2. Planning the public finances

advertisement
2. Planning the public finances
2.1 The Chancellor’s fiscal rules
In 1998, the Chancellor outlined two fiscal rules to constrain his future tax and
spending decisions. His stated rationale was to provide a credible framework
to ensure that the state of the public finances was sustainable and that it did
not impose an unfair financial burden on future generations:1
•
Τhe golden rule states that the government will only borrow to fund
investment. This implies that tax revenues should equal or exceed current
(or non-investment) spending. In other words, the ‘current budget’ should
be in balance or surplus. Sensibly, the golden rule only has to be met on
average over the economic cycle and not every year. This allows the
‘automatic stabilisers’ of the tax and benefit system to operate. When
output in the economy is running below trend, tax revenues are subdued
and spending on social security benefits rises. This temporarily increases
government borrowing and enhances consumers’ spending power. The
reverse happens in a boom: tax receipts increase as a share of national
income and spending on benefits falls. If the rule had to be met every year,
the government would be forced to respond to an increased current budget
deficit, due to weak economic activity, by raising taxes or cutting its
expenditure plans. This could exacerbate the downturn.2
•
Τhe sustainable investment rule states that public sector debt should
remain at a ‘stable and prudent’ level, interpreted by the Chancellor as no
more than 40% of national income. The aim is to avoid a situation in
which the government has to devote an ever-increasing share of national
income to servicing its debt. Over the longer term, this would become both
politically and economically unsustainable. If the Treasury’s forecasts to
overachieve the golden rule are met, then its plans to increase public sector
net investment to 2.2% of national income will be consistent with the
sustainable investment rule.3
Both objectives are reasonable rules of thumb but neither is necessarily
optimal.4 The golden rule has intuitive appeal but may not guarantee
intergenerational fairness. There is no guarantee that the flow of benefits from
an investment project will be synchronised with the debt repayments that
1
For more details, see HM Treasury, Analysing UK Fiscal Policy, London, 1999 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//89A63/90.pdf).
2
It is worth noting that, while the automatic stabilisers operate in the right direction, the
strength with which they do so is a function of the precise structure of the tax and benefit
system and may not be optimal from the perspective of macroeconomic management.
3
Also assuming that the Treasury macroeconomic forecasts are accurate.
4
A more detailed discussion of the government’s fiscal rules can be found in C. Emmerson,
C. Frayne and S. Love, The Government’s Fiscal Rules, Briefing Note no. 16, Institute for
Fiscal Studies, London, 2003 (www.ifs.org.uk/public/bn16.pdf).
© Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2004
8
Planning the public finances
finance it. It is also difficult to determine which sorts of spending yield
benefits for future generations and which do not. The distinction drawn by the
golden rule between capital and current spending suggests that all capital
spending will benefit future generations and all current spending benefits only
the present one. Given the use of national accounts definitions, this is unlikely
to be the case. For example, some current expenditure on education might be
thought to have greater long-term benefits than some capital spending
projects.
While it is clearly desirable that government indebtedness should not increase
explosively, it is also hard to argue on theoretical grounds that the ceiling of
40% of national income laid down under the sustainable investment rule is
necessarily more sensible than, say, 30% or 50%. International and historical
comparisons both indicate that a 40% debt ceiling seems cautious, but this
does not necessarily make it optimal in any rigorous, analytical sense. Also,
focusing on public debt levels may not provide an accurate measure of the
long-term sustainability of a country’s public finances. Governments have a
number of de facto future financial obligations that are not counted as public
sector debt, ranging from risks they have underwritten (either explicitly or
implicitly) to the requirement to provide benefits and pensions to future
generations.5 On the other hand, future governments also have the ability to
increase revenues in the future by raising taxes. It is not obvious how either of
these factors should be taken into account in deciding whether the
government’s financial position at any given time is sustainable.
Assessing whether the golden rule is met
Retrospective assessment of the golden rule: dating the current cycle
One can only pass definitive judgement on whether or not the golden rule has
been met in retrospect, by examining whether the current budget has been in
balance or surplus over a complete economic cycle. Assessing in the midst of
a cycle whether the golden rule is on course to be met over the whole cycle is
complicated by the need to identify where the economy stands in the cycle at
any given time. To do so, it is necessary to estimate the ‘output gap’, a
measure of the distance between actual national income and the potential level
that is consistent with stable inflation (also described as the ‘trend’ level).
Unfortunately, the level of ‘potential’ output cannot be observed directly, only
estimated by looking at the past relationship between output and inflation and
projecting how it will change in the future. In addition, it is necessary to
estimate when the current cycle will end. This depends on the size of the
output gap, the rate at which the economy is expected to grow in the future
and the rate at which the potential level of output is expected to grow.6
5
For a more in-depth discussion of the sustainability of the public finances, see HM Treasury,
Long-Term Public Finance Report: Fiscal Sustainability with an Ageing Population, London,
December 2003 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media//555E2/longterm_fiscal_1to6_436.pdf).
6
For information about the Treasury’s view on the sustainable level of economic growth, see
HM Treasury, Trend Growth: Recent Developments and Prospects, London, April 2002
(www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media//D6678/ACF521.pdf).
9
Green Budget, January 2004
The estimate of the output gap from 1990–91 to 2008–09 that the Treasury
published in the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report7 (PBR) is shown in Figure
2.1. The current cycle is assumed to have begun in 1999–2000 following a
mini-cycle between the first half of 1997 and mid-1999. Output then fell
below trend again in 2001–02. Stronger growth is forecast to close the
negative output gap by mid-2006, bringing the current cycle to an end. As an
approximation, the Treasury thinks that the current economic cycle consists of
the seven financial years running from April 1999 to March 2006.
