AN ABSTRACT OF THE THESIS OF Brett M. Fried for the degree of Master of Science in Aqricultural and Resource Economics presented on December 16, 1992. Title: Usinq Valuation Functions to Estimate Chanqes in the Quality of a Recreational Experience: Elk Huntinq in Oreqon Abs tract approved: Richard M. Adams Public recreational agencies need activities wildlife species. to information assist on the in managing value of fish and Over the past two decades economists have developed and applied techniques to measure the value of such non-marketed commodities. The contingent valuation method (CVM) is one technique used by economists to measure net benefits associated with a change in the quantity or quality of a non-marketed commodity. Unlike other techniques such as the travel cost and hedonic methods, which use market data to infer willingness to pay (WTP), CVM directly elicits willingness to pay or willingness to accept (WTA) information. CVM is used in this thesis to estimate the use value of changes in the quality of the elk hunting experience. T h e focus of the study is elk hunting on the Starkey Research Forest in eastern Oregon. Since 1988, the Oregon Department of Fish and Wildlife (ODFW) and the U.S. Forest Service have collected data on big game hunting on this area. The Starkey data sets provide unique research opportunities because of the enclosed nature of the Starkey Research Forest (25,000 acres surrounded by 38 miles of fence) and the duration of the survey effort (10 years). Although the surveys contain questions specific to an analysis by both the contingent valuation and travel cost methods, only the contingent valuation method is considered here. Specific objectives of the thesis research include: (1) derivation of valuation functions for the two dichotomous choice WTP and WTA elicitations, (2) estimation of changes in WTA and WTP for changes in significant explanatory variables, and (3) suggestions for improvements in future Starkey surveys. Valuation functions, as used here, provide increased flexibility over point estimates. The explanatory variables in a valuation function can be changed to obtain estimates of the corresponding changes in WTP and WTA values. The valuation functions can then be used to derive estimates of central tendency for the contingent scenarios. Results include an estimated median value of $113 per hunter for access to hunting and an estimated mean value per trip of $287 per hunter for increases in the elk herd (to ensure an opportunity to shoot at an elk). Additionally, the flexibility of valuation functions is demonstrated by showing how changes in the values of significant (at the .05 level) explanatory variables affect WTP and WTA values. Four policy and three methodological implications are gleaned from the results. The four policy implications are that: (1) the elk hunting recreational experience is providing substantial benefits to Starkey hunters, (2) willingness to pay values are sensitive to the size of respondents' incomes, (3) respondents are willing to pay more to increase the elk herd to the point where they would be virtually certain of having an opportunity to shoot at an elk and (4) Starkey hunters object to the tradeoff between their right to hunt and private goods. The three methodological implications are demonstration of the flexibility of WTP functions, confirmation of the importance of using specific unambiguous wording in the contingent scenarios, and a (1) (2) a and (3) a confirmation of the importance of pretests to determine the initial ranges and number of bids in dichotomous choice surveys. Two problems with the current surveys are the loss of efficiency due to the low number and narrow range of bids and the lack of specificity and ambiguous wording used in some of the contingent scenarios. Suggestions include increases in the number and range of the bids, the inclusion of an additional question and the inclusion of a Nnot for sale" category. Using Valuation Functions to Estimate Changes in the Quality of a Recreational Experience: Elk Hunting in Oregon by Brett M. Fried A THESIS submitted to Oregon State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science Completed December 16, 1992 Commencement June 1993 APPROVED: Professor of Agricultural and Resource Economics in charge of major Head of department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Dean of Gradua School Date thesis presented Typed by ..- December 16, 1992 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT The quality of the educational experience at OSU has surpassed my highest expectations. I owe thanks to the professors and colleagues who have mentored me and made my experience at OSU so enjoyable and productive. Particular thanks must be extended to two individuals without whom the completion of this thesis would have been impossible. They are: Dr. Richard Adams for his insight, encouragement, editing and contributions; Bob Berreris for his support, advice, contributions and friendship. Additionally, I would like to thank, Dr. Olvar Bergland for introducing me to the Starkey Research Forest data sets and for starting me on the road towards the preparation of my thesis; Dr. David Ervin and Dr. Tremblay for being members of my committee; Lynn Starr, Dr. Chris Carter, Dr. Thomas Quigley and Mike Wisdom for providing primary and secondary data; and my wife, Alexis, without whom I would never have come to graduate school. TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER PAGE INTRODUCTION 1 Problem Statement 2 Objectives 5 Justification 5 THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 7 Economic Efficiency 7 Consumer Surplus 8 The Consumer's Decision Problem 9 The Theoretical Model 14 Hypotheses 19 EMPIRICAL APPLICATION 22 The Starkey Surveys 22 Survey Design and Administration 25 Potential Sources of Bias 29 Data Analysis 30 RESULTS AND IMPLICATIONS 36 The WTP Models 36 The Logit Regressions 37 The Valuation Functions 42 The WTA Models 45 The Logit Regressions 46 The Valuation Functions 49 Implications 51 Implications From the WTP Models 53 Implications From the WTA Models 60 V. Conclusion 63 REFERENCES 69 APPENDICES Appendix 1: Data From the Starkey Survey 74 Appendix 2: The Starkey Survey 87 LIST OF TABLES TABLE PAGE 1 Hicksian measures of welfare change 13 2 Summary information for the Starkey 24 3 Response rates for the Starkey surveys 26 4 BId levels by group for the DC Starkey surveys 28 5 Percentage of yes responses by group for the DC surveys 32 6 Missing responses to valuation questions 35 7 Results from the logit model: increased 40 cost of hunting (ACCINC) 8 Results from the logit model: increased 41 opportunity to shoot at an elk (ELKP) 9 Results from the logit model: increased 47 willingness to accept payment to forgo hunting (HUNTP) 10 Results from the logit model: willingness to accept payment to forgo hunting on the Starkey (HUNTPS) 48 11 Estimated median and mean WTP and WTA values for different income levels 59 USING VALUATION FUNCTIONS TO ESTIMATE CHANGES IN THE QUALITY OF A RECREATIONAL EXPERIENCE: ELK HUNTING IN OREGON I. INTRODUCTION Hunting for deer, elk and other big game species is an important recreational activity for many Americans. In Oregon, approximately 110,000 hunters engaged in elk hunting in 1990 (ODFW). public lands. The majority of big game hunting occurs on Due to the lack of a competitive market for hunting, recreation values can only be estimated through the analysis of elicitation. related market Direct goods elicitation or through using the direct contingent valuation method has become increasingly popular in valuing fishing and hunting experiences (see Cory and Martin, 1985; Johnson and Adams, 1989; Loomis, 1988; Mitchell and Carson, 1989) Public recreational agencies need activities wildlife species. to information assist on the in managing value of fish and For the last four years, the USDA Forest Service and the Oregon Department of Fish and Wildlife (ODFW) have surveyed hunters who received deer or elk tags for hunting on the Starkey Research Forest. These hunts take place within a 25, 000 acre research area that is enclosed with 38 miles of cattle, deer and elk proof fence. surveys, scheduled to continue through 1998, with multiple objectives in mind. The Starkey are developed The main objective of the 2 surveys is to obtain data with which to estimate the values and the economic impacts attributable to deer and elk hunting. Given the characteristics of the Starkey hunting experience, these data offer a unique opportunity to value aspects of big game hunting in Oregon. For purposes of this thesis, only data concerning the economic valuations of elk are considered. Additionally, although the surveys contain questions specific to an analysis by both the contingent valuation and travel cost methods, only the contingent valuation method is considered here. PROBLEM STATEMENT In 1870, the Oregon legislature passed a prohibiting the ukilling law and selling of deer and elk from February 1 to June 1" (Harper et al., 1987, p. 1). This law, however, lacked the enforcement necessary to prevent the near extinction of Oregon elk by the turn of the century. that time, rigorously enforced legislation and Since active management have resulted in the return of a healthy population of elk and deer in the State. Management and regulation of wildlife species is not without cost to Oregonians. Financing for management and enforcement comes primarily from hunting and license fees. In addition, there are opportunity costs associated with wildlife management decisions. A reduction (or increase) in the number of deer and elk or other wildlife species in 3 multiple use management schemes may increase (decrease) the benefits accruing to individuals deriving utility from other uses. The difficult tradeoffs involved in resource management decisions have resulted in the search for tools to aid policy makers in the decision making process. most often used to alternative analysis. sort resource out The analytical tool the economic tradeoffs of allocations has been benefit-cost A problem, however, is obtaining estimates of the benefits associated with increases in fish or wildlife species populations. One method for obtaining net benefit estimates for non- marketed commodities such as elk hunting is the contingent valuation method (CVM). CVM involves the direct elicitation of respondents' willingness to pay (WTP) or willingness to accept (WTA) payment for changes in the quantity or quality of a public good or service. These direct elicitations are done by surveys and elicit either open-ended or closed-ended responses. In the open-ended elicitations, respondents simply express the maximum they are willing to pay or accept. In the closed-ended elicitations, respondents vote yes or no to one or more bid offers. The hypothetical market in the Starkey surveys is the market for elk and deer hunting. are: The contingent scenarios (1) How much would you be willing to pay (accept) to forego hunting? and (2) How much would you be willing to pay 4 for the virtual guarantee that you would have an opportunity to shoot at an elk? bias in CVM surveys. Clearly, there are potential sources of They include hypothetical, strategic, compliance and starting point biases. Further discussion of potential biases and elicitation techniques is found in Chapter 3. The current focus among contingent valuation researchers has moved away from tests of the method's reliability toward refinements of method (see Cameron and James, 1988; Edwards and Anderson, 1991;) However, anomalies such as differences between WTP and WTA elicitations and the number of protest responses Hanemann still vex researchers. (1991) Current research by indicates that these anomalies should be preserved as an integral part of the results of CVM research. One impetus for continued research on CVM has come from the natural resource damage assessments of the Exxon oil spill in Prince William Sound, Alaska. Researchers such as McFadden (1992) have raised questions about the reliability of CVM, particularly in regards to nonuse values. The measuring of nonuse values such as existence value (the value of knowing that a certain quality or quantity of a resource exists) is currently the most controversial area of CVM research. This study, however, is only concerned with measuring use values. CVM researchers often develop point estimates specific to a particular time and site (see Sorg and Loomis, 1984; Brookshire, Randall and Stoll, 1980). The disadvantage of 5 point estimates is their lack of flexibility. That is, point estimates are specific to the values used for the explanatory variables in the original model. An alternative approach is to use a valuation function (Cameron, 1988), in which the values of the explanatory variables in a valuation function can be changed to obtain estimates of the corresponding changes in WTP and WTA values. OBJECTIVES The primary objective of this thesis is to estimate the use value of changes in the quality of the elk hunting experience. Specific objectives include: deriving (1) valuation functions for the two WTP and WTA elicitations, (2) deriving estimates of the changes in WTA and WTP for changes in significant explanatory variables and (3) making suggestions for improvements in future Starkey surveys. JUSTIFICATION There are three reasons why the Starkey data sets are particularly appropriate objectives of this thesis. for addressing the identified First, the enclosed nature of the Starkey Experimental Forest and the extensive biological monitoring allow for a high level of management of the hunted species and the hunters. This increases the ability of researchers to control for differences between hunts. 