Economic Change in Global History, 1500-2000 International Workshop co-organised by the Economic History Department, London School of Economics and the Global History and Culture Centre, University of Warwick London School of Economics 27-28 May 2016 The origins of the international economy is a central question for comparative economic history. In the past, major works in the field constructed arguments by studying mainly Western Europe and North America from the nineteenth century to the present times. In the last decade, the field of global economic history has contributed path-breaking new research on Asia, Africa, and Latin America, and has pushed the boundaries of the debate at least a hundred years further back from the nineteenth century. The divergence literature has also highlighted at least three different modes of doing global economic history, which draw on each other but also maintain a certain distance and autonomy from each other. One of these is comparative history and deals with mainstream questions in economic and business history, such as, whether pre-modern commerce led to modern economic growth or not, and why its growth potentials varied in quality and scale between regions. This part of global history has seen animated debates in the recent times, joined often by applied economists, but it often involves working with simplified models of the pre-modern economy. A second paradigm in global history deals with commercial linkages as such, and goes to great lengths to show the diversity and complexity of these linkages. A fine example of this paradigm is the scholarship on Indian Ocean trade, which has shown how the Indian Ocean trading world contained many sub-regional trading worlds within it, before the advent of the European chartered companies in the region. If the former is comparative history, the latter can be called history of connections. A third paradigm yet engages in both comparisons and connections, but from the vantage point of specific world regions. Such works explore connections and tests models of divergence mainly by re-examining the evidence of specific regions, which can be very large and complex entities in themselves. This workshop brings together a group of scholar to consider these different methodological perspectives to the study of economic change over the longue durée. This workshop is supported by the Economic History Society, the LSE Economic History Department, the Warwick History Department and the Warwick Global History and Culture Centre. Thursday 26 May 2016 19.30 - Dinner Friday 27 May 9.00-9.20 - Introduction Globalization and Economic Change in History – Tirthankar Roy and Giorgio Riello 9.20-11.20 – Session 1. Divergence in Global History (I) Prasannan Parthasarathi (Boston College) and Kenneth Pomeranz (Chicago University), The Great Divergence Debate Jack Goldstone (Hong Kong University of Science and Technology), A Revolution in Two Steps: Great Reversals in World History Maarten Prak (Utrecht University) and Regina Grafe (EUI), State Formation and Empire: The construction of institutions for economic growth 11.20-11.40 - Coffee Break 11.40-13.00 – Session 2. The Emergence of a World Economy (I) Tirthankar Roy (London School of Economics) and Giorgio Riello (University of Warwick), Trade and the Emergence of the World Economy Bernd-Stefan Grewe (Pädagogische Hochschule Freiburg), Global Commodities and Commodity Chains 13.00-14.00 - Lunch 14.00-16.00 – Session 3. Divergence in Global History (II) Kaoru Sugihara (National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies (GRIPS)), Varieties of Industrialization Maxine Berg (University of Warwick), Consumption and Global History Patrick O'Brien (London School of Economics), Technology and Useful and Reliable Knowledge 16.00-16.30 – Coffee break 16.30-18.30 – Regional Perspectives to Global Economic Change (I) Gareth Austin (Cambridge University), Sub-Saharan Africa Alejandra Irigoin (London School of Economics), The Americas Peer Vries (University of Vienna), Europe 19.30 - Dinner Saturday 28 May 9.00-10.20 – Session 4. The Emergence of a World Economy (II) Alessandro Stanziani (EHESS), Migration and Labour Regimes John McNeill (Georgetown University), The Environment and the World Economy 10.20-10.50 – Coffee break 10.50-12.50 – Regional Perspectives to Global Economic Change (II) J. Thomas Lindblad (Leiden University), Changing Destinies in the Economy of Southeast Asia Debin Ma (London School of Economics), Economic Change in East Asia in 1700-1950 Bishnu Gupta (University of Warwick), Colonization and Structural Change in India 13.00-13.30 – Final discussion 13.30 - Lunch ORGANISERS Tirthankar Roy, LSE, t.roy@lse.ac.uk Giorgio Riello, Warwick, g.riello@warwick.ac.uk PARTICIPANTS Gareth Austin, Cambridge University Maxine Berg, University of Warwick Jack Goldstone, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Regina Grafe, EUI Bernd-Stefan Grewe, Pädagogische Hochschule Freiburg Bishnu Gupta, University of Warwick Pat Hudson, Cardiff University Alejandra Irigoin, LSE J. Thomas Lindblad, Leiden University Debin Ma, LSE John McNeill, Georgetown University Prasannan Parthasarathi, