENANT to MARK LESSEE'S DILEMMA Presented to Richard V/. Hemingway By Rocky D. Crocker "166 The Implied Covenant to Market: Lessee's Dilemma There is probably no other legal instrument in which the parties have so much to gain or lose with so little express contractual protection as in an oil and gas lease. The amount of royalties and their rapidity of payment are determined by the extent and promptness of the lessee's drilling and producing operations, and, in the case of gas, by the additional factor of the lessee's marketing of the gas. Nevertheless, the only clause usually found relating to the obligations of the lessee regarding drilling operations is the clause governing the time within which the initial well (or subsequent wells, if the first and subsequent wells prove nonproductive) shall be commenced, or rentals paid in lieu thereof.^ The habendum clause does nothing more than fix the maximum time within which production must be obtained for the lessee's estate to continue, and the delay rental clause is usually worded to allow the lessee the option of holding the estate throughout this 2 period without conducting any drilling operations. Rare- ly is any clause to be found in the usual type of lease imposing any obligations upon the lessee with regard to the marketing or utilization of gas produced, although the payment of gas royalties is in most leases entirely dependent upon the sale or use of the gas by the lessee. Leases are also normally silent with respect to the character of development expected once production is obtained upon the leasehold premises. Nor is any clause usually to be found obligating the lessee to drill in case production is had upon neighboring lands which result in drainage of oil or gas away from the leasehold premises. One might expect that this void of clauses can be explained because the interest of the lessor and lessee are the same. In which case the lessor may rely for his protec- tion upon the self-interest of the lessee. is not the case. However, that More commonly the interest of the lessor and the lessee frequently conflict. The reason for this void of express lease clauses may be because of the hazards and uncertainties surrounding the development of oil and gas properties. As well, the transportation and marketing of oil and gas make it practically impossible to prepare at the time the lease is executed the specific clauses governing the details of development and operation. Furthermore, there is always the possibility that any agreed program of development may be prescribed by legislative enactments or by rules and regulations of a state's conservation board.^ Another possible explanation may lie in the fact that oil and gas leases are usually prepared by the lessees, men experienced in the oil and gas business, and the lessors, frequently lacking in similar experience often sign the lease forms without adequate information upon which to predicate a demand even for proper protective clauses of a general nature. This was especially true in the early days of exploration. Whatever the reason for the failure of oil and gas leases to include express lease clauses, this dereliction 2 has been rendered harmless to a large extent by reason of the diligence of the courts in safeguarding the lessor's royalty interest through the medium of implied covenants. The law is well settled today that the lessee in any oil and gas lease assumes a number of implied obligations to the lessor with reference to the operation and development of the leasehold premises, in the absence of express provisions relieving the lessee of these obligations. The court's basis for implying these covenants is not clear. However, most courts have implied them to carry out the intentions of the contracting parties.^ If the parties to an oil and gas lease express terms in the lease contract that it clearly appears they contemplated such a covenant or provision that they didn't find it necessary to include it in the lease, or it is necessary to imply a covenant to give effect to the purpose of the contract as a whole the 5 courts have implied such covenants. In an oil and gas lease the main consideration that moves to the lessor is the royalty he will derive from the production of oil and gas. It is doubtful that a lessor would grant the exclu- sive right to a lessee to explore and develop his property for a period of years if such exploration and production was never to occur. And if oil or gas is found in paying quantities it seems obvious that the lessor would intend for such to be marketed. benefit from leasing. Otherwise, he would receive no Therefore, the duty of diligently promoting the productivity of the premises must be construed as having been written into the lease. "169 Another reason that the courts have implied covenants may be found in the theory of enforcing that contract which, under the circumstances, fair dealing between the lessor and lessee fairly demands that the lessee pursue.^ Since the lessee is the one who has the leases drawn, it would seem that he would have a tremendous advantage over an unsuspecting land owner. Especially where the land owner is poor and uneducated it would seem that this would be the case. Today, however, many farmers and land owners are neither poor nor uneducated and many times a land owner will have a competent attorney look over the lessee's form of lease to prevent such an unfair advantage. 