6 Second, the long term nature of the study (ten years) makes it possible to analyze changes over time and to provide additional information on the reliability of the contingent valuation method. With the exception of 1988 (a survey for deer hunting was not completed) and 1989 (bid levels were left blank on one of the surveys) there have been surveys corresponding to every hunt on the Starkey Experimental Forest. With two elk hunts and one deer hunt per year, at the conclusion of ten years, surveys will have been administered to participants in 28 hunts. Third, hunters realize that they will be required to provide research data as a condition for hunting within the area. Researchers often encounter resistance when soliciting hunters to complete surveys. The hunters on the Starkey, however, choose the Starkey with the understanding that they will provide research information. As noted later, this results in a high degree of compliance with the survey procedures. The remainder of chapters. this thesis is divided into four Chapter 2 describes the theoretical framework for the model, Chapter 3 presents the application of the framework to the valuation of elk hunting, chapter 4 describes the results and implications from the application of the empirical model and Chapter 5 provides conclusions gleaned from the study and offers suggestions for further research. 7 THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS II. It is important to understand the theoretical foundation of CVM because preferences. the technique is not based on revealed With CVM, a contingent scenario is constructed and then direct money measures for the changes in welfare are elicited. Consumer theory is used in the construction of the contingent scenario and the subsequent analyses. The context for the development of the theoretical model is established with a brief discussion of economic efficiency. ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY Economists operating within the framework of economic efficiency can provide insight into potential between alternate policy choices. tradeoffs Pareto optimality or economic efficiency exists when an agent cannot be made better of f without making another agent worse off. Varian (1992) and Nicholson (1989) Randall (1989), provide detailed discussions of the necessary conditions to achieve efficient solutions. In Oregon, ODFW allocates access to big game hunting by a quota system; a quota of hunters is set for each hunt area. Since the number of applicants typically exceeds the quota, selection is by random drawing. All successful applicants pay flat fees for tags and licenses. Additionally, the department regulates bag limits and sets the length of hunting seasons. Hunters indicate their preferred locations in their 8 applications, but the intensity of preference for different hunting locations is not reflected the in current fee structure. In the absence of market prices, economists have devised three methods for obtaining estimates of willingness to pay. They are the hedonic price method, the travel cost method and the contingent valuation method. Whereas the travel cost and the hedonic methods use market data to infer willingness to pay, CVM directly elicits WTP or WTA information. Each of these methods can be used to estimate changes in the consumer surplus or net benefits associated with a change in the quantity or quality of a resource. CONSUMER SURPLUS Consumer surplus is a measure of the difference between the amount a consumer actually pays for a good or service and the maximum amount he is willing to pay. When maximum willingness for a good, to pay exceeds the expenditure consumer surplus can be measured by calculating the area between the demand curve and the price line. The demand consumer surplus function most commonly associated with is the Marshallian demand. Marshallian demands are generated by varying the price or quantity of a good while holding money income constant. For a normal good, these changes in price or quantity result in an income and substitution effect. The substitution effect results in 9 movements along an individual's indifference curve, whereas the income effect results indifference curve. in movement to different a Consequently, Marshallian measures of consumer surplus only provide unique measures of welfare change under the assumption of constant marginal utility of income (Just et al., 1982). Hicks' (1943) response to the inadequacies of the Marshallian measures of consumer surplus was to develop four new welfare measures: equivalent surplus (ES), variation (Ev), compensating surplus and compensating variation. (CS) equivalent The Hicksian measures hold utility constant and "have been shown to be unique and ordinally related to utility changes" (Bergstrom, 1989: 217) These measures can be derived from the dual approach to consumer theory (Varian, 1992) THE CONSUMER'S DECISION PROBLEM The hunter's constrained optimization problem is to maximize utility subject to a budget constraint. His utility function is assumed to be strictly increasing, continuous and strictly quasi-concave (Varian, 1992). It is also assumed that the hunter's preferences are defined over the quantities of G and Q consumed. (1) maxU=U(G,Q) s.t. mP*G 10 where, U= utility G= endogenously determined vector of market goods p= price vector of the market goods Q= exogenously determined access to environmental services m= household income. The quantity of market goods is considered to be endogenously determined because the individual examines given prices and then chooses the quantities of goods to consume. The access to environmental services is, however, assumed to be exogenously rationed. The solution maximization to problem hunter's the is the constrained indirect utility utility function V(p,g,m). The indirect utility function describes the maximum level of utility obtainable at price vector p, environmental service vector q and income m. Assuming prices are fixed, the inverse of the utility function is the expenditure function, (2) ME(P,Q,U) The expenditure function in equation two is the minimum level of expenditure necessary to reach utility level U. the dual of the maximization problem. (3) This is Specifically, E(P, Q, U) =min.P*G s. t. U(G, Q) U' If the prices of market goods are assumed to be constant and utility is not allowed to change, then a change in the 11 environmental variable must result in a change in the nominal income. This change in nominal income will be the difference between two expenditure functions. Of the non-market valuation techniques, CVM is the most direct method for capturing this change in nominal income. Specifically, an individual could be asked how much he would either pay or accept in order to avoid or be compensated for a quantity or quality change in an environmental service. The choice of which measure to use depends on the presumed property rights. If the respondents are assumed to have the right to the pre-policy level of the environmental service (Q°), then the appropriate welfare measure is the Hicksian compensating measure (HC). With compensation equal to HC the hunter obtains utility level U° from the post-policy level of environmental service Q1 (Randall and Hoehn, 1987). (4) HC(Q°,Q1,U°)=M°-E(P,Q',U°) For an increment, the HC can be interpreted as willingness to pay to obtain the increase in Q (WTPc). For a decrement, the HC can be interpreted as the willingness to accept compensation for a reduction in access (WTAc-) (See Brookshire et al., 1987). If the respondent has the right to the subsequent level of well-being, the appropriate measure is equivalent measure (HE), where (5) HE(Q°,Q',U1)=M-E(p,Q°,u1) the Hicksian 12 With compensation equal to HE, the hunter attains utility level U1 at the pre-policy level of Q° (See Randall and Hoehn, 1987). For an increment, the HE can be interpreted as willingness to accept compensation to (WTAe+). For a decrement, forgo increased Q the HE can be interpreted as willingness to pay to avoid reductions in Q (WTPe-). Table 1 further illustrates the differences between the two Hicksian measures of welfare change. The table shows which levels of utility constant, are being held and the level of environmental service that the consumer ends up with, for the different money measures of welfare change. 13 TABLE 1. HICKS IAN MZASUP.ES OF WELFARE CHANGE Hicksian money measure of welfare change Reference level of utility Reference level of environmental services Income adjustment for increment in services (+) Income adjustment for decrement in services (-) compensa - tion measure U0 WTPc (+) WTAc (-) equivalent measure U1 WTAe() WTPe(-) ±errens, 14 Hicksian welfare measures are not only equivalent or compensating, but also surpluses or variations. With Hicksian variation measures, it is possible for the respondent to make optimizing adjustments. This is precluded in surplus measures (see Brookshire et al., 1980). THE THEORETICAL MODEL The following function is used to explain the welfare changes considered in this study. Explanatory variables include ability (ABIL), hours traveled (DH), (HRT), days hunted prior hunts on the Starkey (PRIOR), education (EDUC) and age (AGE). These variables capture differences in WTP due to differences in strengths of preference between individuals. The use of the hours travel variable in this analysis should not be confused with its use in travel cost analyses. Here it is only included to control for differences in preferences between individuals. In travel cost models, hours traveled data is often used to estimate the opportunity cost of time associated with travel to a recreation site. relationship between travel costs and visits estimated. A demand can then be The area under the calculated demand curve is the estimated consumer surplus. With CVM the consumer surplus is gleaned directly from the respondents. Consequently, in the CVM context the hours travel variable is only included as a measure of avidity. 15 Income (M) is included because for normal goods, income is positively correlated with willingness to pay (WTP). Q is included because it represents the exogenous change being valued. (6) WTP = f(M, ABIL, HRT, DH, PRIOR, EDUC, AGE, Q) where, M ABIL DH HRT PRIOR EDUC AGE Q = = = = = = = = household income hunting ability days spent hunting hours traveled to the site previous hunt on Starkey level of education age quantity or quality change in environmental service This function can be translated into Hicksian measures of welfare change (see Bergstrom, 1992). First, to make the discussion less cumbersome, six of the variables are combined to form a vector of socioeconomic variables called S where, S = (EDUC, AGE, HRT, DH, ABIL, PRIOR) Second, prices are assumed fixed and thus can be excluded from the arguments. The Hicksian welfare measure for willingness to pay to avoid the loss of hunting is then (7) HE(Q°,Q',U')=M-E(Q°,s, V(Q',S)) where HE is the Hicksian equivalent measure, Q° is the initial level of access to hunting, Q1 is no access to hunting for a year and V is the indirect utility associated with S and Q. 16 The Hicksian welfare measure for willingness to pay for an increased opportunity to harvest a deer or elk is (8) HC(Q',Q°, U°) =M-E(Q's, V(Q°,S)) where HC is the Hicksian compensating measure, Q° is the initial probability of harvesting an elk or deer and Q1 is the increased probability of harvesting an elk or deer. The individual's true willingness to pay is assumed to be an unobservable random variable. The true model corresponding to the individual hunter is (9) wTP1=f(x,u1) where, WTP = willingness to pay for the change in Q X = vector of explanatory variables = vector of coefficients on the explanatory variables u1= normally distributed error term. Under a linear specification, the estimated model with an open-ended elicitation technique would be WTP1 = Xt3, where ordinary least squares could be used to regress willingness to pay values on the explanatory variables. However, with dichotomous choice formats the WTP values must be inferred. This inference can be accomplished by assuming a distribution of the error terms and by translating the yes or no responses into probabilities. 17 In this study, a logistic distribution of the error terms is used for the following reasons. First, linear probability model can result in predictions less then 0 or greater than 1 which are outside of the range of possible probabilities. Second, because the logistic function is a close approximation of the normal function, the normally distributed error term assumption can be maintained (See Aldrich and Nelson, 1987). (10) The estimated logistic model is Pr(w=1) = P1 = [1 + exp(-Z(X,Tfl]1 where, W = 1 for a yes response and 0 for a no P1 = probability of obtaining a yes Z T X response = explanatory function = bid variable = explanatory variables. Prior to Cameron's approach to utilizing referendum data, researchers ran logistic regressions using "binary choice formulations" (1988:356) . With this formulation, researchers were only able to obtain measures of central tendency. However, because bids are varied across respondents, Cameron demonstrates how to model this additional information into a maximum likelihood procedure and derive WTP functions. procedure for straightforward. accomplishing this estimation The is The parameters of the explanatory variables from the censored logistic regression are divided by the coefficient on the bid variable. The logistic regression is "censored" because the valuations are censored to be "greater 18 than or less than" a threshold value (Cameron, 1988: 359). The bid variable and its coefficient are then excluded from the resulting willingness to pay function. willingness The estimated to pay function takes the form (11) WTPi=f(X) where X is the vector of explanatory variables minus the bid variable and is the vector of modified coefficients. 