Figure 2.1. HM Treasury estimates of the output gap
3.0
Percentage of trend output
2.0
1.0
0.0
-1.0
-2.0
-3.0
-4.0
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
Year
Note: Actual output less trend output as a percentage of trend output (non-oil basis).
Source: Chart A3, page 179 of the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.
The 2003 Blue Book contained significant upward revisions to estimates of
national income in recent years. In light of the revisions, the Treasury has
increased its estimate of trend annual growth in potential output between the
first half of 1997 and the third quarter of 2001 from 2.61% in the April 2003
Budget8 to 2.94% in the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.9 Despite this
increase, the Treasury’s projection for trend growth from the third quarter of
2001 until the end of 2006 remains 2¾% a year, although the Treasury uses a
more cautious 2½% to project the outlook for the public finances. If the
Treasury had increased its estimate of trend output growth from 2001 to 2006
in light of the revisions, this would have meant that the economy was
presently even further below trend than the Treasury believes. So the output
7
HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report, Cm. 6042, London, December 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr03/prebud_pbr03_index.cfm).
8
HM Treasury, Budget 2003: Building a Britain of Economic Strength and Social Justice,
London, April 2003 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_bud03/bud_bud03_index.cfm).
9
See table A2, page 177 of the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.
10
Planning the public finances
gap would be even bigger than the Treasury’s current estimate of –1.4%. This
is already a relatively large estimate by the standards of other forecasters.10
Retrospective assessment of the golden rule: Estimating the current budget
The golden rule implies that the aggregate current budget balance over the
seven years of the economic cycle should be in balance or in surplus. In
previous speeches, the Chancellor quantified the government’s room for
manoeuvre in meeting the golden rule by aggregating the past and forecast
cash values of the current budget over the cycle. So in his 2003 Budget
speech, for example, he noted that ‘We meet our golden rule over the cycle –
not just achieving a balance but with an estimated surplus at £32 billions’.11
Figure 2.2. Current budget surplus as a percentage of national income
Actual
HM Treasury December 2003 Pre-Budget Report forecast
Percentage of national income
2.5
£19.3bn
£20.4bn
2.0
1.5
£8.8bn
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
–£5bn
-1.0
–£8bn
–£11.8bn
-1.5
-2.0
–£19.3bn
1999–2000
2000–01
2001–02
2002–03
2003–04
2004–05
2005–06
Financial year
Note: Measures exclude the windfall tax and associated spending.
Sources: December 2003 Pre-Budget Report; HM Treasury, Public Finances Databank,
November 2003, London, 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//95B19/PublicFinancesDatabank241103.XLS).
As a result of the increased borrowing forecast for this and the next two
financial years, the Treasury significantly reduced its estimate of the likely
aggregate surplus in the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report: ‘By 2005–06,
when the current cycle ends under the assumptions used in these projections,
10
For instance, the OECD Economic Outlook no. 74, published in December 2003
(www.oecd.org/document/61/0,2340,en_2649_33733_2483901_1_1_1_1,00.html), put the
output gap for the UK at –1.1% of national income in 2003 and –0.9% in 2004. The
International Monetary Fund puts the output gap in the third quarter of 2003 at just –¾%
(www.imf.org/external/np/ms/2003/121803.htm). In addition, the Governor of the Bank of
England, Mervyn King, in the November Inflation Report press conference, stated that he
believed that with respect to the output gap ‘it’s hard to believe that it’s a long way from zero
given that we’ve seen very stable, flat unemployment, stable nominal earnings growth, very
stable inflation and growth not far from trend’.
11
Chancellor of the Exchequer’s Budget Statement, 9 April 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_bud03/bud_bud03_speech.cfm).
11
Green Budget, January 2004
the accumulated total surplus over the economic cycle will be £4½ billion’.12
Figure 2.2 shows the expected current budget surplus over every year of the
current economic cycle that is currently believed to run from 1999–2000 to
2005–06. The size of the surpluses in the first three years of the economic
cycle (1999–2000, 2000–01 and 2001–02) outweighs the size of the expected
deficits from 2002–03 to 2005–06 by £4½ billion.
As Figure 2.3 illustrates, the predicted margin by which the golden rule will be
overachieved in the current cycle has declined steadily over the past two-anda-half years. In Budget 2001, two years into the economic cycle, the Treasury
was projecting a cumulative surplus of around £100 billion, compared with the
cumulative surplus of just £4½ billion that the Treasury is now predicting.
Figure 2.3. Predictions of the cumulative cash current budget surplus
from various Pre-Budget Reports and Budgets
120
100
Budget 01
£ billion
80
Budget 02
Budget 03
60
PBR 03
40
20
0
Mar-99 Mar-00 Mar-01 Mar-02 Mar-03 Mar-04 Mar-05 Mar-06
Note: The cumulative current budget surplus is ‘set’ to zero in March 1999, when the cycle
starts.
Source: HM Treasury, various Budgets and Pre-Budget Reports.
In his statement to Parliament in December 2003, the Chancellor used a
slightly different method of calculation, focusing on ‘the average annual
surplus on the current budget as a percentage of GDP since the cycle began’.13
This method is more favourable because the economic cycle begins with
surpluses and ends with deficits, as £1 of surplus at the start is a larger share of
national income than a £1 of deficit at the end due to both inflation and real
growth in the economy. By contrast, the ‘cumulative current budget surplus’
method regards each £1 of nominal current budget surplus or deficit as the
same, whatever year that £1 was accumulated in.14
12
Paragraph B37, page 214 of the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.
13
Paragraph 2.62 of the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.
