Reviewing the evidence from macro-studies of the incidence of SSCs David Phillips,

advertisement

Reviewing the evidence from macro-studies of the incidence of SSCs

David Phillips, Leon Bettendorf, Antoine Bozio, Tomas Breda, Johannes Geibel,

Michael Neumann and Marianne Tenard

Workshop on SSCs, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, February 2016

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Intro

• Rather than utilise reforms or structural features in a single country,

“macro” literature uses cross-country data, variation and policy reform

• Seminal study undertaken by OECD (1990)

– Additional studies since

• Widespread perception that the macro evidence supports view that workers bear the burden of SSCs

– Contrast with more varied evidence of the micro-literature

Saez (2012): “The most compelling macro-economic argument suggesting that the incidence is borne primary by workers is the fact that the labor income share (which includes all payroll taxes) in GDP is fairly stable over time and across countries, OECD (1990)”

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Actually, labour share varies, volatile & downward

100

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Changes in SSCs and changes in labour shares

-4 -2

0

-1

0

-2

-3

5

4

3

2

1

2 4 6 8 10

Change in Labour Share

12

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Changes in SSCs and changes in labour shares

-4 -2

0

-1

0

-2

-3

5

4

3

2

1

2 4 6 8 10

Change in Labour Share

12

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Our paper (being drafted)

• Reviews this literature

– Underlying conceptual models and empirical strategies

– Data on which they are estimated

– Results

– Issues that need addressing

• Preview of findings

– Not clear that employees bear all burden – wide range of results

– Labour market institutions seem to matter for incidence

– Legal incidence matters in short-run

– Unclear about longer term, as no studies really look properly at this

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

OECD (1990)

Three approaches used

1.

Change in wages, regressed on changes in taxes and productivity:

– Simple 12-year difference using 16 OECD countries, 1974 and 1986

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Approach 1: underlying model

• Underlying theoretical model is homogenous firms and workers in perfectly competitive markets

• F.O.C for profit maximisation: z = employer cost of labour

• Link between employer cost and gross wage:

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Approach 1: empirical strategy and results

• Estimate the following equation:

• τ

E

is employee SSC tax rate, τ

C

is consumption tax rate, y/e is average labour productivity

– All tax rates measured as % of GDP

• Results

• Can reject β

1

= 0 (Full incidence on employer), but not -1 (full on worker)

• Cannot reject incidence of all taxes fully on worker

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Approach 1: critique

• Misspecifications

– Approximation that ln(1+

τ

X

) =

τ

X

only holds when

τ

X

is small. Leads to classical measurement error of all coefficients.

– Use of average not marginal labour productivity

• Data problems:

– Sensitivity of results to precise years and sample of countries

– OECD data has spurious variation in SSC rates due to data compilation problems

• Interpretation as ‘long run’

– 12-year differences does not necessarily mean pick up long-run effects – weighted average of different durations

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

OECD (1990)

Three approaches used

1.

Change in wages, regressed on changes in taxes and productivity:

– Simple 12-year difference using 16 OECD countries, 1974 and 1986

2.

Real-product-wage, regressed on lag, tax wedge, and capital/labour ratio

– Average of 16 country-level regressions, 1955 – 1986

– Tests for incidence of employer==employer

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Approach 2

• Regress:

Where RPW = real product wage, TT = total tax wedge, X = 70s dummy

• Results:

(8.4) (1.7) (0.5) (2.1)

• With 16 individual regressions, t=0.5 is ‘borderline significance’

– Some partial bearing of tax by employers?

• Cannot reject incidence of employee and employer same, but large standard errors mean:

– Cannot reject employers SSCs borne by workers and vice versa!

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

OECD (1990)

Three approaches used

1.

Change in wages, regressed on changes in taxes and productivity:

– Simple 12-year difference using 16 OECD countries, 1974 and 1986

2.

Real-product-wage, regressed on lag, tax wedge, and capital/labour ratio

– Average of 16 country-level regressions, 1955 – 1986

– Tests for incidence of employer==employer

3.

As above but also including change in tax wedge

– Much stronger statistical power

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Approach 3

• Finds β

4

= 0.5, statistically different from 0 and 1

– Around half burden of taxes in short-run borne by employers

• Also finds

– Employers bear less of employee than employer SSCs in short-run

– But still some evidence of partial shifting of both in short-run

– Employers bear more of indirect tax burden than SSC burden – the role of inflation in pay negotiations?

• So evidence on long-run incidence is weak

– Stronger evidence about short-run

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

We also review 8 further studies

• Generally, better specified than OECD (1990)

– For instance, use ln(1+ τ ) not τ

• But most cited (Alesina and Perotti (1997) and Daveri and Tabellini

(2000)) use problematic OECD data

• Wide range of estimates

– Some find labour taxes fully on worker even in short-term

– Others find substantial share on employers even in long-term

• So taken together, what can we learn?

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Poor methodology for assessing long-run effects

• Number of studies look at ‘dynamic’/long-run effects

– Tyrvainen (1995) has vector auto-regressive model

– Arpaia and Carone (2004), Azemar and Desbordes (2010) and Nunziata

(2005) have auto-regressive wages

• Auto-regressive models not suited to finding long run-effects of SSCs

– Simply multiply short run effects: if partly incident on employers in short term, point estimate is even more so in long term

– Weak statistical power: not able to distinguish between statutory incidence and shifting

• Difficult to conclude how short and long-run incidence differ from these studies

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Surprisingly little testing differential incidence

• Only one study tests whether incidence of employer and employee incidence differs (Arpaia and Carone (2004))

– Short-run: employee SSCs on workers, employers SSCs partly on employers

– Weak statistical power means cannot test long-run

• More studies examine SSC-benefit link, and compare with income tax

– Ooghe et al (2003) find more SSCs borne by workers if stronger contribution-benefit link

– Alesina and Perotti (1997) find similar in countries with highly centralised bargaining

– But find employer SSCs borne more by employers than income tax when low or moderately centralised bargaining

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Labour market institutions matter

• Alesina and Perotti (1997) find high/low centralised wage bargaining mean SSCs borne almost entirely by workers

– But medium-level of bargaining around two/thirds by employers

• Consistent with models of bargaining (e.g. Olson (1982))

– Power of unions at industry level allows shifting of burden to employers

– But take account of employment spillovers if national-level bargaining

• Other papers find moderate degrees of coordination associated with burden partly on employers

– Most find highly-centralised means incidence on workers (3 papers)

– Less consensus on whether decentralised means same (2 papers)

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Summary

• Idea that this literature supports full shifting to workers is misplaced

• No clear conclusion on either short- or long-run incidence

– Studies do not properly address issue of long-run incidence

• Little work examines whether legal incidence matters for economic incidence

• Only clear finding is that bargaining institutions matter

– But no real consensus on what way

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Avenues for future analysis

• Update using longer-time series and better data

– A comprehensive comparison of methods?

• Properly examine longer-run effects using lagged changes in tax rates

• More examination of influence of formal incidence

• Cross-country studies using micro data, and/or different degrees of aggregation of data

– May be able to learn about ‘local’ versus ‘market’ level incidence

© Institute for Fiscal Studies

Download