19 HYPOTHESES An advantage of deriving valuation functions (rather than point estimates) explanatory is the ability to test hypotheses on the variables. Besides formulating hypotheses concerning the explanatory variables, predictions are made concerning the signs of the coefficients on the bid variables in the logit regressions. The following sixteen hypotheses will be tested in this study. The welfare changes are measured as willingness to pay for a decrement in quality (WTPe-) in the first five hypotheses, as willingness to pay for an increment in quality (WTPc+) in the next six and as willingness to accept a decrement (WTAc-) in the last four hypotheses. HYPOTHESES SUPPOSITIONS aWTPe-/aINcoME > 0 Assuming that access to elk hunting is a normal good, increased income will result in increased willingness to pay. awTPe-/aPRI0R > 0 If individuals have hunted on the Starkey before, hunting there again indicates that they are obtaining their preferred choice. This is reflected in an increased willingness to pay for access to hunting. aPr(W=1)/aT < 0 If access to hunting is a normal good, the probability of a yes response will decline with increases in price. aWTPe-/aABIL > 0 Hunting ability reflects a greater investment in developing 20 hunting skills. Consequently, hunting ability is positively correlated with willingness to pay for hunting. awTPe-/aDH > The more time spent hunting the more likely a hunter is to obtain an elk. Consequently, the number of days spent hunting 0 is positively correlated with willingness to pay. awTPc+,a INCOME > 0 Assuming that increased harvesting opportunity is a normal good, increased income will result in willingness to pay. > awTPc+/aPRIOR 0 increased Because hunting on the Starkey is associated with higher success rates, hunters' choice to hunt on the Starkey reflects their strength of preference for of higher probabilities harvesting a deer or elk. apr(W=l)/ aT < 0 If increased opportunity of harvesting an elk is a normal good, the probability of receiving yes responses will decline with increases in price. awTPc+/aHTR > aWTPc/aDH < The number of hours traveled is an indication of the intensity of preferences for hunting. Consequently, hours traveled is positively correlated with willingness to pay. 0 The more time spent hunting, the likely a hunter is to obtain an elk. Consequently, the willingness to pay for increased elk numbers is negatively correlated with days spent hunting. 0 more awTPc/aABIL < 0 The greater the hunting ability, the more likely it is that a hunter will be successful in 21 harvesting an elk. Consequently, the less he is willing to pay for increased elk populations. aWTAc-/aINCOME > 0 Although this relationship seems clear for the WTP variables it is much more ambiguous for the willingness to accept variables. However, since the marginal utility of income is highest for those individuals with the least income, they should also be willing to sell for the least. awTAc-,aPRIoR < 0 If individuals have hunted on the Starkey before, hunting there again indicates that they are obtaining their preferred choice. This is reflected in a positive correlation between WTA and Prior. aPr(w=1),aT > awTAc-IaABIL The higher the bid, the greater the probability that it will be accepted. 0 > 0 Hunting ability reflects a greater investment in developing hunting skills. The higher the hunting ability the greater amount an individual would have to be paid to forgo hunting. awTAc-/aDH > 0 The more time spent hunting, the a hunter is to more likely obtain an elk. Consequently, the number of days spent hunting is positively correlated with willingness to accept. 22 III. EMPIRICAL APPLICATION The preceding chapter developed the theoretical framework for the empirical model. chapter This discusses the application of that framework to the valuation of elk hunting. Specifically, a preview of potential problems and a context for interpreting the results are provided through a discussion of the survey instrument, the elicitation formats and data characteristics. THE STARKEY SJRVEYS The Starkey Experimental Forest and Range, located 28 miles southwest of La Grande on the Wallowa-Jhjtman National Forest, was established in 1940 as a Forest research area. In 1987 researchers enclosed 25,000 acres of the Starkey with 38 miles of cattle, deer and elk proof fence. uto test animal response to various This was done forest, range, and recreational activities, and to changes in habitat caused by those activities N (USFS - ODFW, 1989). As part of this research effort, controlled hunts of elk and deer are conducted within the enclosure. The hunts are used by researchers to change the size and composition of deer and elk populations on the Starkey and to examine how deer and elk respond to hunting pressure. The hunters are thus an integral part of the research effort. A total of ten surveys from eleven hunts (the two antlerless 1989 elk hunts were combined and are considered as 23 one hunt) have been conducted by the Oregon Department of Fish and Wildlife (ODFW) and the U.S. Forest Service (USFS). of these ten hunts were elk hunts (see table 1). Seven Because of the small sample sizes for the deer hunts, only elk hunts are considered here. 24 TABLE 2. SU)*ARY INFORMATION FOR THE STARKEYa HUNT 1988 1988 1988 1989 1989 1989 1989 1990 1990 1990 1991 1991 1991 a b DATE Either-Sex Bull Elk Bull Elk Bull Elkb Either-Sex Antlerless Antlerless Bull Elk Buck Deer Antlerless Bull Elk Buck Deer Antlerless Deerb Deer Elk Elk Elk Elk Oct Oct Nov Sept Sept Dec Dec Aug Sept Dec Aug Sept HUNTERS(No.) HARVEST(No.) 1-Oct 12 30 5-Nov 13 26 - Oct 2 - Sept 10 30 - Oct 11 9-Dec 15 30 - Jan 18 - Aug 29 - Oct 1-Dec 17 - Aug 28 - Oct Nov 30-Dec 7 26 10 7 25 4 6 118 98 99 10 87 63 28 172 25 92 152 24 132 The above statistics were supplied by Mike Wisdom; U.S. Forest Service - La Grande No survey data were collected for this hunt. 82 50 49 3 61 33 9 51 8 61 45 9 64 25 SURVEY DESIGN AND ADMINISTPATION All of the Starkey survey instruments were developed and administered by the U.S. Forest Service and the Oregon Department of Fish and Wildlife Service and included WTPe, WTPc and WTAc questions. The surveys were mailed to all individuals who obtained elk tags for hunting on the Starkey. Surveys were also available at the entrance to the Starkey Forest. Individuals then deposited their completed surveys at the entrance to the controlled hunt area. Additional survey forms were also available so that individuals who did not bring their surveys with them could fill them out before beginning their hunt. A total of ten hunts were surveyed over a four year period. Response rates to the ten hunts surveyed are listed in Table 2. 26 TABLE 3. RESPONSE RATES FOR THE STARKEY StRVEYS Survey 1 2 3 4 6 5 7 8 10 9 Elk Elk Elk Deer Elk Elk Deer Elk Elk Deer 1988 1988 1989 1989 1990 1990 1990 1991 1991 1991 (Oct) (Nov) (Dec) Hunters 98 99 91 (Aug) (Dec) 87 172 92 2 (Aug) (Dec) 152 132 24 (No.) Observ.a 85 86 42 74 149 82 23 Response 87 Rate 87 46 85 87 89 92 144 95 109 20 83 83 (%) Total : 814/972 = 84% a Returned surveys with a response to at least one question. 27 The two surveys administered in 1988 differ from each other and from subsequent surveys. One difference between the 1988 and 1989 questionnaires was the replacement of the "openended't valuation questions with "iterative bidding" questions. The only difference between subsequent surveys (post 1988) is the level of the bid within each season. reported in table 4. The bids are 28 TABLE 4. BID LEVELS BY GROUP FOR THE DC STAREEY SURVEYSa ype of Hunt Group A ($) Deer Elk 25 50 Group B ($) 50 100 a DC refers to dichotomous choice. Group ($) 100 250 C Group D ($) 200 500 29 POTENTIAL SOT3RCES OF BIAS As discussed in Chapter 1, there are several potential sources of bias in contingent valuation. With open-ended questions, respondents may attempt to influence the outcome of the survey, valuation. thus introducing strategic bias into the In addition, respondents frequently have difficulty in assigning values to commodities for which they have limited points of reference, i.e., no previous experience in valuing the commodity in question. This can lead to increased numbers of nonresponses and\or unreliable responses. The dichotomous choice method used in the post-1989 surveys was designed to provide a more realistic contingent market scenario and to avoid strategic bias. Respondents may, however, feel compelled to "comply with the presumed expectation of the sponsor" (Mitchell and Carson, 1989: 236). Another potential problem with the referendum method, when compared with the iterated referendum method, is its inefficiency. The iterated referendum method has the potential for reducing the size of the variance in the valuation estimates (Mitchell and Carson, 1989: 103). The iterated responses are, however, still susceptible to compliance bias. Additionally, there is the possibility of starting point bias if an individual's response to the second bid is influenced by his response to the first bid. By their nature, contingent valuation analyses also have the potential for hypothetical bias. 30 One reason to expect less bias in the Starkey surveys is that the hunters are informed prior to the hunt that they are expected to participate in the Starkey research program. Hunters surveyed without such prior information might be more inclined towards dismissing the surveys or responding with less care. The high response rates on the Starkey surveys (average of 84 percent) reduces the potential for sampling bias such as the self-censoring of nonrespondents (see Edwards and Anderson, 1987). Edwards and Anderson also discuss the potential for bias due to the censoring of protest responses (p. 168) There is a potential for this type of bias in the Starkey surveys. Although the written responses of individuals on the open-ended elicitations were recorded, unusually high bids were censored, and none of the surveys provide a means to record protest responses. DATA ANALYSIS Data from the 1989, 1990 and 1991 hunts are combined to create one elk data set. Durmny variables corresponding to each hunt were then utilized to control for differences between hunts. Four of the seven elk hunts (1988 hunt 1, 1988 hunt 2, 1990 hunt 1, 1991 hunt 1) were for bull (antlered) elk and the other three were for antlerless elk. Additionally, dummy variables were used to test for differences in willingness to pay associated with differences between years. 31 No significant differences were found. Consequently these variables were not included in the final model. Because the open-ended elicitation format used in 1988 differed from the iterative bid format used in 1989, 1990 and 1991, data from the 1988 surveys are not pooled. The iterative bid format used in the Starkey Survey is referred to by Mitchell and Carson as "the take-it-or-leave-it with follow up" approach (1989: 98). Only the take-it-or-leave-it portion of the survey is considered here. Table 4 shows how individuals responded to the dichotomous choice questions on the elk surveys. 32 TABLE 5. PERCENTAGE OF YES RESPONSES BY GROUP FOR THE DC SURVEYSa Welfare Measure Group A Group B Group C (%W=1 T=50) (W=1 T=100) (%W=1 T=200) (1989-90-91) (1989-90-91) (1989-90-91) Group D (W=1 T=500) (1989-90-91) ACC INC (WTPe-) 63 . 0 49.6 28.5 19.0 ELKP (WTPc) 63.6 41.5 21.7 7.5 prjNTpb 0.0 1.8 11.3 17.3 5.1 18 . 0 30.2 36.1 (WTAc) HUNTPS (WTAc) a b Percentage of yes responses from the total of yes and no responses. Missing responses are not included in the total. DC refers to dichotomous choice. Data for 1989 are missing for this variable. Where: ACC INC = ELKP= HtJNTP= HIJNTPS = Yes or no response on bid amount, 1=yes Bid amount Willingness to pay to avoid not hunting Willingness to for pay increased opportunity to harvest an elk. Willingness to accept payment to give up hunting for the year. Willingness to accept payment to give tp hunting at the Starkey for a year. 33 The correlations between the percentage of yes responses to the WTP and WTA questions and the size of the bids is consistent with economic theory respectfully) for normal goods. (positive and negative, In addition, the respondents are differentiating between what they are willing to pay for hunting Starkey and hunting in general. The data in table 4 also indicate a problem with the bid structure used for the WTA and WTP variables. For the WTA variables, the range of bids only captures a small percentage of the potential bids. This is particularly apparent for the HUNTP variable where no positive responses were received for the lowest bid and the highest bid results in only 17 percent positive responses. The reduction in the number of missing responses between the 1988 and later surveys (see table 5) indicates that changing the format had the desired effect. however, two cautions that need to be considered. valuation questions on the 1988 There are, First, the open-ended surveys are different than the ones on the dichotomous choice survey. Second, there was no place on the dichotomous choice survey to indicate a protest response. Although it is not possible to isolate the protest responses from other responses on the open-ended surveys, some respondents to the open-ended questionnaire listed "not for sale" as their response. A "not for sale" category is often included in the possible responses to valuation questions on CVM surveys. In future surveys, 34 including this category may provide useful information about the extent and nature of the protest vote. 35 TABLE 6. MISSING RESPONSES TO VALUATION QUESTIONS SURVEY 1 2 3 Elk 1988 Elk 1988 Elk 1989 (Oct) (Nov) (Dec) 4 Elk 1990 5 Elk 1990 6 Elk 199]. (Aug) (Aug) 7 Elk 1991 (Dec) VARIABLE a ACCINC (%) ELKP OR 47b HUNTP 24.7b (%) HUNTPS a 454b 70b 430b 360b 14.3 4.0 7.3 7.6 6.4 9.5 3.3 3.3 1.2 1.2 4.2 3.5 3.7 5.5 4.7 1.2 3.5 4.6 a (%) a This information was not collected for this data set. b Outliers are included in the missing response categories. 