7 If, as some authorities have proposed,' the basis for implying covenants in oil and gas leases is to promote fair dealing, it seems that they would not be implied where the lessor and the lessee stood on equal footing. The real reason for implying covenants in leases may simply be that the lav/ of oil and gas has just "grown up" over the years implying these covenants. To begin, now, looking at the position of the parties and implying covenants only when one of the parties to the lease has an advantage would cause an unbelievable amount of litigation. It would probably be much simpler, considering the present state of the law, to allow the present growth to continue. One covenant that has seen such recent growth is the implied covenant to market oil and gas. Although this covenant may be applied to oil, it is usually associated with gas production. Royalty on gas is usually an agreed fraction " 170 of the gas marketed or utilized by the lessee/' Since in most leases today, the royalty upon gas is payable not upon the gas produced, but only upon the gas marketed by the lessee; the prevailing view in most jurisdictions is that an implied obligation to use reasonable diligence in marketing the gas o will arise upon its discovery in paying quantities.' Texas courts also follow the majority view and imply a covenant to market when royalty payments are conditioned upon the marketing of oil and gas.^ The question becomes, when and at what price oil ana gas must be marketed. In the case of Cole Petroleum Co. 11 v. United States Gas & Oil Co. a lease clause obligated United States Gas & Oil Co., after completion of the first or test well, to "proceed with such additional development as is reasonably necessary....to 1 2 develop this lease to a normal stage of production." - The court stated that after looking at all the terms of the contract, developing the lease to a normal stage of production necessarily involved marketing oil or gas discovered in paying quantities in order to yield part of the oil or cash for the gas 13 as royalty. ^ Simply exploring and discovering oil or gas lay the basis for marketing. The court went on to state that "under the ordinary oil and gas lease, the lessee is not required to market the yield of leased land at any certain time or for any certain price." ^ The lessee's duty is to exercise ordinary or reasonable care. The court ex- plained that the exercise of ordinary or reasonable care meant reasonably diligent operation for the best advantage 15 and benefit of both the lessor and lessee. it would scorn then, that the time of marketing and the price received for the product would be unimportant as long as the lessee was diligent in his efforts to find a reasonably priced market within a reasonable time. Nevertheless, other cases seem to suggest that this may not be the case, which is where the lessee may encounter problems.' In many instances, especially where gas is involved, it may be years before a pipeline can be connected to a well at some remote location. Other times, but less often, there may be an available pipeline but the price may not be as economically beneficial as desired. Of course there is no problem where the pipeline and the price are available and adequate. But, where this is not the case, the lessee may face a dilemma especially if either price or time is important in complying with the implied covenant to market. If a lessee sells the gas or oil too quickly he may have missed the opportunity to receive the best available price possible or worse yet, not even a reasonable price. Where the lessee waits too long for a better price he may be beyond the reasonable time limits of the marketing covenant. In either case the lessee may have breached his duty to the lessor to find a favorable market. It is true courts have held that the lessee may withhold products from the market for1 a reasonable time in order to receive the best price. In addition, in the 17 r case of Gazin v. Pan American Petroleum Corporation ' where a gas well was shut-in .from 1956 until I960 in order "172 to obtain a hotter contract price, it v/as held that the lessee had not breached the covenant to market because he used due diligence during the period. But, what if the period had been form 1956 until 1961, or 1965? the lessee used due diligence until 1981? tinue to have the well shut-in? What if Could he con- It would seem doubtful that a lessee could prove that he used due diligence where a well is shut-in for such a period of time. How- ever, if the lessee had marketed the gas as soon as the well "came in" in 1956 he may have breached the marketing covenant if he did not receive at least the fair market value for the gas. There is considerable authority for the proposition that the lessee owes a duty to the lessor to obtain the best price possible for gas. This duty can arise either under a "market value" or a "proceeds" royalty clause. Professor Merrill has stated "the concept of diligence in marketing should include the duty to realize the highest price obtainable by the exercise of reasonable effort... 