Minimum unit pricing of alcohol Andrew Leicester Independent Scientific Committee on Drugs (ISCD), 2nd February 2012 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Background • Minimum unit pricing (MUP) has received considerable support • Policy is set to be introduced in Scotland this year – Rate still to be set based on consultation and new evidence – Legal issues? • Other policy action towards alcohol pricing – ‘Below-cost’ ban in April 2012, England and Wales – Beer tax reform in October 2011 – tax varies with ABV – 2% real increase in alcohol duty each year to 2014/15 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Impact of minimum pricing (Leicester, 2011) • Descriptive picture of off-licence alcohol purchasing in 2010 – Impact on-licence likely to be much smaller • Average per-unit price on-trade £1.26 (E&W, 2009), off-trade £0.44 • Not modelling any likely behavioural responses • Data from Kantar Worldpanel (market research organisation) – 25,000 British households with in-home barcode reader – Detailed grocery purchase records at the barcode level • Data on products, stores, prices, household characteristics – Look at alcohol purchasing and prices paid per alcohol unit • Actual strength ABV known for beer, cider and alcopops • Estimated for spirits based on brand and spirits type • Constant 12.5% ABV assumed for all table wine – Assume MUP is 45p in December 2010 prices • How to uprate any minimum price an important question! © Institute for Fiscal Studies Impact by off-licence alcohol type % of units sold Avg. p/unit % below 45p Wine 37.6% 45.3p 65.3% Spirits 26.9% 42.0p 77.3% Lager 17.4% 37.9p 80.7% Cider & perry 8.8% 29.1p 87.4% Beer 4.3% 49.6p 42.1% Fortified wine 2.5% 37.7p 73.7% Sparkling wine 2.0% 79.3p 18.6% Alcopops 0.6% 83.4p 1.6% 100.0% 42.6p 71.0% ALL Source: Leicester (2011), estimates from Kantar Worldpanel data 2010 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Impact by alcohol consumption level Increase in budget (%) All >35 30-35 25-30 20-25 18-20 16-18 14-16 0 12-14 0 10-12 3 9-10 20 8-9 6 7-8 40 6-7 9 5-6 60 4-5 12 3-4 80 2-3 15 1-2 100 <1 Price (p); % affected (units per adult per week) Units per adult per week Average price per unit (p) © Institute for Fiscal Studies % units affected Increase in food budget (%) Source: Leicester (2011), estimates from Kantar Worldpanel data 2010 Impact by household income group (including those who do not buy off-licence alcohol) 2.5 80 2 60 1.5 40 1 20 0.5 All £70k+ £60k-£70k £50k-£60k £40k-£50k £30k-£40k £20k-£30k £10k-£20k 0 < £10k 0 Increase in budget (%) Price (p); % affected 100 Gross annual household income Average price per unit (p) % units affected Increase in food budget (%) © Institute for Fiscal Studies Source: Leicester (2011), estimates from Kantar Worldpanel data 2010 Behavioural responses • Consumers – Demand response to changing relative prices (across/within category) – Substitute towards on-licence consumption, other expenditures • Responses vary across consumers – Cross-border purchasing, home-brew, illicit alcohol purchasing? • Manufacturers and retailers – Indirect effect on more expensive alcohol products – Long-term effects on product availability – Impact on non-alcohol prices? Alcohol as a ‘loss-leader’? • Current models do not really consider this range of effects © Institute for Fiscal Studies Minimum pricing: summary • Preferable to taxation if taxes are not passed through? – On average, pass through seems to be more than one-for-one – But need more evidence on the distribution of pass-through • Small impact on moderate drinkers? – At a MUP of 45p, almost all off-licence purchasers directly affected – Two-thirds of moderate drinker units affected – Heavy drinkers on average pay less, but not that much less • Probably slightly regressive – Low income households buy cheaper products – But on average effects are small, shouldn’t be main concern • Transfers from alcohol consumers to producers/retailers – Higher alcohol taxes at least raise revenue for public purse – Reform tax system, not just raise rates ... © Institute for Fiscal Studies Current structure of alcohol taxes (on an effective tax per alcohol unit basis) Effective tax per unit (p) 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 4 8 Spirits Source: Leicester (2011) Note: Cider assumes ‘still’ cider rate © Institute for Fiscal Studies 12 Beer 16 20 24 ABV (%) Table wine 28 Sparkling wine 32 36 Cider 40 A flat-rate excise tax on alcohol content? • Starting point of taxing on basis of alcohol content sensible – Need compelling evidence to vary rates – area for further study? – Do the marginal external costs very by drink / strength? – US studies: if anything, case for bigger tax on beer than spirits • Floor price through tax system if combined with ‘below-cost’ ban • EU Directives restrict tax structure – Precedents for levying additional alcohol taxes if not ‘state aid’ – Convoluted – preferable to reform at EU level! © Institute for Fiscal Studies