36 IV. RESULTS AND IMPLICATIONS This chapter begins with a discussion of the results from the logistic regressions and benefit functions, and concludes with some methodological and policy implications. The results from the willingness to pay variables (ACCINC and and the willingness to accept variables ELKP) HUNTPS) are discussed separately. (HtJNTP and This separation of the discussion between the two elicitation formats (WTP and WTA) facilitates the interpretation of the signs on the estimated coefficients from the logit models. THE WTP MODELS The question associated with the ACCINC variable reads: Would you choose not to hunt at all in 1990 if total costs increased by ? The results of the Starkey surveys are interpreted as if the question had been, Would you choose to hunt at all in 1990 if total costs increased by ? By making this change, the responses can be discussed in the traditional willingness to pay fashion. A yes response thus corresponds to an individual's willingness to pay the bid amount. The question associated with the ELKP variable reads, If the number of animals were sufficient to make it virtually certain that you would have an opportunity to shoot at an elk/deer, would you be willing to pay additional to hunt? 37 The Logit Regressions Tables 6 and 7 present model specifications, goodness of fit measures, sample sizes and significance measures for the two willingness to pay logit regressions. The logarithmic specification used for the ACCINC and ELKP models has the advantage of allowing only positive willingness to pay values. Theoretical support for the use of the logarithmic specifications is provided by Johansson, Kristoom and Maler and Bowker and Stoll (1989) who argue that the (1988) logarithmic specification can be considered a first-order approximation to a well-behaved indirect utility function (Park et. al., 1991). Following Learner (1983) different specifications can be examined to test the robustness of the coefficients in the models. Learner advocates testing the robustness of a model by seeing if the results change when different specifications are attempted. robust, with The ACCINC and ELKP model specifications are the only sign change occurring for the coefficient on the AD2 variable in the ELKP model. The robustness of both models is also reflected in their respective goodness of fit measures. The McFadden R2 of .13 and the percentage of correct predictions of 74 for the ACCINC model are similar to those obtained in related studies. Creel For example, Park, Loomis and (1991) obtained a Mcfadden R2 of .13 and a percent correct predictions of 71 with a similar logit model (p. 68). 38 Both models use the Hicksian equivalent surplus welfare measure, assume a logistic distribution of errors and use a logarithmic model specification. The goodness of fit statistics for the ELKP model are better than those for the ACCINC model and related Park, Creel and Loomis model. A McFadden R2 of .12 and a percent of correct predictions of 63 were obtained in the Park study, whereas the ELKP model has a McFadden R2 of percentage of correct predictions of 81. .22 and a The difference in the goodness of fit statistics between the ACCINC and ELKP models reflects the more appropriate bid structure used for the ELKP question (see table 4). Besides the measures of goodness of fit and robustness, the sample sizes and likelihood ratio tests provide evidence of the statistical properties of the two models. The sample size of 401 for the ACCINC model and of 413 for the ELKP model fall within the range of sample sizes in related studies (see Whitehead and Blomquist, 1991; Park, Loomis and Creel, 1991). Current research by Cameron and Huppert (1991) evidence that the results from censored regressions are provides particularly sensitive to the size of the sample. The likelihood ratio test (comparable to the F test for OLS models) indicates that the coefficients of the explanatory variables are different from zero at the .001 level of 39 significance for both models. The coefficients on the bid variables are also significant at the 99 percent confidence level. 40 TABLE 7. RESULTS FROM THE LOGIT MODEL: INCREASED COST OF HUNTING (ACCINC) ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTSa VARIABLES Intercept 34062b (.9076) Log of the Bid (LNT) _.8651b (.1337) Income (DY1) .6925b (.2546) Log of Hours Traveled 3245b (.1467) (LNHTR) Ability 1 (AD1) .1549 (.3137) Ability 2 (AD2) .8432 (.4518) Log of Days Hunt (LNDH) -.1865 (.2861) Prior Hunt (DPHS) -.0971 (.2423) Age (DAGE) .1000 (.2536) Education (DEDUC) .0422 (.2484) Hunt 2 1989 (HUNE89) -.1012 (.4536) Hunt 1 1990 (HtJNEA9O) -.4555 (.3075) Hunt 2 1990 (HUNE9O) -.6016 (.3623) Hunt 2 1991 (HtJNE91) -.3759 (.3308) 401 Likelihood Ratio Teste Percent Correct Pred. McFadden R2 73 74 .13 a Asymptotic standard errors in parentheses. Asymptotically significant at the 95 percent confidence b level. C The likelihood ratio test indicates that the coefficients are significant at the 99 percent confidence level. 41 TABLE 8 RESULTS FROM THE LOGIT MODEL: INCREASED OPPORTUNITY TO SHOOT AT AN ELK (ELKP) VARIABLES ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTSa Intercept 59998b (1.0270) _13522b (.1593) .7683b (.2771) .2370 (.1593) Log of the Bid (LNT) Income (DY1) Log of Hours Traveled (LNHTR) Ability 1 (AD1) Ability 2 .2940 (.3430) .9512 (.4848) _6404b (.3086) -.2452 (.2614) .3273 (.2778) .0776 (.2678) -.5550 (.4949) .0949 (.3296) -.7267 (.3943) -.5598 (.3646) (AD2) Log of Days Hunt (LNDH) Prior Hunt (DPHS) Age (DAGE) Education (DEDUC) Hunt 2 1989 (HUNE89) Hunt 1 1990 (HUNEA9O) Hunt 2 1990 (HUNE9O) Hunt 2 1991 (HtJNE91) 413 Likelihood Ratio Testc 118 Percent Correct Pred. 81 McFadden R2 .22 a Asymptotic standard errors in parenthesis. b Asymptotically significant at the 95 percent confidence level. The likelihood ratio test indicates that the coefficients are significant at the 99% confidence level. 42 The negative signs on the coefficients of both bid variables conforms to the expectation that the probability of a yes response decreases (increases) as the price (bid) willingness to pay increases (decreases). The Valuation Functions The logit equations are rescaled into functions by multiplying the constant term and all the slope parameters (except for the coefficient on the bid variable) 1988), by k (Cameron, where: The k=-1/a and a=the coefficient on the bid variable willingness to pay functions for the variables ACCINC and ELKP are, ACCINC: (12) 1nWTP= 3.94 + .80(DY1) + .37(LNHTR) + .18(AD1) + (.72)* (.31)* .97(AD2) (.54) .05(DEDUC) (.29) (.17)* (.36) -.21(LNDH) - .11(DPHS) + .12(DAGE) (.28) (.29) (.33) - .12(HUNE89) -.69(HUNE9O) (.52) (.42) .53(HTJNEA9O) -.43(HUNE91) (.36) (.38) and, ELKP: (13) 1nWTP= 4.44 + .57(DY1) + 17(LNHTR) + .22(AD1) + (.48)* (.21)* (.12) (.25) .70(AD2) - .47(LNDH) - .18(DPHS) + .24(DAGE) + (.36) (.23) (.19) (.20) .06(DEDUC) -.41(HtJNE89) + .07(HTJNEA9O) (.20) (.37) (.24) .54(HtJNE9O) -.41(HUNE91) (.29) (.27) 43 where the standard errors are in parentheses and * denotes significance at the .05 level. The anti-logs of the fitted values are medians (Cameron, 1988). The average of these medians is $113 for the ACCINC model and $90 for the ELKP model. Because the valuation functions are geometric, measures such as the arithmetic mean are inappropriate. Arithmetic means are the expected values of linear functions. Consequently, there is no reason to presume that the expected value of any other functional form will correspond to the arithmetic mean. Both Cameron (1988) and Hanemann (1984) discuss the use of scaling factors that can be used to find the expected values of functions with logistic error distributions. log-linear The equations used by Cameron and Hanemann are, (14) where: F(]. - k)r(1 + k)=(fl/a)/(sin(U/a)) k = -1/a a = coefficient on the bid variable. From the scaling factor equations in (14) it is clear that the absolute value of the coefficient on the bid variable must be greater than one for the scaling factor to be defined. Because the coefficient on the bid variable for the ACCINC model is - .8651 and the coefficient on the bid variable for the ELKP model is -1.3522, the scaling factor is only defined for the ELKP model. The mean of the fitted values for the ELKP model is then estimated by first multiplying the scaling 44 factor times the fitted values and then dividing the sum of these values by the sample size. The resulting mean value of $287 is more than 3 times the value of the calculated median and is clear evidence of a skewed distribution of the willingness to pay values. The skewed distribution of the WTP values is consistent with the choice of a log-logistic model. The standard errors in equations (12) and (13) were derived using the following Taylor series approximation, var(P) =[yj/a2] var(a) +(-1/a] var(yj) (15) + 2[y/a2] a where: [-1/a] COV(U,yj) = coefficient on the bid variable and = coefficient on the explanatory variable The variable which is most significant in the ACCINC and ELKP models is the income dummy variable (DY1). The coefficients on the DY1 variable are significant at the 99 percent confidence level in both models. The income question on the Starkey surveys includes six categories. These categories, varied by increments of $10,000, are u<10,000,N "10,000 - 19,999," "20,000 - 29,999," "30,000 -39,999," "40,000 - 49,999" and ">50,000." Although there are only 23 responses on the low end (<10,000), there are 119 responses on the high end (>50,000). Clearly, additional variation could have been captured by increasing the number of categories on the high end. The dummy variable, 45 DY1 represents income above $29,999. The positive sign on the coefficients of this variable indicates that willingness to pay increases (decreases) with increases (decreases) in an individual's income, as expected. The other significant variable in the ACCINC valuation function is LNHTR (log of hours traveled to the Starkey). The positive correlation of this variable with willingness to pay indicates a higher preference for elk hunting among those traveled a greater distance. individuals who A low correlation coefficient (.05) between the DY1 and LNHTR indicates that this result is not due to collinearity. LNDH (log of the expected number of days that the respondent will spend elk hunting) is also significant in the ELKP valuation function. The negative correlation of this variable with WTP indicates a lower preference for increased elk numbers among individuals who spend more days elk hunting. Time spent hunting is a substitute for elk numbers (i.e. the hunter with more time can "produce' his own elk). THE WTA MODELS There are two WTA questions on the survey. The first is: If you could still hunt somewhere else during the general season, would you accept a payment of from someone else and give up your hunting privilege on Starkey this year? The second WTA question is: If someone would pay you to completely give up your hunting privilege this year (Starkey AND elsewhere), would you give it up for ? 46 The Logit Regress ions Tables 9 and 10 summarize the results from the willingness to accept logit regressions. Although willingness to accept valuation questions are less common than willingness to pay questions, Brookshire, Randall and Stoll (1980) use a WTA format to estimate values associated with changes in the quality of elk hunting experiences. In comparing the observed WTA values against WTA values derived from the WTP values, they found that observed WTA values were significantly different from and up to an order of magnitude greater than, derived WTAN (p. 487). Such a divergence between WTA and WTP occurs in the Starkey models. However, because the bid amounts for the Starkey WTP and WTA questions were the same, the bid levels were too low to capture most of the variation (see table 4). The lack of positive responses reduces the usefulness of percent correct predictions as a measure of goodness of fit. The Mcfadden R2 (.23 and .16) measurements compare favorably with those found by Park, Creel and Loomis and Whitehead and Blomquist (.12 and .13). The coefficients on both the HUNTP and HtJNTPS models are also significantly different from zero at the 99 percent confidence level. Additionally, all the coefficients are robust, with no sign changes occurring for different specifications. 47 TABLE 9. RESTJTJTS FROM THE LOGIT MODEL: WILLINGNESS TO ACCEPT PAYMENT TO FORGO HUNTING (HUNTP) ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTSa VARIABLES _83282b (2.0713) Intercept 15847b (.3564) Log of the Bid (LNT) .4956 (.4907) Income (DY1) Log of Hours Traveled -.1257 (.2542) (LNHTR) Ability 1 (AD1) -.6302 (.4752) Ability 2 (AD2) -.2236 (.8789) _13g55b (.5181) Log of Days Hunt (LNDH) Prior Hunt (DPHS) -.9248 (.4969) Age (DAGE) .6927 (.4982) Education (DEDUC) -.1138 (.4568) Hunt 1 1990 (HUNEA9O) -.4639 (.5230) Hunt 2 1990 (HUNE9O) -1.1596 (.6898) Hunt 2 1991 (HUNE91) -.7132 (.6446) Likelihood Ratio Testc Percent Correct Pred. McFadden R2. a 378 48 85 .23 Asymptotic standard errors in parenthesis. b Asymptotically significant at the 95 percent confidence level. C The likelihood ratio test indicates that the coefficients are significant at the 99 percent confidence level. 48 TABLE 10. RESULTS FROM THE LOGIT MODEL: WILLINGNESS TO ACCEPT PAYMENT TO FORGO HUNTING ON THE STARZEY (HtINTPS) ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTS VARIABLES _37573b (1.0273) 9486b (.1639) .4758 (.2985) _3331b (.1636) Intercept Log of the Bid (LNT) Income (DY1) Log of Hours Traveled (LNHTR) Ability 1 (AD1) Ability 2 -.3823 (.3278) -.2100 (.5483) _7847b (.3077) -.3846 (.2874) -.3737 (.2883) .1449 (.2854) (AD2) Log of Days Hunt (LNDH) Prior Hunt (DPHS) Age (DAGE) Education (DEDtJC) Hunt 2 1989 (HtJNE89) Hunt 1 1990 (HUNEA9O) Hunt 2 1990 (HEJNE9O) Hunt 2 1991 (HtJNE91) Likelihood Ratio Testc Percent Correct Pred. McFadden R2 _1.4522b (.6898) -.6784 (.3490) -.6589 (.4053) -.3623 (.3773) 413 70 77 .16 a Asymptotic standard errors in parenthesis. ID Asymptotically significant at the 95 percent confidence level. The likelihood ratio test indicates that the coefficients are significant at the 99 percent confidence level. 