1Q he is bound to get the best price he can." It has also been stated that "at all events, it is well settled that the lessee is impliedly obligated to 'market' - to sell or otherwise utilize - the production obtainable from a commercial well. Probably this requires the lessee to secure 19 the highest price reasonably obtainable...." y Several courts have also found an implied duty or obligation on the part of the lessee to obtain a market for gas at the best price available.20 -7- The recent Texas case of Amoco Production Company v. 21 First Bantist Church of Pyote inn covenant ovon further. seems to push the market- Amoco owned oil and gas leaser, covering several small tracts of land in the townsite of Pyote. Each of these leases provided for a one-eighth royalty to be paid based on the "proceeds" realized on the gas sold at the wells. Amoco pooled its leases with other leasehold estate owners in the same section to form the Caprito 100 unit. In 1973 the working interest owners drilled a well in this unit which was completed as a producer. Each working interest owner had been selling gas from this well to various purchasers. Amoco was selling its percentage of the gas (about 17%) from the well to Pioneer Natural Gas Company and Odessa Natural Gasoline Company, which acquired its rights under Pioneer. The price Amoco was receiving from Pioneer for this gas was based on a purchase contract entered into in November, 1969 which covered six of eithteen leases involved here. In June, 1975j Amoco entered into a supplemental agreement v/ith Pioneer by which Amoco dedicated the other twelve leases to the 1969 contract. In return for this dedication Amoco's price for gas v/as increased from 17tf per MCF to 70c per MCF for gas produced from August 197^ for twelve months, 710 por MCF for the next twelve months and 720 per MCF for the remaining months through June, 1977. This price was about one-half the amount at which gas was being sold to other purchasers from the same well by the other working interest owners. The court concluded that Amoco had an implied covenant or duty to act in good faith when marketing the gas of its royalty owners even under a lease provision providing for "payment of royalty based upon the proceeds realized from the sale of gas." Amoco was found to have breached its duty to act in good faith by failing to receive the fair market value for the 22 gas sold under the contract. However, there was no evidence of bad faith present anywhere in the record; only proof that the lessee sold his gas for less than others sold theirs. Therefore, under this holding a lessee has a duty to market gas at its fair market value. Failure to enter into a contract for sale of gas for at least the going fair market value is a breach of the lessee's duty to act in good faith and thus, a breach of the implied covenant to market. Where the gas has been marketed at less than the fair market value the lessor is entitled to recover the difference between that and its selling price. Since the holding in the Amoco Production Company case the dilemma of the lessee seems to have become more closely defined. If the lessee is not held to breach the covenant to market by receiving less than fair market value, he at least will be required to pay the difference between the selling price of the gas and the going fair market value. But, where the lessee holds the gas off the mar- ket to obtain a better price or in some instances, just the fair market value, he may be in jeopordy of breaching the implied covenant to market by not selling the gas 9 within a reasonable period of time. As mentioned earlier, it has been held that a lessee may wait for a better price and need not sell at the first opportunity, but to avoid breaching the marketing covenant he must use due diligence to find a market during the per25 iod he is withholding the gas. ^ Whether a lessee is ex- ercising due diligence is a question of fact which of necessity depends upon the circumstances of each case,^^ In one case where the only market for a gas well was onehalf mile away, the.court held that a reasonable time in which to market was the reasonable time it would take 25 the lessee to lay a pipeline to the only available market. y The court went on to say that it was incumbent upon the lessee under the circumstances to forthwith begin operations with reasonable diligence and dispatch until the 26 gas reached the market. In some instances, however, there may not be an available buyer and no amount of diligence will aid in finding a market. Another possible situation would be where there is a buyer but he is unwilling to pay a price for the gas that others are receiving in the same area. What can a lessee do to avoid the problems he may face with regard to marketing oil or gas within a reasonable time or waiting to receive at least the fair market value for the product? The simplest answer would be to write an express provision into the lease. As in the case of other implied covenants, an express covenant on the same subject will displace the implied covenant to 10 . . 27 mantes. There are several different clauses that can be used to solve the problem. In some instances a general clause may be the best approach. 28 Texas Company In the case of Gex v. Louis S. Gex ana his wife, Kate, executed, to the Texas Company a mineral deed. vided in part as follows: The instrument pro- "It is agreed that the Texas Company, its successors or assigns, shall never be under obligation to drill or mine oil or gas or other minerals, but such mining or drilling, both before and after -production, shall be wholly at the ontion of said grantee, its successors or assigns." (emphasis added) The grantor was to receive one-eighth royalty if there was production from the property in paying quantities. The court cited as authority Cole Petroleum v. United States Gas & Oil C o . ^ which involved a lease situation where there were covenants requiring the lease to be developed to the normal state of production. It was held in the Cole case that the clause "to develop said lease to a normal state of production" necessarily involved marketing.