14
If the rationale behind the golden rule was that future taxpayers should not be affected by
the current spending decisions made over the current economic cycle, then the correct test
would be adding the nominal surpluses and not taking the figures as a share of GDP.
12
Planning the public finances
Over the first four years of the cycle, the current budget averaged surpluses of
1.0% of national income a year. The Treasury predicts deficits of 1.7% this
year, 0.7% in 2004–05 and 0.4% in 2005–06, reducing the average over the
cycle to date to 0.2% by the time the cycle ends. On this basis, the Chancellor
said, ‘we not only meet our first fiscal rule, the Golden Rule, that we balance
the budget, but even on cautious assumptions we have an average annual
surplus over the whole cycle of around 0.2 per cent of GDP – meeting our first
rule in this cycle by a margin of £14 billion’.15
The figure of £14 billion can be reached by multiplying the expected
cumulative surplus over the cycle (expressed as a percentage of national
income) by expected national income at the end of the cycle, in 2005–06.
Figure 2.4 shows what the implied surplus would have been using this
methodology alongside that using the previous methodology, based on
previous Treasury forecasts for the current budget surplus and national income
to March 2006. If the Treasury had forecast the cumulative surplus on the
current budget as a percentage of national income for the current economic
cycle in this way in April 2001, it would have obtained a cumulative forecast
of around 10% (or 1.4% a year) of national income, or £119 billion, based on
what it then expected national income to be in 2005–06.
Figure 2.4. Predictions of the implied total current budget surplus in
2005–06 using the expected sum of cash amounts and expected averages,
from various Pre-Budget Reports and Budgets
Summing cash amounts
140
1.4%
Summing shares of national income
120
1.1%
£ billion
100
80
60
0.5%
40
0.2%
20
0
Budget 01
Budget 02
Budget 03
PBR 03
Notes: The percentage above each column shows what the average current budget surplus as a
share of national income was expected to be by the end of 2005–06 at the time of each
publication. Both the percentages and the absolute sums are calculated using contemporary
predictions of national income in future years, not the most up-to-date forecasts from the
December 2003 PBR.
Source: HM Treasury, various Budgets and Pre-Budget Reports.
15
Chancellor of the Exchequer’s Pre-Budget Report Statement, 10 December 2003
(http://www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr03/prebud_pbr03_speech.cfm).
13
Green Budget, January 2004
As Figure 2.4 shows, the underlying pattern is the same whichever method of
calculation is used: having forecast two-and-a-half years ago that the golden
rule would be overachieved by a huge margin, the Chancellor now finds his
room for manoeuvre to be much diminished, partly as a result of deliberate
policy decisions and partly as a result of forecast errors and revisions. To some
extent, this is to be expected. Aiming to overachieve the golden rule by a large
amount early in the cycle might be regarded as prudent, given the considerable
uncertainties in forecasting the path of the public finances over a number of
years. But there is no reason for the Treasury to seek to have overachieved the
golden rule ex post by a significant amount, unless public debt were at or near
the 40% of national income ceiling and the government wished to create room
for more investment. It is therefore reasonable that the forecast
overachievement of the golden rule should decline as the end of the cycle
draws nearer and as the uncertainties surrounding the out-turn over the
remainder of the cycle diminish.
Margins of caution and forecasting error
Deciding how much caution the Treasury should seek to build into its
forecasts for the public finances at different points in the economic cycle is a
matter of judgement. It depends on how confident one wants to be at any
given point that existing tax and spending policies would be consistent with
meeting the golden rule when the cycle ends. This, in turn, depends on what
the pattern of forecast errors in the past suggests about the likely direction and
magnitude of forecast errors in the future, and on the scope the Treasury sees
for countervailing policy adjustments if such errors materialise.
The Treasury’s average absolute error in forecasting public sector net
borrowing – the current balance plus net investment – one, two, three and four
years ahead for the period from 1977–78 to 2002–03 is shown in Table 2.1.
This shows that even one year ahead, the average absolute error is
£11.6 billion in today’s prices.
Table 2.1. Average errors in forecasting public sector net borrowing
(PSNB), as a percentage of national income and in £ billion
Time period
Average error
Average error
(% of national income)
(£bn)
One year ahead
1.0
11.6
Two years ahead
1.7
18.7
Three years ahead
2.2
25.0
Four years ahead
3.1
34.0
Notes: Figures in £ billion are calculated assuming HM Treasury GDP forecast for 2003–04 of
£1,111 billion. Average error corresponds to the average absolute error over the period 1977–
78 to 2002–03 for one year ahead, 1981–82 to 2002–03 for two years ahead, 1982–83 to
2002–03 (excluding 1996–97 to 1999–2000) for three years ahead, and 1983–84 to 2002–03
(excluding 1984–85 to 1986–87 and 1997–98 to 2000–01) for four years ahead. Figures are
based on HM Treasury data on average absolute error as a share of out-turn revenues and are
calculated as a share of national income using the average value of tax receipts as a share of
national income over the relevant period.
Sources: Table 2.8 of HM Treasury, End of Year Fiscal Report, London, December 2003
(www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr03/assoc_docs/prebud_pbr03_adend.cfm);
authors’ calculations.
14
Planning the public finances
When it comes to meeting the golden rule over the current cycle, the Treasury
may be particularly concerned that its one-year-ahead forecast errors have
been moving in a negative direction since the beginning of the current cycle.