49 The Valuation Functions The valuation functions for the HIJNTP and HUNTPS variables are, HUNTP: 1nWTA= 5.25 - .31(DY1) + .08(LNHTR) + .40(AD1) + (.63)* (.31) (.16) (.31) .14(AD2) .88(LNDH) + .58(DPHS) - .44(DAGE) + (.56) (33)* (.33) + .29(HUNEA9O) .07(DEDtJC) (.29) .45(HtJNE91) + (.32) .73(HtJNE9O) (.44) (.33) + (.42) and, HtJNTPS: 1nWTA= 3.96 - .50(DY1) + .35(LNHTR) + .40(AD1) + (.69)* (.32) (.18) (.35) .22(AD2) + .83(LNDH) + .40(DPHS) + (34)* (.58) .39 (DAGE) (.31) - .15 (DEDUC) (.30) + (.31) .72 (HUNEA9 0) (.38) + 1.53(HUNE89) + .69(HUNE9O) + .40(HtJNE91) (.76)* (.44) (.40) where the standard errors are in parentheses and * denotes significance at the .05 level. The median for HUNTP is approximately $1,634, and for HUNTPS it is approximately $1,105. The median for HUNTP is more than fifteen times the median value for ACCINC. Although this divergence appears high, Mitchell and Carson (1989) report divergences of 1000 percent in some CVM studies. The mean of the fitted values of the HUNTP model can be determined because the bid coefficient of 1.6 is greater than 1 (Hanemann, 1984). The HUNTP mean of indicates that this distribution is skewed. $3,529 clearly 50 Because the coefficient on the bid variable for the HUNTPS model is less than 1, the mean value is undefined. relative ranking of these WTA values is as expected. words, The In other the lower median value of $1,105 for HUNTPS model conforms to the expectation that individuals would sell their Starkey-specific recreational experience for less than they would sell their right to hunt. The coefficient on the variable LNDH (log of days hunted) is significant at the 99 percent level. The days hunted variable reflects the number of days an individual plans to hunt in a given year. The coefficient on this variable indicates that the more days an individual hunts, the more he will have to be paid to forgo this experience. the coefficient on the HTJNE89 Additionally, (1989 antlerless elk hunt) variable is significant at the 95 percent level in the HtJNTPS valuation equation (17). The positive correlation between the HUNTPS coefficient and WTA indicates that participants in this hunt were less willing to sell their right to hunt on the Starkey then participants in other hunts. Interestingly, income, which is significant in both of the WTP models, is not significant in the WTA models. Hunters are bound by their income constraints when responding to the willingness to pay question but not when responding to the willingness to accept question. At the extreme, a hunter with a $1 income could pay a maximum of $1 but could accept any amount. 5]- Hanemann (1991) has also shown that for valuations of quantity or quality changes the WTA values substitution as well as an income effect. reflect a Thus, Hanemann explains large differences between the WTP and WTA values by arguing that the "private-market goods available in their choice set are collectively a rather imperfect substitute for the public good under consideration" (p. 646). IMPLICATIONS The research findings reported methodological and policy implications. are four policy implications and above have Specifically, there three methodological implications that may be gleaned from this research. methodological implications are: Demonstrating the flexibility of WTP functions over point estimates. Confirming the importance of using unambiguous and specific wording when specifying the attributes of the commodity being valued. Confirming the importance of using a pretest to establish the initial ranges and number of bids in dichotomous choice CVM survey. both The 52 The policy implications are: The hunting recreational experience is providing substantial benefits conservative estimate to hunters. Starkey (using A the median fitted value from the ACCINC model) of the net benefits per hunter is $113. Starkey hunters are willing to pay additional costs to increase the elk herd to the point where they are virtually guaranteed a shot at an elk. estimated value for this increment The in quality, using the mean of the fitted values from the ELKP model, is $287 per hunter. The willingness to pay values are affected by the size of the respondents' incomes. For example, hunters who fall within the income category 29,999) have a mean fitted value (0- (for the ELKP variable) of $179, and hunters with higher incomes have a mean fitted value of $345. Starkey hunters object to the tradeoff between their right to hunt and private goods. The apparent objection to this tradeoff could result in opposition to any efforts to privatize this resource. 53 The following discussion attempts to integrate both policy and methodological implications. Additionally, because the policy implications from the WTP and WTA models differ, the original separation between these two elicitation formats is maintained. Implications From the WTP Models The importance of using specific language in describing the contingent scenario is illustrated by the problems encountered in the interpretation and modeling of the ACCINC data. Because the ACCINC question includes the general category "hunting" instead of the more specific "elk hunting," it is difficult to identify the attributes of the commodity being valued. For example, some hunters may have answered the ACCINC question as if it referred only to elk hunting, while others may have thought it referred to their entire bundle of hunting experiences. Placing a value on the entire bundle of hunting experiences is a much more complicated exercise than valuing a specific hunting experience. In contrast, the ELKP question specifically mentions elk hunting. The difficulty experienced by hunters in formulating a response to the ACCINC question is reflected in the percent of missing values (see table 5). The proportion of missing values for ACCINC is 11 percent, whereas for the ELKP variable it is only 4 percent. The goodness of fit statistics for the ACCINC model are also the lowest of all the models. 54 Another methodological implication of this study is the importance of carefully choosing the number and range of bids Ideally, the range and on dichotomous choice CVM studies. nunther of the bids is structured so that it captures most of the variation in valuation estimates. Specifically, the more variation that is captured between the lowest and highest bid levels, the greater the explanatory power of the model. In this study, only four dichotomous bids are used and One result of this choice of the range is from $50 to $500. bids is that 19 percent of the respondents voted for the highest bid level. Boyle and Bishop experienced a (1988) similar problem in their CVM analysis of boaters in Wisconsin. They concluded that the initial selection of bid ranges Hcan affect final value estimates (p. 25). pretesting avoid as a way to inappropriateness of bid ranges. They go on to suggest problems with the With the ELKP variable, only 7 percent of the respondents voted for the $500 bid level. Problems with the appropriateness of the bid ranges and ambiguous wording in the ACCINC question are reflected in the lack of a defined mean for the fitted values. Hanemann (1984) suggests that the median is an appropriate measure of net willingness to pay because of its robustness and lack of sensitivity to outliers. McFadden (1992), however, points out that the median is a biased estimator of central tendency when the distribution of WTP estimates is not symmetric. McFadden 55 further argues that most CVM studies result in nonsymmetric estimates of WTP and consequently have median values that are downwardly biased estimates of the true mean. In this context the median may be viewed as a conservative estimate of the current net economic use value of elk hunting. However, serious problems with the bid structure and a lack of specificity in the contingent scenario reduce the usefulness of the $113 figure. McFadden's argument that the medians are downwardly biased estimates of the true mean is supported by the CVM studies where the means are approximately 100 percent larger then the medians (see Boyle and Bishop, 1988; Kahneman and Knetsch, 1991). A large difference between the mean and the median is also found in a study by Loomis, Cooper and Allen (1988). The Loomis, Cooper and Allen study is similar to this study in that it assumes a logistic distribution of the error terms, uses a logaritbmic functional model specification and elicits values for elk hunting. The estimated mean for the Loomis, Cooper and Allen "ELKP-type model" larger than the median. difference This compares used closely to the (3.2 times larger) between the mean and median fitted values obtained for the ELKP model. is is 3.1 times only to illustrate the This comparison similarity in skewed distributions of WTP estimates, not to compare the valuation estimates. 56 A comparison between the valuations studies in is complicated by differences in the wording of the questions, the choice of welfare measure, the method used to calculate net willingness to pay estimates, and the sample population. For this study, the sample population is hunters who received elk tags specific a controlled hunt to at the Starkey The 38 miles of elk proof Experimental Forest. fence surrounding the area and an average success rate of 43 percent (1988-1990) illustrate the unique nature of this hunt. The average success rate for elk hunting in Oregon is 16 percent (1988-1990) Although both WTP were questions not specifically targeted at the Starkey, hunters who choose the Starkey on their applications may not be statistically representative of hunters who choose other areas. Additionally, the respondents' high expectations for their hunting experience on Starkey could bias the their valuation estimates. Consequently, it is preferable to obtain estimates specific to a particular area. The transferability contingent method Cameron of the valuations. does, results Unlike however, from increase dichotomous studies where the choice numerical integration techniques are used to derive point estimates of net willingness to pay, the Cameron method can be used to derive functions from the logistic regressions. These functions can then be transferred to other areas where new 57 location-specific values explanatory variables. can be used as values for the Using a function instead of point estimates makes it possible to control for differences in hunter attributes such as income. Benefit transfer studies, such as the one by Sorg and Loomis (1984), typically do not adjust estimated values for differences in hunter incomes across samples. Although the $287 mean of the fitted values for the ELKP variable is not as transferable as the function, this point estimate does have policy implications. Clearly, the willingness (at least among Starkey hunters) to pay additional money for the increased opportunity to shoot at an elk indicates a preference for increased elk numbers. The $287 figure thus gives managers and decision makers an idea of the magnitude of the preferences for increases in the elk herd size. Another policy implication of this research is that equity concerns should be considered when pursuing revenue enhancing policies such as increases in elk tag fees. policy implication follows from the sensitivity of This net willingness to pay values to income levels. To estimate the importance of the income explanatory variable in explaining net willingness to pay, the data set was split into two subsets. The first subset includes only those observations where respondents have incomes lower than $29,999; the second subset includes only those individuals 58 with incomes above $29,999. The valuation functions are then used to derive the average medians and means of the fitted values for the subsets. Table 10 shows that the median and mean of the fitted values for the ELKP model almost double between income categories. Additionally, the median for the ACCINC variable more than doubles between income categories. The differences in willingness to pay for different income levels indicates that the population of Starkey hunters is heterogenous in regard to income. The heterogeneity of the population of Starkey hunters is also demonstrated by the significance of the hours travel variable in the ACCINC model and days hunt variable in the ELKP model. The coefficient of .37 on the LNHTR variable in the ACCINC equation (12), and the coefficient of .47 percent on the LNDH variable in the ELKP equation (13), can be interpreted as elasticities. Thus, both LNHTR and LNDH are inelastic with a 1 percent change in LNHTR (LNDH), resulting in an estimated .37 percent (.47 percent) change in the respondents' willingness to pay. 59 TABLE 11. ESTIMITED MEDIAN AND MEAN WTP AND WTA VALUES FOR DIFFERENT INCOME LEVELS INCOME LEVELS AVERAGE OF FITTED MEDIAN VALUES ACCINC AVERAGE OF FITTED MEDIAN VALUES ELKP ($) ($) AVERAGE OF FITTED MEAN VALUES ELKP ($) Income All 113 90 287 Income 58 56 179 141 108 345 (0-29, 999) Income (>29,999 60 Implications From the WTA Models CVM researchers have long struggled with the size of values generated from WTA models (see Mitchell and Carson, 1989; Brookshire, Randall and Stoll, 1980; Hanemann, 1991; Randall and Hoehn, 1987). This study is no exception, with median fitted values of $1,634 and $1,105 for the HUNTP and HUNTPS variables and $3,529 for the mean on the ELKP fitted values. Prior to Hanemann's theoretical research (1991) the tendency of CVM practitioners was to dismiss the WTA formats as inappropriate for the particular commodity being valued (see Brookshire, Randall and Stoll, 1980). Randall and Stoll (1980) show how WTA values can be calculated from WTP values (for quantity changes) by modifying Willig's (1976) calculations (for price changes). They demonstrate that a necessary component for translating WTP values into WTA values is the "price flexibility of income." Hanemann then takes the Randall and Stoll theoretical formulation a step further by showing how the price flexibility can be further decomposed into an income and substitution elasticity. The size of the difference between the WTP and WTA values is then inversely related to the size of the elasticity of substitution between the public commodity and private goods. In this thesis, it is not possible to differentiate between the substitution and income effects. Estimating the income effects is complicated by the discrete nature of both 61 the income variable and the change being valued (hunting to not hunting). Additionally, problems associated with the bid structure for the ACCINC variable would cloud the results of any attempt to obtain income effects. The supposition that the elasticity of substitution between elk hunting and private goods (for Starkey hunters) is less than one is thus an intuitive one. Mitchell and Carson (1989) argue that the Randall and Stoll (1980) bounds suggest that WTP and WTA measures should be "within 5% of each for most other Consequently, it contingent appears valuation income studies" effects alone (p. are 32). not sufficient to explain the divergences between these measures. The WTA models also demonstrates the importance of including variables for days hunted and hours traveled in hunting valuation analyses. In the HTJNTP and HUNTPS models, a 1 percent increase in the number of days spent hunting elk causes an estimated .88 percent increase in the amount hunters are willing to accept as payment for hunting and a .83 percent increase in the amount hunters are willingness to accept as payment for hunting on the Starkey. The derived valuation functions from the WTP and WTA elicitations indicate that the population of hunters applying for elk tags to hunt on the Starkey are heterogeneous in income, days hunt and\or hours traveled. Additionally, including both WTA and WTP elicitations on surveys can provide valuable information on how the contingent scenario is viewed 62 by the respondents. If enough CVM surveys include both types of elicitation formats (WTA and WTP), then a comparison of differences between the estimated values across questions could provide information on the degree to which various public good commodities are substitutable with private goods. 