^ Analogizing this holding the court in the Gex case found the expression, "wholly at the option of the grantee," as used in the deed precluded any implied covenant to develop or produce. The court stated, "By the same reasoning, conversely the expressed covenant in the mineral deed here involved by eliminating any implied covenant to develop or produce precludes any implied covenant to market."-"^ A general lease clause providing that "all develop-11- 177 menL shall be at the discretion of the lessee" may also provide an adequate solution to the aforementioned prob32 lem. In the case of Cowden v. Broderick & Calvert^ the lessor was trying to have a lease cancelled because of failure of lessees, after discovery of oil in payingquantities upon a 160 acre tract, to continue reasonably to develop the said tract by drilling and equipping other wells. The lessors claimed that the implied obligation to develop with reasonable diligence arose after the discovery of oil in paying quantities in the first well. The court stated that implied obligations do arise where a lease is silent upon the subject. The clause requiring "other development to be at the discretion of the lessee" required the lessee only to act in good faith and is not the same obligation as would arise under an implied covenant. v Although this case did not specifically deal with the marketing covenant, arguably a clause to the effect that "marketing shall be within the sole discretion of the lessee" would have the same effect. Such a clause would require a lessee only to exercise good faith and though not as adequate as other clauses, may take some of the sting out of the implied covenant to market without restricting the lessee -to strict time and price constraints. Although these general lease clauses may be found to displace the implied covenant to market, the better approach may be to include a specific express clause in the lease. In this way both the lessor and the lessee can be assured -12- 178 of the terms they are agreeing to in the lease. With- out such an express clause there is no way the lessee can be assured that the implied covenant to market has been rendered harmless. One common lease clause thought to effect the implied marketing covenant is the shut-in gas royalty clause. Under this clause the lessee may continue the life of the lease by paying a stipulated sum in lieu of the royalty a lessor would receive if oil or gas was being produced.^ Although it is arguable that the implied duty to market is negated by the right of the lessee not to market upon the payment of shut-in royalty, some authorities believe this view to be unsound because it misapprehends the pur55 pose of the shut-in c l a u s e . P r o f e s s o r s Williams and Meyers of Stanford University follow this view on the reasoning that the shut-in royalty clause was intended to modify the habendum clause so that the lease may be preserved in the interim between discovery of gas and marketing thereof, although there is no production. They believe that the shut-in royalty clause is a saving clause to counteract decisions holding that discovery of gas does not satisfy the requirement of production in the habendum clause and that, under such circumstances, the lease terminates at the end of the primary term for lack of production in paying q u a n t i t i e s . T h e r e being no inconsistency between the shut-in royalty clause and the implied marketing covenant, the paying of such does nothing to relieve the lessee of his duty to market within a reasonable time at a fair market price. They sight as authority for this view the Louisiana case of Risinror v. 57 Arkansas-Louisiana Gas Co. In that case a gas well pro- ducing a large volume of salt water was shut-in and shut-in royalty was paid by the lessees. The lessors sought to cancel the lease because of failure on the part of the lessees to market the gas. The court found that for the lessee to market the gas under the present technology would not be profitable. Therefore, the lessee had not violated the express provisions of the lease to use due diligence in the operation of the well. Professors Williams and Meyers state that "if the court had thought that the shut-in gas royalty clause barred enforcement of the implied marketing covenant, we believe that it would have said so and disposed of the case in this easy fashion rather than weighing the evidence to determine breach of -2 duty."^ O This seems to be a very questionable reading of the holding in the Risinger case. The lessees in that case never argued the position that they could permanently and indefinitely continue to make shut-in royalty payments. Nor did they urge that the shut-in royalty clause displaced the implied covenant to market. The lessees' only defense was that they had used due d i l i g e n c e . A s a result, the court in coming to its conclusion never discussed the effect of shut-in payments on the implied covenant to market. The court did state in its holding "the fact that they (the lessees) succeeded in obtaining a well producing gas, entitles them, under the express provisions thereof, "180 to continue the leases in effect by paying 'i!