As shown in Figure 2.5, the forecast was about 2% of national income too
pessimistic for 1999–2000, ½% too pessimistic in 2000–01, 1% too optimistic
in 2001–02 and 1½% too optimistic in 2002–03. If the Pre-Budget Report
forecast of a current deficit of 1.7% of national income in 2003–04 turns out to
be accurate, then the one-year-ahead forecast in last year’s Budget will also
turn out to have been almost 1% of national income too optimistic. Past
experience suggests that if a forecast is overoptimistic in one year, it is more
likely than not to be overoptimistic in the following year too.16
Figure 2.5. One-year-ahead, five-month-ahead and actual current budget
balances as a percentage of national income
Previous year’s Budget
Pre-Budget Report
Actual
Percentage of national income
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
1999-2000
2000-01
2001-02
2002-03
2003-04
Financial year
Source: HM Treasury, various Budgets and Pre-Budget Reports.
Errors in forecasting the cumulative budget surplus over an economic cycle
can arise from three sources:
•
errors in forecasting the path and composition of economic activity (and
therefore the impact of the automatic stabilisers);
•
errors in forecasting tax revenues and spending for any given level and
composition of national income; and
•
errors in estimating the level and growth rate of trend output. Such errors
can affect the estimated timing of the economic cycle and the assessment
of the underlying strength of the public finances.
Errors in forecasting economic growth are relatively unimportant in explaining
the Treasury’s errors in forecasting the budget balance over a horizon of at
16
See chart 2.4 of HM Treasury, End of Year Fiscal Report, December 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr03/assoc_docs/prebud_pbr03_adend.cfm).
15
Green Budget, January 2004
least up to four years.17 The present year’s current budget deficit, for example,
seems likely to be significantly larger than the Treasury predicted at the time
of the April 2003 Budget even though the Treasury’s forecasts for economic
growth have been relatively accurate.
In recent Budgets and Pre-Budget Reports, the Treasury has taken pains to
demonstrate that it plans the outlook for the public finances in a deliberately
cautious way. First, although the Treasury believes that the UK’s trend rate of
output growth is 2¾%, the figure of 2½% is used in projections of the public
finances. The intention is to avoid repeating the experience of the late 1980s,
when a move into budget surplus was misinterpreted by the Treasury and
many other forecasters as a structural improvement in the public finances
rather than the by-product of an unsustainable boom in economic activity.
In previous Budgets and Pre-Budget Reports, the Treasury also ‘stress-tested’
the public finance projections against a ‘cautious case’ in which the level of
trend output was 1% lower than the central estimate. Such a reduction in the
trend level of output would increase the share of past budget surpluses
attributable to the cyclical strength of economic activity and reduce the share
attributable to the underlying health of the public finances. Having predicted
in every Pre-Budget Report and Budget since November 199818 that the
golden rule would still be met on this basis, the Treasury conceded in the
December 2003 PBR that ‘the average surplus on the current budget in the
cautious case is no longer positive’, arguing in mitigation that this level of
caution was no longer necessary with the end of the cycle drawing closer.19
It is indeed reasonable to argue that if the government is focused on meeting
the golden rule over the current cycle, there is less need for caution as the end
of the cycle draws nearer and uncertainty about the path of the public finances
over the remainder of the cycle diminishes. But it could be argued that the
Treasury has used up too much of its room for manoeuvre too quickly. With
two-and-a-half years of the current seven-year cycle still to go, and having
made overoptimistic forecasts three years running, the Treasury now expects
the golden rule to be overachieved over the whole cycle by an amount smaller
than its average error when forecasting an annual budget deficit two years
ahead. In addition, the Treasury concedes that the golden rule will no longer
be met if the negative output gap is one percentage point smaller than its
current estimate of 1.4% of potential output – at a time when the International
Monetary Fund estimates that the output gap is in fact only 0.75% of potential
output. So on the Treasury’s own figures, on the basis of past errors and
uncertainties, it is possible that further tax increases or reductions in public
spending might be necessary to meet the golden rule over the current cycle.
But is it sensible to judge whether policy is consistent with the golden rule by
focusing on what is essentially an arbitrary definition of the ‘current’ cycle? If
17
See table B13 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report, Cm. 4076, London, November 1998
(archive.treasury.gov.uk/pub/html/prebudgetNov98/index.html).
18
See, for example, chart 2.3, page 25 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report, Cm. 4076,
London, November 1998.
19
Paragraphs 2.71–2.74, pages 38–39 of the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.
16
Planning the public finances
the government made an average-sized overoptimistic forecast of the budget
deficit one year before the cycle was due to end, it would hardly seem sensible
to announce tax increases or spending cuts of more than £10 billion for one
year simply to ensure that the golden rule over that period was still on course
to be met. Cycles are a never-ending process and any point in time could be
seen as the end of one cycle and the beginning of the next. It is not obvious
that with public sector debt still below 40% of national income, the amount the
government can borrow between now and March 2006 should be determined
by the size of the surpluses it has run since April 1999. This backward-looking
approach places undue emphasis on the exact dating of the economic cycle
and on the legacy of previous fiscal policy decisions and external shocks,
rather than focusing on the future sustainability of the present policy stance.
Forward-looking assessment of the golden rule
The prominence the Chancellor has given to meeting the golden rule over the
current cycle means that the credibility of his long-term commitment to it may
be severely diminished if it is missed on this basis. But as a guide for sensible
policy-making, it is nonetheless better to ask whether existing tax rates and
spending plans are consistent with meeting the rule in the future, over some
appropriate medium-term time horizon, than over the current cycle. In the case
of monetary policy, the Bank of England does not try to ensure that consumer
price inflation averages 2% between two dates. Rather, the Bank sets interest
rates at a level that will be consistent with hitting the inflation target
approximately two years ahead. The emphasis is on the stability of future
inflation.