63 V. CONCLUSION The focus of this study is on the derivation of valuation functions and estimates of central tendency for four different contingent scenarios. Using three years of data on elk hunts on the Starkey, values are obtained for the per trip WTP to avoid the loss of hunting privileges and per trip WTP to ensure an opportunity for a shot at an elk. Additionally, values are obtained for the per trip WTA for giving up the right to hunt and per trip WTA for giving up the right to hunt on the Starkey. Although the results are promising, caution should be exercised in the application of these results in a policy context. The ambiguous nature of some of the contingent scenarios and the low number and small range of the bids reduce the applicability of the results. Additionally, respondents who choose the Starkey may not be statistically representative of hunters who choose other areas, and Respondents' expectations for their Starkey hunting experience may bias their valuation estimates. The results include an estimated median value of $113 per hunter for access to elk hunting and an estimated mean value of $287 per hunter per trip for increases in the elk herd to ensure an opportunity to shoot at an elk. Additionally, the flexibility of valuation functions is demonstrated by showing how changes in the values of significant (at the .05 level) explanatory variables affect WTP and WTA values. Another 64 advantage of the use of the valuation function is that explanatory variables can be changed to reflect attributes specific to other hunting areas. The four policy implications are that: hunting recreational experience (1) the elk is providing substantial benefits to Starkey hunters, (2) willingness to pay values are sensitive to the size of respondents' incomes, (3) Starkey hunters are willing to pay more to increase the elk herd to the point where they would be virtually certain of having an opportunity to shoot at an elk, and (4) Starkey hunters object to the tradeoff between their right to hunt and private goods. The three methodological implications are (1) a demonstration of the flexibility of WTP functions over point estimates, a confirmation of (2) the importance of using specific and unambiguous wording in the contingent scenarios, and (3) a confirmation of the importance of pretests to determine the initial ranges and number of bids in dichotomous choice surveys. In the process of completing this research, some problems were encountered. Chief among these problems was the reduction in efficiency caused by the low number and narrow range of bids. Increases in efficiency could have been gained by utilizing the additional information from the responses to the iterated bids. There are, however, two reasons why the information from the iterated bids was not used in this analysis. First, 65 although techniques are available to utilize the additional information associated with iterated bids, recent critiques in the literature by Cameron (1992) and McFadden and Leonard (1992) demonstrate that there are problems associated with the endogeneity of the second bid. Second, the dichotomous bid elicitation format is currently the method of choice for the majority of CVM researchers. Consequently, by using the dichotomous bids the results from this study are comparable with the results from other studies, such as the one by Park, Loomis and Creel (1991). Another problem encountered in this study is the lack of specificity and ambiguous wording of some of the contingent scenarios. Because the Starkey surveys are to continue for the next five years, there is the potential for ameliorating some of the existing problems and for obtaining further information. The challenge is to strike a balance between maintaining consistency and improving the accuracy and reliability of the results. The following are suggestions for improving the surveys: (1) For the WTP elicitations, add dichotomous bids of $30, $150, $200, $350 and $650. Consistency can be maintained between the data from future surveys and data from existing surveys because an individual responding with a "yes" to a bid of $150 would also say yes to a 66 $100 bid. Additionally, bids lower then the current minimum bid of $50 could be excluded from the analyses. The iterative bids for the WTP elicitations can remain the same. For the WTA elicitations, add dichotomous bids of $750, $1,000, $1,250, $1,500, $1,750 and $2,000. Additionally, add iterative bids of $1,500, $1,750, $2,000 and $2,500. $1,000, $1,250, The increase in the number and range of dichotomous bids should result in increased efficiency. (2) Although the wording of the contingent scenarios should remain unchanged to maintain consistency, an additional WTP question should be added. This question could read: Would you choose to hunt elk on the Starkey if total costs increased by By including this ? question in future Starkey surveys, the use value of the Starkey elk hunting experience could be estimated. Additionally, the responses to this question might provide insight into the perceived difference in the use value of hunting elk on the Starkey versus the use value of hunting in general. 67 (3) A "not for sale" category should be included in the WTA elicitations. The purpose of this category provide a screen for protest responses. is to Respondents could then be grouped according to their response to this category. In five years, completed, when the Starkey surveys have been the resulting data sets should provide a rich source of opportunities for CVM researchers. Economists, however, need not wait until 1997 to begin taking advantage of the research opportunities provided by the existing bank of data. Because of the potential for controlling for differences between hunts and the large number of data sets collected over time, the Starkey project provides a unique opportunity for conducting future research on benefits transfer and stability of preferences. The valuation functions and logistic models developed in this thesis provide the necessary structure for conducting further research on benefits transfer. The impetus for conducting benefit transfer research comes from the prohibitive costs associated with conducting a new CVM study for each separate site. As discussed in the previous section, four policy and three methodological implications result from the derivation of the valuation functions and examination of how changes in 68 the values of the explanatory variables affect the WTA and WTP estimates. Additionally, this research provides the necessary base for exploiting future research opportunities afforded by the Starkey data sets. 69 REFERENCES Adams, R.M., Bergland, 0., Musser, W.N., Johnson, S.L., and L. M. Musser. 1989. User fees and equity issues in public hunting expenditures: the case of ring-necked pheasants in Oregon. Land Economics 65: 376-385. Allen, S. 1988. Montana bioeconomics study: Results of the elk hunter preference study. Montana Dept. of Fish, Wildlife and Parks, Helena. Aldrich, J. and C. R. Nelson. 1984. Linear Probability, Logit and Probit Models. Sage Publications, Beverly Hills. Bergstrom, J. C. 1990. Concepts and measures of the economic value of environmental quality: A review. Journal of Environmental Management 31: 215-228. Berrens, R. 1992. Using contingent valuation to estimate recreational impacts from proposed Columbia River system operational changes: Some experimental design and modelling considerations. (Draft Discussion Paper, April 5, 1992 AREC-OSTJ, Corvallis, OR.) Bishop, R. C., Heberlein, T. A., McCollom, D. W. andM. Welsh. 1988. A validation experiment for valuation techniques. Dept. of Agricultural Economics, Univ. of Wisconsin, Madison. K. J. and R. C. Bishop. 1988. Welfare measurements using contingent valuation: A comparison of techniques. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 70(1): 20-28. Boyle, Brookshire, D. S., Randall, A. and J. R. Stoll. 1980. Valuing increments and decrements in natural resource service flows. American Journal of Agricultural Economics August: 478-488. Cameron, T. A. 1988. A new paradigm for valuing non-market goods using referendum data: Maximum likelihood estimation by censored logistic regression. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 25: 355-379. Cameron, T. A. 1991. Interval estimates of non-market resource values from referendum contingent valuation surveys. Land Economics 67(4): 413-21. Cameron, T. A. and D.D. Huppert. 1991. Referendum contingent valuation estimates: sensitivity to the assignment of offered values. Journal of the American Statistical Association. 86. 910-918. 70 Cameron, T. A. and J. Quiggin. 1992. Estimation using contingent valuation data from a dichotomous choice with follow-up questionnaire. Unpublished manuscript. Cocheba, D. J. and w. A. Langford. 1978. Wildlife valuation: The collective good aspect of hunting. Land Economics 54(4): 490-504. Cooper, J. and J. B. Loomis. 1992. Sensitivity of willingnessto- pay estimates to bid design in dichotomous choice contingent valuation models. Land Economics 68: 211-224. Cory, D. C., Colby B. D. and E. H. Carpenter. 1988. Uncertain recreation quality and wildlife valuation: Are conventional benefit measures adequate? Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 13 (2): 153-162. C. and W. E. Martin. 1985. Valuing wildlife for efficient multiple use: Elk versus cattle. Western Cory, D. Journal of Agricultural Economics 10(2): 282-293. Creel, M.D. and J. B. Loomis. 1992. Modeling hunting demand in the presence of a bag limit, with tests of alternative specifications. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 22: 99-113. Duff ield, J. 1988. The net economic value of elk hunting in Montana. Montana Dept. of Fish, Wildlife and Parks, Helena. Edwards, S. F. and G. D. Anderson. 1987. Overlooked biases in contingent valuation surveys: Some considerations. Land Economics 63(2): 168-178. Fried, B. F. 1991. The Starkey questionnaire: A preliminary data assessment. Report submitted to the Forest Service, USDA. Hanemann, W. M. 1991. Willingness to pay and willingness to accept: how much can they differ? The American Economic Review 81(3): 635-647. Hanemann, W. M. 1984. Welfare evaluations in contingent valuation experiments with discrete responses. American Journal of Agri cultural Economics, August, 1984: 332-341. Hoehn, J. P. and A. Randall. 1987. A satisfactory benefit cost indicator from contingent valuation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 14: 226-247. Johnson, N. S. 1988. A bioeconomic analysis of altering instream flows: Anadromous fish production and competing 71 demands for water in the John Day River Basin, Oregon. M.S. Thesis, Oregon State University. Johnson, N. S. and R. M. Adams. 1988. Benefits of increased streamf low: The case of the John Day River steelhead fishery. 1846. Water Resources Research 24 (11 November): 1839- Johnson, N. S. and R. M. Adams. 1989. On the marginal value of a fish: Some evidence from a steelhead fishery. Marine Resource Economics 6: 43-55. Just, R. E. Hueth, D. L. and Schmitz, A. 1982. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy. Prentice Hall, Inc. New Jersey. Kahneman, D. and J.L. Knetsch. 1992. Valuing Public Goods: The Purchase of Moral Satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 22: 57-70 Learner, E. 1983. Let's take the con out of econometrics. American Economic Review. 73. Loomis, J. B. 1990. Comparative reliability of the dichotomous choice and open-ended contingent valuation techniques. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 18: 7885. Loomis, J. B. 1988. Contingent valuation using dichotomous choice models. Journal of Leisure Research 20(1): 46-56. Loomis, J. B. 1989. Test-retest reliability of the contingent valuation method: A comparison of general population and visitor responses. American Journal of Agricultural Economics February 1989: 76-84. Loomis, J. B., Cooper, J. and S. Allen. 1988. The Montana elk hunting experience: A contingent valuation assessment of economic benefits to hunters. Montana Dept. of Fish, Wildlife and Parks, Helena. Loomis, J. B., Creel, M. and J. Cooper. 1989. The economic benefits of deer in California: Hunting and viewing values. (Institute of Ecology Report 32) University of California, Davis, Davis, CA. Loomis, J. B. and R. G. Walsh. 1986. Assessing wildlife and environmental values in cost-benefit analysis: State of the art. Journal of Environmental Management 22: 125-131. 72 McConnell, K. E. Models for referendum data: the discrete choice models for contingent 1990. structure of valuation. Journal of Management 18: 19-34. Environmental Economics and McFadden, D. and G. Leonard. 1992. On the contingent valuation method for measuring the social value from passive use of environmental resources. Unpublished manuscript. Mitchell, R. C. and R. T. Carson. 1989. Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent Valuation Method. Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C. Nicholson, W. 1989. and Extensions. Microeconomic Theozy: Basic Principles Dryden Press, Chicago. Park, T. A. and J.B. Loomis. 1991. Joint estimation of contingent valuation survey responses. In: Papers of the 1991 Annual Meeting, Western Agricultural Economics Association: 102-108. Park, T. A., Loomis, J. B. and M. Creel. 