>200.00 per year per well until such time as the gas shall be utilized or sold off the premises."^0 Professor Williams and Professor Meyers views also seem questionable for another very subtle reason. They state that the shut-in clause is used to preserve the lease between discovery of gas and the marketing thereof, 1 I where there is no production. Although the definition of "production" varies among jurisdictions and one construction of the term does not include marketing, the ma.jor line of construction does include marketing in the term "production."^ Therefore, if the shut-in royalty clause is intended as a substitute for production,^ it seems only logical that such payments would necessarily be substituted for marketing as well. There is little authority on the question of the effect of the shut-in royalty clause on the implied covenant to market and there is no authority squarely in point. However, there are a few cases that at least suggest that payment of shut-in royalty does effect the implied covenant to market. In the case of Cox v. Miller*^ a gas well was productive in paying quantities but gas was not produced because there was no market available. The court held that the lease had terminated for lack of production at the end of the primary term. The court, however, went on to say "the rule is otherwise where the lease provides in the alternative for a stipulated rental for each gas well L, 5 and the rental is paid."^ Professor Summer of the Univer- ",5I81 sity of Illinois has also stated that in some cases where gas has been discovered in paying quantities and where the lessee was unable to market the gas because of an unavailable market or otherwise, it has been held that the lessee could extend the lease beyond the primary term by payment or tender of a gas well rental.^ Most of the scant authority suggest the sounder view to be that the shut-in royalty clause does affect the implied covenant to market. The exact effect is still speculative, how- ever. Conclusion The lessee of an oil and gas leasehold who is interested in protecting his property should consider the use of express lease provisions. Admittedly, express provisions cannot be used in every instance because of the very nature of oil and gas exploration and development. Also, it would be very difficult for a lessor to be convinced to accept many lease provisions. Especially a general "blanket" type provision disclaiming all implied covenants which would be very beneficial to the lessee. Neverthe- less, there are some provisions that should be included in the lease if possible. One such provision would be one which would protect the lessee from the implied covenant to market. This is especially true now that the implied covenant to market may include an obligation to sell gas at fair market value at the very least. 16 However, a lessee may reccive some protection if he fails to include an express lease provision regarding the marketing of gas, where the common shut-in royalty clause has been included in the lease. The wise lessee will not simply rely upon the shut-in royalty clause but will try instead, to have a provision included in the lease that deals specifically with the implied covenant to market. FOOTNOTES 1 A. W. Walker, Jr., The Nature of the Property Interest Created By An Oil And Gas Lease in Texas, 8 Tex. k> Rev. 483, 520-540(1930). 2 Id. at 511-520. 3 Helmerick v. Roxana Pet. Corp., 136 Kan. 254, 14 Pac. (2d) 663 (1932). Lf R* Hemingway, The Law of Oil and Gas, § 8.1 (1971). 5 Id. ^ M. Merrill, Covenants Implied in Oil and Gas Leases, § 221, 222 (2d. ed. 1940) 8 Id at § 34, 9 1A L. Summers, Oil and Gas, § 131 (1927). Where a fixed sum per year on gas wells is paid as royalty it has been held immaterial whether the gas was marketed so long as the fixed sum was paid. Id. -18- 184 10 Stanolind Oil & Gas Co. v. Barnhill, 107 S.W. (2d) 746 (Tex. Civ. App. 1937 error ref'd). 11 41 S. W. (2d) 414, 415 (Tex. Sup. 1931). 12 Id. at 416. Id. at 417. Hemingway, supra n. 4, at I 8 . 9 . ^ 17 1^ Okl., 367 P. (2d) 1010. M. Merrill, sunra n. 6, at § '34. 19 Siefkin, Rights of Lessor and Lessee with Respect Sale of Gas and as to Gas Royalty Provisions, 4th Annual Institute Oil & Gas Law & Tax, 182 (1953). 20 Livingston Oil Corporation v. Waggoner, 273 S. IV. 903 (Tex. Civ. App. - Arnarillo 1925, no writ). 21 579 S. W. (2d) 280 (Tex. Civ. App. - El Paso 1979, reh. denied) 2t " Id at 235 • 23 Cazin v. Pan-America Petroleum Corp, 367 P. (2d) 1010, 24 Id.at 1012. Union Oil Co. of California v. L. B. Ogden, 278 S. W. (2d) 246 (Tex. Civ. App. - El Paso 1955, no writ), 26 27 w. Hemingway, supra n. 16. 10 25 337 S. W. (2d) 820 (Tex. Civ. App. - Amarillo 1960, reh. denied). 29 41 S. IV. (2d) 414, (Tex. Sup. ^1931). 50 Id at 416. 31 337 S. W. (2d) 820, 826 (Tex. Civ. App. - Amarillo 1960, reh. denied). 52 114 S. W. (2d) 1166 (Tex. Sup. 1938). Id. at 1171. 3 Williams and Meyers, Oil and Gas Law, § 631-635 (1962) 20- 3? 5 .Villiams ana Meyers, Oil and Gas I,aw, § 858.2 (1964). id. 37 58 39 3 So. (2d) 289 (1941). 5 'Villiams and Meyers, supra n. 35« 3 So. (2d) 289, 292. Id at 293. I 1 5 Williams and Meyers, supra n. 35. ^ R. Hemingway, supra n. 4 at § 6.4. ^ 3 Williams and Meyers, Oil and Gas Law § 632.13 (1962) (Variants of Shut-in Royalty Clause: Effect of Pay- ment or Tender) The customary shut-in royalty clause begins as follows: "and if such payment is made it will be considered that gas is being produced throughout such year..." Id. -21- 187