To assess whether policy is consistent with the golden rule looking forward,
one must evaluate the underlying health of the public finances. The underlying
position is judged by adjusting the current budget balance for the state of the
economy, i.e. by asking what the current budget balance would be if national
income were at its sustainable level, with an output gap of zero. If this
‘cyclically adjusted’ balance is in deficit and expected to remain so on existing
policies, then those policies are unlikely to be consistent with meeting the
golden rule looking forward. The cyclically adjusted current balance is shown
alongside the actual current balances in Figure 2.6. This shows that:
•
following the fiscal tightening of fiscal policy in the 1981 Budget, the
deficits on the current budget seen in the early 1980s were due to poor
economic performance rather than to a structural weakness in the public
finances;
•
the move into surplus in the late 1980s reflected the economic boom rather
than a structural improvement in the fiscal position;
•
fiscal policy was loosened in the run-up to the 1992 election, resulting in
even larger deficits than would have occurred anyway as a result of the
recession of the early 1990s;
•
fiscal policy was then tightened significantly and consistently from 1993 to
1999; and
•
fiscal policy was then loosened again after 1999, when the current Labour
government began to increase public spending more rapidly.
17
Green Budget, January 2004
Figure 2.6. Current budget surplus as a percentage of national income
8
Percentage of national income
Actual
6
HM Treasury December 2003 Pre-Budget Report forecast
4
Cyclically adjusted surplus
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
78–79
81–82
84–85
87–88
90–91
93–94
96–97
99–00
02–03
05–06
08–09
Financial year
Note: Measures exclude the windfall tax and associated spending.
Sources: December 2003 Pre-Budget Report; HM Treasury, Public Finances Databank,
November 2003, London, 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//95B19/PublicFinancesDatabank241103.XLS).
Figure 2.7. Predictions of the cyclically adjusted current budget balance,
taken from various Pre-Budget Reports and Budgets
Percentage of national income
2.5
Budget 02
2.0
PBR 02
Budget 03
1.5
PBR 03
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
1999- 2000- 2001- 2002- 2003- 2004- 2005- 2006- 2007- 20082000
01
02
03
04
05
06
07
08
09
Financial year
Source: HM Treasury, various Budgets and Pre-Budget Reports.
The Treasury now expects fiscal policy to tighten again over the next five
years, moving from a cyclically adjusted current budget deficit this year of
0.8% of national income (the largest since Labour came to power) to a surplus
of 0.6% in 2008–09. As Figure 2.7 illustrates, over the last 18 months, the
Treasury has been forced regularly to revise down its forecast for the
cyclically adjusted current budget balance in 2003–04, but it has always
18
Planning the public finances
maintained that on existing policies, the underlying fiscal position would be
back in healthy surplus by the end of its forecasting period. On the face of it,
this suggests that current tax rates and spending plans are more than consistent
with meeting the golden rule looking forward. The projections in the PBR do
not necessarily show the expected path that the Treasury will choose to take.
For that, we have to wait until the Budget. But it has given little indication that
it believes a smaller tightening would be appropriate.
Whether or not the current policy stance is consistent with the golden rule
looking forward depends on whether one believes that the fiscal position will
strengthen as strongly and as quickly as the Treasury believes on the basis of
existing policies, above and beyond any improvement arising from stronger
economic growth. As we discuss in Chapter 3, this prediction may be unduly
reliant on ambitious forecasts for tax receipts.
Even if one accepts the Treasury’s forecasts, it is important to be clear what
the assumption of ‘existing’ spending and tax policies that underlies them
implies. For spending, it implies that the steady rise in government current
expenditure (including depreciation) from around 37% to 40% of national
income seen since April 1999 comes to a halt this year and that the share is
held roughly constant at just under 40% over the forthcoming spending review
period and into 2008–09. The absence of a further significant increase in
current spending on this measure underlines the pressure facing the
government to deliver noticeable improvements in the quality of public
services on existing levels of resources (which we discuss in Chapter 7). By
contrast, public sector net investment is expected to continue rising from 1.6%
to 2.2% of national income. This implies that total public spending would
continue to rise as a share of national income, but much less quickly than over
the past five years.
Only a small fraction of the rise in current spending is due to the economic
cycle. The forecast rise in current spending as a share of national income from
April 1999 to March 2009 is 2.9% of national income while the increase in the
cyclically adjusted figure is 2.7% of national income. Figure 2.8 shows
cyclically adjusted current receipts and current expenditure as shares of
national income. (The difference between the two series is the cyclically
adjusted current budget surplus shown in Figure 2.6.) It is clear that the recent
increases in current spending largely reflect policy decisions, not economic
circumstances.
For taxation, following a sharp drop in the share of national income taken in
tax between 2000–01 and 2002–03, the government is now expecting receipts
to rise by more than 2% of national income over the next five years, exceeding
40% for the first time since the late 1980s. Figure 2.8 shows that little of the
projected rise in current receipts, like that of current expenditure as a share of
national income, reflects the impact of the expected cyclical recovery in
economic activity. Adjusted for the economic cycle, current receipts are
projected to rise from 38.3% to 40.4% of national income over the next five
years. This partly reflects economic factors that are not captured in
conventional cyclical adjustment, such as rebounds in receipts from taxes that
were depressed by the stock market slump and an expected ‘rebalancing’ of
the composition of economic growth towards elements that are relatively
19
Green Budget, January 2004
highly taxed (such as consumer spending). Over the long term, such factors
should not be expected to affect the share of national income taken in tax. The
cyclically adjusted increase in current receipts also reflects the government’s
efforts to collect more of the tax that it believes it is due – for example, by
cracking down on VAT fraud and avoidance. The government believes that in
2001–02, it should have collected about £10 billion more in VAT revenue than
it did, given existing rates and rules.20
Figure 2.8. Cyclically adjusted current receipts and current expenditure
as a percentage of national income
Percentage of national income
42.0
Cyclically adjusted current receipts
41.0
Cyclically adjusted current expenditure
40.0
39.0
38.0
37.0
36.0
1996-97
1998-99
2000-01
2002-03
2004-05
2006-07
2008-09
Year
Notes: Current expenditure includes spending to offset depreciation. The cyclically adjusted
figures for public sector current expenditure and current receipts were obtained using the
‘ready reckoner’ formula in table A5 of HM Treasury, End of Year Fiscal Report, December
2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr03/assoc_docs/prebud_pbr03_adend.cfm).
Source: HM Treasury website and December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.
The most important source of increased future revenue is fiscal drag (which
we discuss in more detail in Chapter 4). The Treasury assumes in forecasting
the public finances that tax allowances and thresholds rise in line with retail
prices. But earnings typically rise more quickly, which means that this
assumption about allowances and thresholds implies a continuous rise in the
share taken in income tax as more people find larger proportions of their
income being taxed at higher rates. The impact of this is shown in the PBR:
the Treasury forecasts that gross income tax receipts will increase from 11.1%
of national income in 2005–06 to 11.6% of national income in 2008–09
despite the economy being at trend and no other discretionary tax changes in
the pipeline. Left unchecked, fiscal drag would see the share of national
income taken in income tax rise steadily for a considerable time.
20
Source: HM Customs and Excise, Measuring Indirect Tax Losses, London, November 2002
(www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media//F7505/admeas02-297kb.pdf).
20
Planning the public finances
In a trivial sense, ‘existing’ policies therefore clearly imply that the golden
rule will be met in the future, thanks to fiscal drag. But, as the Long-Term
Public Finance Report that accompanied the PBR acknowledges, this is
unrealistic, and the Treasury therefore assumes that revenues and their
composition remain broadly unchanged as shares of national income over the
longer term.21 This implies ‘a comprehensive form of “real indexation”’,22
which presumably means tax allowances and thresholds rising more in line
with earnings than with prices. The Treasury may indeed believe that, over the
short to medium term, exploiting fiscal drag is the most sensible way to raise
the extra revenues that it requires to meet the golden rule looking forward. But
one should be clear that this would be a policy choice and not an economically
neutral assumption. There are other ways that the revenue could be raised.
Overall, the level of current expenditure as a share of national income is now
almost the same as it was in 1996–97, when Labour had just come to power.
Given the Chancellor’s commitment to meet his golden rule, and the fact that
current spending is forecast to remain at this level, this implies that revenues
as a share of national income need to be higher than they were in 1996–97. So
far, tax revenues have not been sufficient to finance the significant increase in
public spending and continue to meet the Chancellor’s golden rule looking
forwards. Borrowing has therefore been higher and fiscal policy looser. This
has helped lift some of the burden of sustaining economic growth in the UK
from monetary policy. But continuing this higher level of borrowing is not
compatible with the Chancellor’s golden rule, so the share of national income
taken in tax is set to rise significantly over the next five years to finance the
increase in spending we are seeing. The PBR projections make it clear that
current receipts will have to rise relative to national income if the Chancellor
wishes to meet the golden rule with the margin of comfort he has sought in the
past. Should the economy not deliver the expected increase in tax receipts,
then announcements of further tax increases, or reductions in currently
anticipated levels of public spending, would be needed for this to remain the
case.
Assessing whether the sustainable investment rule is met
As long as the golden rule is met, then the sustainable investment rule seems
unlikely to impose a binding constraint on the government’s ability to spend
without announcements of further tax increases in the medium term. Figure
2.9 shows public sector net debt as a share of national income from 1974–75
to 2008–09. This has declined steadily from 43.7% of national income in
March 1997, just before Labour took office, to 30.2% of national income in
March 2002. Net debt is set to rise over the next six years to 35.5% of national
income in March 2009, according to the Treasury’s plans for receipts and
spending. But assuming that the golden rule is met, the government would still
be able to spend an additional one-off 4.5% of national income on public
21
Source: Paragraph 6.17, page 50 of HM Treasury, Long-Term Public Finance Report:
Fiscal Sustainability with an Ageing Population, London, December 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//555E2/longterm_fiscal_1to6_436.pdf).
22
Source: ibid., paragraph 6.18.
21
Green Budget, January 2004
sector net investment before breaching the sustainable investment rule. Given
that public sector net investment is forecast to rise to just 2.2% of national
income in 2008–09, such a large additional investment spend is unlikely.
Figure 2.9. Public sector net debt as a percentage of national income
Percentage of national income
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
74–75 77–78 80–81 83–84 86–87 89–90 92–93 95–96 98–99 01–02 04–05 07–08
Financial year
Source: Pages 204 and 236 of the December 2003 Pre-Budget Report.
Capital spending under the Private Finance Initiative
In addition to public sector capital investment, some capital spending is
undertaken by private firms on behalf of the public sector by means of the
Public Finance Initiative (PFI). Under the PFI, the public sector pays private
firms a rental price for use of a capital asset that the private sector delivers. In
the absence of the PFI, the public sector would have had to undertake the
accumulation of the capital itself, leading to higher debt if this were financed
through borrowing as would be allowable under the golden rule.
Figure 2.10 compares the Treasury’s projections of public sector net debt with
the path that would have been seen if all PFI deals since 1990–91 had been
conventionally financed through borrowing. By March 2006, public sector net
debt would be 3.4 percentage points of national income higher, leaving the
ratio of public sector net debt to national income just 2 percentage points
below the ‘stable and prudent’ ceiling of 40% of national income. Given that
public sector net debt is forecast to rise from 34.6% of national income in
2005–06 to 35.5% in 2008–09, and that the value of capital spending carried
out under the PFI is likely to increase between now and 2008–09, it seems
possible that by the end of the current planning period, adding PFI spending
could push public sector net debt above the 40% of national income ceiling.