1991. Confidence for evaluating benefits estimates from dichotomous choice contingent valuation studies. Land intervals Economics 67 (1 February): 64-73. Pindyck, R. S. and D. L. Rubinfeld. 1991. Econometric Models and Economic Forecasts. McGraw-Hill, New York. Quigley, T. M. 1992. Forest health in the Blue Mountains: Social and economic perspectives. (Gen. Tech. Report PNWGTR-296) Pacific Northwest Research Station, Forest Service, USDA, Portland, OR. Randall, A. 1987. Resource Economics: An Economic Approach to Natural Resource and Environmental Policy. John Wiley, New York. Randall, A. and J. R. Stoll. Consumer's surplus in commodity space. The American Economic Review 70(3): 449-455. Seller, C., Stoll, J. R. and J. Chavas. 1985. Validation of empirical measures of welfare change: A comparison of nonmarket techniques. Land Economics 61(2): 156-175. Sorg, C. F. and J. B. Loomis. 1984. Empirical estimates of amenity forest values: A comparative review. (General Technical Report RM-107) USDA Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Collins, CO. Station, Fort 73 Sorg, C. F. and L. J. Nelson. 1986. Net economic value of elk hunting in Idaho. (Resource Bulletin RN-12) USDA Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station, Fort Collins, CO. Varian, H. R. 1992. Microeconomic Analysis. Norton, New York. Walsh, R. G., Johnson, D. M., and J. R. McKean. 1988. Review of outdoor recreation economic demand studies with nomnarket benefit estimates, 1968-1988. Colorado Water Resources Research Institute, Fort Collins, CO. Whitehead J. C and G. C. Blomquist. 1991. Measuring Contingent Values for Wetlands: Effects of Information about Related Environmental Goods. Water Resources Research. 27: 2523-2531. Willig, R. D. 1976. Consumer's surplus without apology. The American Economic Review 66(4): 589-597. Wisdom, M. 1992. The Starkey Project: New technologies chase old questions about deer and elk management. Western Wildlands 18(1): 32-38. APPENDICES 74 APPENDIX 1 DATA FROM THE STARKEY SURVEYS 75 The data sets are in order with HUNTE89 first with 42 observations, HUNE9O with 82, HIJNEA9O with 149, HUNE91 with 109 and HEAtJG91 with 144. = Refers to missing value For HUNTE89 the bid levels for the inadvertantly left blank. hp variable were Variables = definition [corresponding question number on the survey) = group GR ACC = wtp to avoid loss of hunting [13] = wtp for gaurenteed elk or deer [8] = wta payment for hunting starkey [19) EP HPS = wta payment for hunting [20] = income [211 DH = days spent hunting [6) HTR = hours spent traveling to starkey [3) ABIL = hunting ability [5) PRHS = prior hunt starkey [10] AGE = age of respondent [21) HP INC = wtp to avoid loss of hunting [13) = wtp for gaurenteed elk or deer [8) ACC EP EDtJC = level of education [21) OBS GR ACC EP 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 1 3 3 4 1 4 1 3 2 1 1 2 2 1 1 4 1 3 3 3 4 3 2 2 1 . 2 . 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 HPS HP INC DH HTR ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 2 . 4 7 5.0 4 1 3 2 2 . 5 6 11.0 3 2 4 3 1 2 . 4 2 5 8.0 4 3 1 2 2 . 2 4 1 2 6.0 3 2 2 2 4 1 . 6 7 6.0 4 5 2 2 . 3 6 7.0 4 1 6 1 2 2 . 2 11.0 4 2 5 1 6 2 2 6 7 7.0 3 2 4 2 1 2 2 7 5.0 3 2 6 2 1 2 4 5 . 3 2 3 2 2 2 6 7 10.0 3 2 3 2 2 2 10.0 4 5 7 2 4 4 1 2 5 7 0.5 4 2 4 2 1 2 7 6.0 4 1 4 6 3 1 2 4 4 7.0 4 2 1 3 2 2 7 5 2 4 5.5 4 3 1 2 4 7 5.0 4 2 5 5 2 2 5 7 4.0 5 2 4 3 2 . 2 9 . 3 1 . 1 2 2 . 6 1.0 3 1 6 2 2 5 2 2.0 4 2 4 2 2 2 4 7 8.0 4 2 5 2 2 2 76 OBS GR ACC EP 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 1 3 3 4 1 2 4 2 4 3 2 4 2 3 2 3 4 1 3 3 1 3 1 3 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 . . 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 . 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 . 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 3 3 2 2 1 2 1 . 2 1 2 2 2 2 4 4 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 . . 4 1 4 4 1 2 2 3 4 1 1 4 2 3 4 4 1 . 1 1 1 1 2 2 3 3 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 . 4 5 . 4 6 7 7 5 4 5 2 2 HTR 5 3 6 2 2 6 2 5 9 . . 2 6 . 5 3 7 5 . . 1 . 2 . 1 2 2 1 . 2 1 HPS HP INC DH 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 . 2 2 2 . . . . 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1. 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 4 6 4 4 4 3 3 3 3 6 4 3 6 5 5 5 5 3 3 5 5 6 2 2 2 1 I 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 7 4 4 4 4 5 7 4 4 4 710.0 8 . 3 5 3 4 4 4 3 3 . 3 3 4 3 1 4 3 3 3 6.0 2.0 2.0 1.0 10.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 6.0 9.0 9.0 8.0 3.0 4.5 4.0 5.0 7 2 3 4 7 7 7 6 7 4 6 1 2 5 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 2 2 4 4 4 5 610.0 2 7 9 7 7 9 2 . 5 8.0 6.0 8.0 1.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 7.0 6.0 6.0 3.5 6.0 2 2 7 7 5 7 5 4 5 7.0 6.0 1.5 . 7.0 7.0 7.0 2.0 11.5 10.0 5.5 10.0 5.0 5.5 5.0 5.0 4.5 9.0 6.0 ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 7 7 7 4 5 2 1 3 4 5 4 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 5 3 4 1 1 1 4 1 1 1 1 2 5 3 3 4 1 3 4 4 3 3 1 4 3 3 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 5 5 5 1 2 4 4 2 2 6 2 3 3 4 2 4 4 4 4 4 5 2 3 3 3 2 4 4 4 4 2 5 2 2 3 3 6 2 4 4 4 4 6 3 4 4 4 5 2 6 4 4 4 4 6 4 4 3 4 3 5 3 5 6 4 5 1 2 3 1 4 4 7 5 2 3 6 3 3 2 3 2 2 3 5 2 2 2 4 3 2 2 2 3 2 2 2 77 OBS GR ACC EP 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 111 112 113 114 115 116 117 118 119 120 121 122 3 1 4 1 . 3 3 4 2 1 4 3 2 4 3 4 1 2 4 1 1 1 1 4 4 3 2 2 3 2 3 1 3 4 2 3 2 4 4 1 1 2 3 2 1 1 1 . 1 1 2 1 1 1 . 1 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 3 2 3 1 1 3 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 4 3 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 HPS 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 INC HP 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 HTR ABIL PRRS AGE EDIJC DH 4 7 6 6 5 5 6 7 6.0 7.0 5.0 3 . 5 4 6 5 6 3 . 4 5 6 6 4 6 6 . 1 6 4 4 5 3 7 9 7 7 5 7 7 7 7 7 4 5 7 7 6 7 2 7 7 5 4 1 6 2 3 4 4 4 7 7 4 3 3 6 2 5 5 5 5 3 4 4 3 5 3 . . 6.0 . 6.0 7.0 6.0 510.0 7 6.0 7 7.0 9 8.0 7 7.0 3 6 6 3 6 5 . 6 3 3 5.0 1.0 4.0 10.0 3.0 9 7 3 2 7 6 6 5 6 2 . 5.0 7.0 6.0 9.5 9.0 4.0 1.5 7.0 1.5 6.0 1.5 1.0 4.0 1.0 1.0 0.5 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.5 0.5 4.0 5.0 4.0 6.0 5.5 5.5 1.5 3 2 5 3 4 5 4 2 2 3 3 3 3 4 3 3 4 3 3 5 5 5 3 5 4 3 3 3 3 4 3 4 5 3 3 2 4 2 4 5 4 4 3 4 3 3 5 5 4 5 1 4 1 2 2 1 5 4 4 4 2 1 4 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 . 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 . 3 5 5 2 2 5 7 2 5 3 4 7 5 6 4 5 5 4 4 4 4 2 6 4 4 5 5 6 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 2 4 5 3 4 6 4 4 1 4 1 3 5 4 4 3 5 6 6 5 6 2 5 2 1 2 2 5 2 3 5 5 4 3 4 5 4 2 2 4 5 2 5 4 2 2 2 1 6 1 7 2 2 2 2 78 OBS GR ACC 123 124 125 126 127 128 129 130 131 132 133 134 135 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 146 147 148 149 150 151 152 153 154 155 156 157 158 159 160 161 162 163 164 165 166 167 168 169 170 171 172 2 2 4 2 4 1 3 3 1 2 3 3 1 1 3 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 . . 2 1 1 2 1 2 2 1 1 . 1 2 4 1 1 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 3 2 4 4 1 2 2 3 2 1 2 2 4 2 1 2 1 4 4 4 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 4 . 2 3 3 3 3 2 4 1 1 1 4 4 1 EP 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 2 1 . 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 HPS HP INC DH 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 . . 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 1. 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 . 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 . 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 5 6 6 6 6 3 5 3 5 6 3 3 4 2 6 5 5 4 5 4 3 3 6 6 2 4 6 4 4 4 4 4 3 . 3 . 3 3 3 1 4 1 3 . 3 . HTR ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 3 3 3.0 0.5 512.0 2 3 9 3 8 4 4 4 5 3 3 6 5 8 6 5 5 9 8 2 3 5 6 9 5 4 7 9 5 3 2 9 4 4 1 4 6 4 2 9 8 8 4 4 1. 4 8 2 2 3 4 4 6 4.0 6.0 7.0 1.0 5.5 0.5 . 1.0 2.0 1.5 2.0 2.0 2.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.5 . 0.5 1.0 1.0 1.0 2.0 1.0 1.0 0.5 9.0 . 2.0 1.0 1.0 1.5 1.0 1.0 1.0 4.0 1.0 4.0 1.0 1.0 5.0 5.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 3.0 4.5 4 4 1 1 4 2 4 3 3 3 4 4 3 3 4 4 4 3 2 3 3 3 3 4 4 1 . 3 3 3 3 3 2 4 5 1 2 4 4 3 3 1 4 4 1 4 2 3 2 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 5 4 6 5 2 2 4 2 4 4 4 4 3 6 4 3 4 4 3 1 2 2 3 3 4 2 3 7 5 5 2 2 5 6 4 4 4 4 3 4 2 3 2 2 2 6 1 2 4 3 4 4 3 5 4 4 3 5 4 3 1 3 2 3 2 6 2 3 6 5 2 2 2 1 2 5 6 4 6 4 6 4 2 4 1 5 1 1 5 2 3 2 2 2 3 1 3 1 1 79 OBS 173 174 175 176 177 178 179 180 181 182 183 184 185 186 187 188 189 190 191 192 193 194 195 196 197 198 199 200 201 202 203 204 205 206 207 208 209 210 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 219 220 221 222 GR ACC 2 3 4 1 2 1 1 1 3 3 2 2 2 4 1 1. 3 3 4 1 4 3 3 3 1 4 2 4 1 3 4 3 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2. 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 . 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 3 2 2 1 4 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 4 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 EP 1. 2 2 1 2 1 . 2 1 2 1. 2 1 2. 1 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2. 2 2 2. 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2. 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 . 1 2 1 HPS INC DH HP 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 . 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 . . 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1. 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 HTR 3 4 1 4 6 4 4 8 5 4 5 4 . 9 2 4 3 3 2 8 1 8 8 9 3 4 4 5 9 3 5 4 6 6 5 4 1 4 6 1 6 3 2. 9 4 1 3 3 9 4 5 9 3 5 9 2 2 1 2 4 4 6 6 4 2 6 5 5 5 5 1 6 3 2 2 2 2 2 4 8 2 3 4 3 9 6 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 6 6 6 4 . 6 3 6 . 3 3 2 6 2 5 9 3.0 2.0 2.0 3.5 2.0 7.0 1.0 2.0 2.5 2.0 4.0 3.0 1.5 5.5 6.0 0.5 0.5 5.0 . 6.0 6.0 . 5.5 5.0 8.0 5.0 6.0 6.0 6.0 6.0 6.0 . 6.0 5.0 5.5 . ABIL PRHS AGE EDtJC 2 2 1 3 3 4 3 3 1 3 4 3 2 3 4 3 5 2 3 3 3 1 3 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 3 1 4 3 4 3 1 4 6.0 1.0 5.0 1.0 6.0 4 712.0 3 9 9 9 7 5 7.0 9.0 8.0 3.0 8.0 812.0 9 8 9.0 12.0 2 2 4 3 4 1 4 3 2 1 4 4 . 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2. 2 2 2 2 2 2. 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 3 1 3 3 6 5 1 3 3 5 5 5 2 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 3 3 6 4 2 5 2 2 2 1 3 4 4 2 2. 2 2 2 3 2 3 5 4 2 6 3 6 2 2 2 3 6 5 2 5 4 4 4 9 3 5 2 4 4 5 4 2 1 2 5 3 5 2 2 2 1. 4 4 4 5 3 5 6 6 6 3 3 5 4 7 2 5 3 2 2 2 80 OBS GR ACC EP 223 224 225 226 227 228 229 230 231 232 233 234 235 236 237 238 239 240 241 242 243 244 245 246 247 248 249 250 251 252 253 254 255 256 257 258 259 260 261 262 263 264 265 266 267 268 269 270 271 272 1 2 3 1 3 1 1 3 2 4 4 1 1 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 3 3 3 1 3 1 3 4 2 1 2 2 1 1 4 3 4 4 3 2 4 4 1 1 . 3 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 2 4 2 2 1 3 2 4 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 3 3 4 1 2 1 HPS INC DH HP 2 1 . . 1 . 2 2 2 2 2 1 . 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 . 5 2 5 5 5 4 1 4 3 1 2 6 6 5 . 4 6 . 3 3 4 6 2 5 5 5 6 6 9 9 9 4 4 6 3 9 4 9 1.0 1.0 2.0 6.5 6.5 6.5 6.0 1.0 . 2 3 10.0 1.5 1.0 1.0 8.0 5.0 0.5 0.5 5.0 8.0 10.0 7 7 9 5 6.0 5.5 5.5 15.0 2 7 5 5 7 914.0 5 6 6 7 7 4 4 9 9 1 1 6 6 6 4 7 1.0 5.0 5.0 3.0 3.0 . 1.0 1.0 914.0 8 0.5 1.5 1.5 5.0 8.0 8.0 6.0 4 6 9 3 7 7 7 5 910.0 . 5 . . 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 3 2 6 7 5 210.0 . 1 HTR 3 3 4 4 6 9 9 1.0 9.0 810.0 8 5 5 5 10.0 1.5 5.0 5.0 ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 5 4 4 4 2 4 3 4 4 3 5 1 3 2 5 5 3 5 3 3 3 2 3 1 5 4 3 1 1 5 4 1 3 1 3 3 3 3 4 3 3 2 3 4 2 4 4 2 2 2 1 1 1 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 3 4 6 1 4 2 2 4 1 4 4 5 3 4 5 2 1 5 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 4 1 3 3 6 4 3 . 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 3 4 5 2 2 1 4 3 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 4 2 2 2 5 4 5 6 6 5 1 4 1 2 4 4 4 3 1 4 4 6 5 6 6 5 4 4 4 4 2 2 2 3 2 2 5 2 1 3 4 1 2 1 2 5 3 2 2 1 6 5 2 3 2 6 3 5 2 2 81 OBS GR ACC EP 273 274 275 276 277 278 279 280 281 282 283 284 285 286 287 288 289 290 291 292 293 294 295 296 297 298 299 300 301 302 303 304 305 306 307 308 309 310 311 312 313 314 315 316 317 318 319 320 321 322 1 1 4 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 3 1 1 1 4 . 2 2 3 1 4 2 4 3 3 4 2 3 1 4 3 1 3 2 3 3 3 1 3 2 2 4 1 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 . 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 . . 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 1 1 2 1 1 4 2 2 2 2 4 1 1 1 2 2 . 1 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 2 3 1 3 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 1 . 2 2 1 HP 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 . 2 1 2 2 . 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 4 2 2 3 3 6 4 5 6 2 4 6 6 6 2 5 4 6 4 4 4 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 . 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 . 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 6 3 5 1 3 4 6 5 5 6 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 HTR ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC DH INC 2 2 1 2 . 2 1 HPS . 6 6 . 5 4 3 5 4 4 3 4 6 6 4 3 5 7 6 7 5 4 5.0 1 1 . 4 4 4 2 1 1 1 7.0 2.5 8.0 411.0 7 9 6 5 . 5 3 5 5 . . 5 4 7 6 7 3 5 2 2 6 3 4 7 4 3 5 2 3 6 7 7 5 6 9 4 4 7 7 3 4 7 7 5 6.0 6.0 8.0 5.0 10.0 . 3.0 10.1 1.0 10.0 3 2 4 4 2 4 3 3 4 4 3 3 4 . 12.2 9.5 2.5 1.5 8.0 6.0 7.0 7.0 6.0 2.0 2.0 8.1 8.0 6.0 6.0 1.5 8.0 6.0 5.5 7.0 1.5 5.5 . 3.0 3.1 . 6.0 8.0 6.0 5.0 8.0 6.0 2 . 2 3 2 2 5 2 4 3 3 4 . 3 4 5 4 3 3 4 3 4 3 3 2 . 4 4 2 4 5 5 4 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 1 5 3 4 4 1 5 6 5 3 3 4 2 4 4 4 5 5 4 1 5 3 5 4 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 6 3 3 2 1 1 2 2 5 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 2 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 3 6 4 2 2 3 4 1 4 6 5 1 2 3 5 3 1 4 2 2 5 2 2 2 7 5 2 2 5 6 1 1 2 6 5 1 4 5 3 4 6 4 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 3 3 2 2 5 4 3 5 2 1 2 82 OBS 323 324 325 326 327 328 329 330 331 332 333 334 335 336 337 338 339 340 341 342 343 344 345 346 347 348 349 350 351 352 353 354 355 356 357 358 359 360 361 362 363 364 365 366 367 368 369 370 371 372 GR ACC EP 4 1 2 3 1 1 1 1 3 2 2 2 3 . 