But the Chancellor might reasonably argue that if he had intended to include
PFI spending, he would have set the ceiling higher.23
23
For a more detailed discussion see chapter 2, pages 13–17 of R. Chote, C. Emmerson and H.
Simpson, The IFS Green Budget: January 2003, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, 2003
(www.ifs.org.uk/gb2003/ch2.pdf).
22
Planning the public finances
Figure 2.10. Public sector net debt (PSND) as a percentage of national
income
Percentage of national income
80.0
PSND plus capital spending carried out under the PFI
70.0
Public sector net debt
60.0
50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
0.0
1990-91
1993-94
1996-97
1999-2000
2002-03
2005-06
Financial year
Notes: The figures for capital spending under the PFI prior to 2003–04 are adjusted from a
calendar-year basis.
Source: Figures up to March 2003 are taken from chart 2.3, page 7 of HM Treasury,
Departmental Investment Strategies: A Summary, Cm. 5674, London, December 2002
(www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media//343A6/dis_whitepaper02.pdf). Figures thereafter are taken
from table C18, page 272 of the 2003 Budget.
Private Finance Initiative payments are not the only set of liabilities that do
not count as public sector net debt that might be faced by the government. For
example, the government has underwritten some bonds issued by London
Continental Railway relating to the Channel Tunnel Rail Link but has not
scored this as borrowing, on the basis that the probability that the guarantee
will be called is low.24 There is also the issue of whether borrowing carried out
by Network Rail should be considered similar to conventional government
borrowing. This depends on the likelihood that Network Rail would fail
without increased support and, in this eventuality, that the government would
offer financial support to ensure that the company survived.25 A measure of
public sector indebtedness that did incorporate all these contingent liabilities
might well exceed 40% of national income. While this would breach the
ceiling for public sector net debt under the sustainable investment rule, the
arbitrariness of the 40% limit, and the low level of debt relative to other
countries and historical standards, mean that this is unlikely to affect any
fundamental assessment of the sustainability of the UK government’s
finances.
24
See page 34 of HM Treasury, Public Private Partnerships: The Government’s Approach,
The Stationery Office, London, 2000 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/80.pdf).
25
For more information on the classification of Network Rail, see
www.statistics.gov.uk/about/Methodology_by_theme/rail_network/default.asp.
23
Green Budget, January 2004
2.2 The Maastricht Treaty fiscal rules
Alongside the two fiscal rules described earlier in the chapter, the UK is also
subject to further constraints on its debt and deficit as a signatory of the
Maastricht Treaty. According to a protocol of the Maastricht Treaty, general
government gross debt must be kept at below 60% of national income, while
countries should have a medium-term objective of running a budget balance.
The general government deficit should not exceed 3% of national income
except under exceptional circumstances. Both these rules measure deficits and
debt on a different basis from the UK’s two fiscal rules and some caution
needs to be taken in comparing them. Nevertheless, it is clear that the
requirement that the general government deficit should be at or below zero
over the medium term and that it not exceed 3% is a stronger requirement than
the golden rule, its public sector equivalent in the UK’s fiscal rules. In
particular, it does not allow for ongoing borrowing for investment purposes as
the golden rule does.
According to the December 2003 PBR forecasts, the deficit on the Maastricht
basis is expected to be 3.3% in 2003–04 and 2.6% in 2004–05.26 So the UK
will almost certainly be in breach of the Maastricht limit this year and, given
the large average errors associated with planning the public finances (see
Section 2.1), could breach the limits again next year. Although the UK reports
deficits and debt levels to the European Commission twice annually under the
Excessive Deficits Procedure of the Maastricht Treaty, there is no provision
for any action to be taken by the Commission if the limits are missed. As such,
the Chancellor is able to continue to borrow on the terms allowable by his own
rules, despite the possibility of being in breach of the Maastricht criteria he has
also signed up to. Until the UK decides to join the Euro (if, indeed, it ever
does), its breach of the Maastricht criteria is of little consequence either to the
Chancellor or to other member states.
A decision by the UK government to join the Euro might, in principle,
increase the importance of the Maastricht rules. In practice, countries have
been able to join the Euro despite being in breach of these rules. Table 2.2
shows government borrowing and debt for the 15 EU countries in 2002 and
1998. It shows that while all Euro countries were within the 3% limit in 199827
– the last year before the final stage of Euro entry – a number of countries that
joined the Euro in 1999 were in breach of the debt rule. It was argued that as
long as they were able to demonstrate falling debt, they should not be denied
entry to the single currency.
Table 2.2 also shows debt and deficit levels for 2002. The countries that are
Euro members are now bound by the Stability and Growth Pact, which
contains the same debt and deficit rules but includes the provision for
monetary fines by the European Council if these are breached. In 2002, both
France and Germany were in contravention of the deficit rule, and they are
26
Although the Maastricht criteria are discussed on calendar-year terms, the UK is assessed
according to its usual financial years.
27
With the exception of Luxembourg, which qualified as being close to the limit.
24
Planning the public finances
expected to have missed it in 2003 and to miss it in 2004. Both have
successfully avoided facing the fines despite not being able to claim the
mitigating circumstances of a ‘severe’ recession.