1 2 4 2 2 1 3 3 4 2 4 3 1 1 4 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 3 2 . 2 1 1 1 2 1 4 1 1 2 2 2 1 . 3 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 4 1 1 2 1 3 2 3 1 2 4 4 1 3 1 2 4 4 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 1 HPS . 2 1 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 1 2 1 1 2 2 . 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 INC DH HP 2 2 1 2 2 4 HTR 7 ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 8.0 1 1 710.0 710.0 9 4.5 3 3 4 2 6 3 7 7 3 5 4 . 2 6 4 4 5 2 . 2 2 6 2 2 4 5 4 2 2 2 1 2 6 2 610.0 7 3 6 3 7 7 5 1 6 4 4 4 3 2 6 7 2 6 5 2 4 4 2 6 5 2 2 . . 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 . 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 5.0 5.0 6.0 5.5 5.0 3 5 9 9 4 6 4 6 5 3 6 6 5 5 3 7 8 3 . 1 5 1 9 7 5 1 7 0.5 2.0 1.5 2.5 5.0 6.0 10.0 1.0 1.0 4.0 5.0 . 0.5 0.5 6.0 5.0 8.0 5.0 8.0 8.0 . 610.0 . 3 3 4 4 3 4 4 4 5 3 4 3 2 2 3 1 5 4 2 2 4 3 4 2 4 4 3 4 5 4 4 2 910.0 4 2 5 2 3 4 7 4 3 3 9 9 5 5 2 6 6 4 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 5 5 5 4 1 2 4 7 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 9 5 . 8.0 6.0 8.0 2 2 2 2 2 4 4 6 2 2 1 4 4 4 4 2 2 1 1 3 4 4 2 2 2 2 2 4 3 1 6 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 5 1 4 2 6 1 4 2 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 . 3 3.5 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 4 2 7.0 4.0 4.0 3.5 7.0 7.0 7.0 7.0 5 4 4 4 4 5 1 3 3 3 5 4 3 3 4 6 6 4 6 5 5 4 2 2 5 7 1 5 2 2 2 1 2 5 5 2 4 1 2 2 3 4 4 4 6 2 6 1 2 2 5 1 2 4 2 1 1 1 2 4 1 2 1 2 2 3 1 3 2 4 4 4 4 2 2 2 2 3 1 3 4 2 4 83 OBS GR ACC EP 373 374 375 376 377 378 379 380 381 382 383 384 385 386 387 388 389 390 391 392 393 394 395 396 397 398 399 400 401 402 403 404 405 406 407 408 409 410 411 412 413 414 415 416 417 418 419 420 421 422 3 1 1 1 1 4 2 1 4 4 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 1 1 2 HPS HP INC 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 4 5 2 6 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 . . . . . . 3 2 1 3 3 1 . . 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 4 3 1 1 2 3 1 4 2 1 1 1 3 . 4 1 1 3 4 4 4 2 3 2 4 3 1 4 4 4 4 1 3 1 2 1 . 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 1 1 2 1 1 . 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 4 6 2 2 2 2 1 2 6 2 2 2 2 2 2 5 1 6 1 2 3 2 2 1 1 1 2 . 2 1 5 . 2 3 4 1 . . 4 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 . 3 3 4 2 3 2 4 6 5 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 4 2 2 2 6 1 5 3 2 HTR DH 3 5 5 4 4 2 . 6 3 9 7 9 9 9 4 7 5 7 6 9 3 4 3 3 3 6 5 7 7 5 8 3 7 7 4 9 4 5 3 4 4 6 4 9 9 9 9 9 9 4 5 5 3 7 4 . 9 2 4 ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 3.5 2.0 2 6.0 6.0 4 4 4 4 . 6.0 9.0 1.0 . 8.0 0.0 4.0 6.0 1.5 0.5 2.0 1.0 2.0 5.5 4.0 1.0 1.0 5.5 8.0 9.0 11.0 7.5 7.0 5.5 . 7.0 5.0 2.0 8.0 6.0 8.0 5.5 8.0 . 6.0 1.5 6.0 8.5 1.0 7.0 8.0 5.0 1.5 6.0 2.0 1 4 3 2 4 2 1 . . 3 4 4 4 4 4 1 2 1 1 1 . . 1 3 1 3 5 1 4 4 5 4 1 3 3 3 2 3 3 3 4 2 3 4 5 3 5 3 4 4 2 5 2 1 5 3 3 4 3 4 1 4 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 5 3 4 1 4 1 4 5 5 3 4 6 4 4 1 4 4 4 1 4 4 3 4 2 6 3 4 6 4 3 3 3 1 4 2 5 6 3 4 4 4 2 1 4 2 4 4 2 2 3 5 5 1 2 1 3 4 6 5 2 3 5 6 2 3 2 3 1 5 4 5 5 2 2 5 2 5 4 2 2 3 1 1 1 5 2 6 2 7 2 1 5 84 OBS GR ACC 423 424 425 426 427 428 429 430 431 432 433 434 435 436 437 438 439 440 441 442 443 444 445 446 447 448 449 450 451 452 453 454 455 456 457 458 459 460 461 462 463 464 465 466 467 468 469 470 471 472 2 4 3 4 4 2 1 3 2 1 1 1 2 2 1 4 3 3 2 1 1 2 1 1 3 3 1 3 2 3 4 2 3 3 1 2 4 4 3 3 2 4 1 1 3 2 3 2 4 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 1 . 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 . 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 EP 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 . 1 1 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 1 HPS HP 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 . 1 2 2 2 2 2 . 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 . 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 . . . 2 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 1 HTR DH INC ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 6 3 5 8 810.0 4 4 3 . 9 3 3 6 3 6 1 3 5 3 3 3 5 4 5 5 6 6 9 6 8 8 5 9 5 3 7 5 3 4 . 6 . 4 2 3 3 5 6 6 5 4 2 . 4 3 3 3 6 6 2 6 6 2 6 4 1 5 4 5 3 3 5 3 5 5 5 6 5 9 . 10.0 9.0 1.5 6.0 0.5 4.0 4.0 12.0 4.5 5.0 10.0 1.0 3.0 8.0 1.0 4.0 1.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 . 7.0 7.0 6.0 9 5.0 8 6.0 8 6.0 7 1.0 5 5.0 8 . 4 2.0 7 . 5.0 9 910.0 9 9.0 1.0 9 4 5.0 9 1.5 9 . 8 6.0 7.0 3 8 6.0 3 1.5 7 . 3 4.0 9 2.0 9 2.0 9 2.0 3 3 1 5 4 3 3 1 3 1 3 3 4 4 1 2 4 3 4 2 4 4 4 5 3 4 3 4 2 4 5 4 4 2 4 4 1 2 3 3 3 4 4 3 3 4 2 2 2 2 2 4 4 1 2 2 1 5 1 4 2 2 2 5 3 1 4 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 4 3 4 4 3 1 3 4 2 5 5 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 4 4 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 4 1 5 5 5 4 4 6 2 4 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 6 4 4 5 1 3 3 3 3 4 4 6 4 4 5 2 1 1 5 2 1 7 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 3 6 4 1 3 7 2 2 4 2 7 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 2 2 5 2 5 3 1 2 1 2 2 2 4 2 2 2 85 OBS GR ACC EP 473 474 475 476 477 478 479 480 481 482 483 484 485 486 487 488 489 490 491 492 493 494 495 496 497 498 499 500 501 502 503 504 505 506 507 508 509 510 511 512 513 514 515 516 517 518 519 520 521 522 3 4 2 1 4 2 1 3 2 3 3 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 1 4 3 1 2 4 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 3 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 3 1 2 2 2 1 4 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 4 1 2 2 2 1 4 1 3 1 4 2 4 2 4 3 2 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 HPS HP INC DH 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 6 3 1 6 8 5 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 4 2 2 3 2 2 3 4 8 9 5 5 7 6 8 9 8 9 9 9 7 7 7 8 8 6 9 3 5 2 8 6 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 2 HTR ABIL PPJIS AGE EDUC 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 6 6 6 6 . 2 4 3 4 4 4 4 6 6 3 4 4 5 4 6 6 6 5 5 6 5 5 . 6 4 3 4 6 6 4 4 1 6 . 5 3 5 8 5 9 4 8 9 7 9 4 8 3 9 8 7 9 5 8 5 7 7 8 9 1.0 5.0 5.0 1.5 7.0 12.0 7.0 10.0 2.0 6.0 5.0 . 5.0 . 2.5 9.0 6.0 6.0 6.0 1.0 1.5 . 10.0 6.0 6.0 4.5 8.0 6.0 . 3.5 5.0 3.5 6.0 5.0 1.5 5.0 5.0 . 3.0 5.5 . 7.0 6.0 6.0 6.0 7.0 2.0 1.0 6.0 5.0 2 1 5 3 2 4 3 4 1 4 4 3 3 1 1 3 1 4 4 4 2 3 5 4 3 2 4 3 4 3 4 1 3 3 3 3 4 4 1 2 2 4 1 4 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 3 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 2 1 2 2 4 4 4 4 4 4 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 5 1 4 3 4 2 4 4 5 2 4 3 4 1 2 3 2 4 2 5 1 2 2 4 5 4 4 4 4 4 2 2 2 2 5 3 5 4 5 6 4 3 5 2 3 4 3 3 4 4 3 5 5 5 4 4 4 3 4 5 3 3 3 4 4 4 4 5 3 2 5 4 2 2 2 2 6 5 5 3 2 7 2 5 2 2 5 6 4 2 1 1 3 2 4 5 1 2 2 2 86 OBS GR ACC EP 523 524 525 526 3 1 2 2 . 1 2 2 . 2 2 HPS HP INC DH 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 5 2 HTR ABIL PRHS AGE EDUC 9 1.5 9 . 9 9 6.5 10.0 4 1 5 3 1 2 1 1 2 6 2 6 4 1 2 2 87 APPENDIX 2 STARKEY RESEARCH FOREST SURVEY 88 Dear Starkey Hunter, As you are aware, there are many studies being conducted on the Starkey Experimental Forest. One of our goals is to gather information to assist National Forest Managers as they plan management of resources for multiple-use. We believe we have reliable estimates of costs and benefits associated with timber harvest and livestock grazing, but we currently lack good measures of values associated with recreation and wildlife. We are asking your help as forest recreation users in obtaining recreation values. The attached questionnaire is designed to gain an understanding of wildlife and recreation values as perceived by you, the users. Please take the time to complete this questionnaire prior to riving at Starkey. It will take you about 20 minutes to complete. We will ask for them at the gate as you check in for the hunt, and if they are already filled in it will shorten your check in time.- We realize you cannot be completely accurate in some of your estimates of costs, time, etc., but we are interested in your expectations. Therefore they need to be completed prior to the hunt. Thank you for taking the time to complete this now. Chris Carter Oregon Departaent of Fish and Wildlife Tom Quig]ey Forest S.rvice 89 Date Hunter ID Interviewer Starkey Hunting Valuation Study Questionnaire Please provide the following information. All information you provide will be held in the strictest of confidence. No reports will refer to you specifically nor will the personal information be given to any other individual or group. The information will be used to help determine the values associated with hunting on the Starkey Experimental Forest. Was the primary purpose of the trip to hunt? NO How many days do you plan to hunt the Starkey? How many hours do you plan to hunt the Starkey in total? (actual daylight hours of hunting) How many hours did it take for you to travel to Starkey? How did you travel to get to Starkey? Mark all the modes of travel you used to get to Starkey: Car or Pick-up Motor Home Other (Specify) $. Was the trip planned to coincide with: _Visiting relatives _Visiting friends _Vacaçion to do other things in NE Oregon Only the hunt _Other (specify) 90 5. How do novice 2 1 6. r.ite 2/our hunting ab[litjes (1-5): intermediate expert 4 5 How many DAYS have you or will you do the following during 1990: (NUMBER of DAYS) Hunt deer _____Hunt upland game Hunt elk Hunt other species _____Hunt bear Hunt waterfow 7. 3 Ocean fishing Freshwater fishing If you had not been selected to hunt the Starkey, what do you think you would have done instead? Approximately how many big-game have you personally killed? Elk Deer Bear Antelope Moose How many non-hunters traveled with you to the Starkey? Have you hunted the Starkey area before? _____YES _____NO What was the primary reason you requested the Starkey hunt? (mark ONE only) _____Have hunted this area before Noie].ty of hunting in an enclosure Novelty of hunting in a research project More likely to be successful in tagging deer/elk Other (Specify) 91 12. What is the ount of expenditures you have and/or will have associated with the hunt? (NE Oregon is assumed to be Wal.lova. Umatilla, Morrow, Grant, Baker, and Union counties.) Outside NE Inside NE Oregon Oregon Transportation $ $ Lodging Food from Stores Food in Restaurants Supplies License & Fees We are attempting to determine the value of wildlife in the Starkey area. No plans are being made to charge extra fees for access to Starkey. The following hypothetical questions are being asked so that comparisons can be made with wildlife values and other resources values. 13. Would you choose not to hunt at all in 1990 if total costs increased by 7 YES. I would not hunt. ____NO, I would still hunt. 13a. IF YES, would you choose 13b. IF NO to question 13 not to hunt total costs above, would you choose increased by 7 not to hunt if toc1. YES NO costs increased by 7 YES NO if 14. Please consider how important you view the following activities in your own life. Please circle whether you consider these to be highly important (H), of medium importance (N), low importance (L), or of no importance (N). - HNLN HMLN H )fL N HMLN HMLN HMLN HNLN H MLN HMLN HMLN HMLN HMLN golf, tennis, bowling fishing hunting swimming, hiking, biking, skiing camping, backpacking, horseback riding rafting. canoeing, kayaking. water-skiing watching sports on TV watching sports in person livestock grazing in the National Forests timber harvesting in the National Forests wilderness ar.u; in th Natinaj F.rt wildlife vjewji' 92 1.5. What form of recreation would you consider most equal in 'value with the hunting experience you will 'e having at Starkey? 16. We are interested in your general attitude about hunting deer Please circle whether you consider these reasons highly and elk. low importance (L), or important (H). of medium importance of no importance (N). O. H M L N H M 1.. N H )( L N H H L N H H L N H H L N I enjoy being out of doors and experiencing the natural environment. I enjoy socializing with friends and/or relatives in the outdoor setting. I believe the meat viii satisfy a real need for my family. I have hunted for years and the tradition will. continue. I consider hunting as the best use of my spare and/or vacation time. I really don't have any alternatives I consider of equal importance. 1.7. How likely do you think it viii be that you will have an opportunity to shoot at an elk/deer? ______% chance 18. If the number of animals were sufficient to make it virtually certain that you would have an opportunity o shoot at an elk/deer, would you be willing to pay additional to hunt? _____YES _____NO 18b. IF NO to q.18 above, l8a. IF YES would you be willing to pay additional? voul4 you be willing to additional? pay _____YES _____NO NO YES 93 If you could still hunt somewhere .lse during the general season, would you accept a payment of .. from someone else and give up your hunting privilege on Starkey this year? ______YES NO ]9a. IF YES, you11 you accept a payment of'. for your hunting privilege on Starkey? ______YES ______NO 19b. IF NO to q.19 above. would you accept a payment of for your hunting privilege on Starkey? ' YES NO If someone would pay you to completely give up your hunting privilege thu year (Starkey AND elsewhere), would you give itupfor YES NO 20*. I? YES, 20a. IF NO to q.20 above, voulr1 you accept a payment of. to give up your hunting of elk/deer this season? would you accept a payment of_____ to give up your hunting of elk/deer for the season? YES YES NO Personal information: Age: _____< 16 16-24 25-34 Male 35-50 51-64 > 65 Female Mumber in your household including yourself. Axe you retired? Yes No Average hours you work for pay: < 10 31-40 10-20 41-50 21-30 > 50 Your hourly wage rate (S/hour): <$3.00 59.00-12.00 3.00-6.00 12.00-15.00 6.00-9.00 > 15.00 Hours of PAID vacation per month: NO