Table 2.2. Public finances across the EU as a percentage of national
income
2002
Public balance
–0.2
0.1
2.1
4.2
–3.1
–3.5
–1.2
–0.2
–2.3
2.5
–1.6
–2.7
0.1
1.3
–1.5
–0.4
Debt
67.3
105.8
45.5
42.7
59.0
60.8
104.7
32.4
106.7
5.7
52.4
58.1
53.8
52.7
38.5
59.1
1998
Public balance
–2.4
–0.7
1.1
1.5
–2.7
–2.2
–2.5
2.4
–2.8
3.1
–0.8
–2.6
–2.7
1.8
0.2
–0.6
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Ireland
Italy
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
United Kingdom
Unweighted EU
average
Weighted EU average
–1.9
62.3
–1.6
Unweighted Eurozone
–0.7
62.5
–1.0
Weighted Eurozone
–2.2
69.0
–2.2
Source: Eurostat, EC Economic Data Pocket Book, no. 07-0/8/2003
(europa.eu.int/comm/eurostat/Public/datashop/printcatalogue/EN?catalogue=Eurostat&product=KS-CZ-03-000-3A-N-EN).
Debt
63.7
119.6
56.2
48.6
59.5
60.9
105.8
54.9
116.3
6.3
66.8
55
64.6
68
47.6
66.3
68.7
68.5
73.5
In any event, the decision not to censure France and Germany for their
consecutive breaches of the 3% deficit limit means that the Stability and
Growth Pact has, in effect, been suspended. How the rules might be applied or
developed in the future is not yet known, but it is possible that there would no
longer be pressure on the UK to reduce its borrowing because of its European
commitments.
2.3 A third fiscal rule: more active
stabilisation
By requiring achievement of the golden rule over an economic cycle rather
than every year, the current fiscal framework gives free rein to the automatic
stabilisers. The government can borrow to finance current expenditure during
economic downturns provided that it runs offsetting current budget surpluses
when national output is running above potential. This helps to limit swings in
economic activity, although stabilisation is primarily the responsibility of the
Bank of England. The Bank in effect uses monetary policy to keep the output
gap as near to zero as possible once inflation is on course to hit its target.
25
Green Budget, January 2004
Joining the Euro would mean accepting the interest rate set by the European
Central Bank (ECB) for the Eurozone as a whole. The UK accounts for a
relatively small proportion of Eurozone economic activity, so there is no
guarantee that the rate set by the ECB would stabilise economic activity in this
country. The Treasury is therefore exploring the possibility of more active use
of fiscal policy to stabilise the domestic economy if the UK joins the Euro.
Even if the UK does not join the Euro, a more active stabilisation policy could
be considered desirable.
One possibility would be to make the automatic stabilisers more powerful –
for example, by increasing social security benefits or making tax rates more
progressive (so that a given increase in economic activity produced a larger
increase in tax payments than is currently the case). But this could conflict
with the government’s other objectives for redistribution and/or incentives.
Alternatively, the government could use fiscal policy more actively in a
discretionary way to support activity during downturns and to dampen it
during booms. But given the failures of past attempts at fiscal stabilisation, the
government is keen for people to believe that such a policy would be
symmetric – in other words, that the government would be as keen to tighten
policy in the good times as it would be to loosen it in bad times. Fiscal
Stabilisation and EMU, published by the Treasury alongside the assessment of
the five Euro tests,28 proposes a third fiscal rule which would mandate a
temporary fiscal policy response whenever economic activity diverged by a
given amount from its sustainable level in either direction. Possible policy
tools might include changes in VAT or excise duty rates, or – if the swings in
the economy are being driven by the housing market – in rates of stamp duty
for property transactions.
Whether or not such a rule would be helpful depends on a number of factors,
including:
•
whether or not explicitly temporary tax changes would have a significant
or predictable impact on economic activity;
•
whether or not people would anticipate the triggering of the rule and alter
their behaviour in a way that would exacerbate rather than ameliorate
swings in activity;
•
whether or not the rule would be credible – and therefore whether people
would believe that the ‘temporary’ tax changes would in fact be reversed
when activity returned towards trend;
•
whether or not the government is confident enough of its estimates of the
output gap to believe that the rule would be triggered at appropriate times;
and
•
whether or not the operation of such a rule would be consistent with the
government’s commitments under the Excessive Deficits Procedure of the
Stability and Growth Pact. If the procedure did not permit greater
28
HM Treasury, Fiscal Stabilisation and EMU, London, June 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/documents/the_euro/assessment/studies/euro_assess03_studherefordshire.cfm
).
26
Planning the public finances
borrowing when economic activity is depressed, then the activation of the
new rule might well be inconsistent with the budget deficit limits laid
down in the procedure.
2.4 Conclusions
If the Treasury’s public finance projections are correct, then both fiscal rules
will be met over the economic cycle that is predicted to run from April 1999 to
March 2006. But its room for manoeuvre is greatly diminished: the cumulative
surplus on the current budget that the Treasury expects is just £4½ billion or
£14 billion depending on how it is calculated. Either way, this is less than the
average absolute error that the Treasury has made in the past in forecasting
public borrowing two years hence. An upward revision to borrowing before
March 2006 of the magnitude seen in recent projections would necessitate
substantial tax increases or spending cuts if the golden rule is to be met over
the current economic cycle.
A better interpretation of whether current fiscal policy is consistent with the
golden rule is to look at projections for receipts and spending in future years.
The Treasury’s public finance projections suggest that over the period 2003–
04 to 2008–09, current spending will remain just below 40% of national
income while receipts will grow from 38.1% of national income in 2003–04 to
40.4% in 2008–09. If these forecasts prove correct, then the golden rule will
continue to be met looking forwards. Should the economy not deliver the
expected increase in tax receipts as a share of national income, then the
Chancellor will have to announce further tax-raising measures or cuts in his
existing tentative spending plans to expect to meet the golden rule with the
degree of comfort he has sought in the past.
Robert Chote, Carl Emmerson, Christine Frayne and Sarah Love
27
Download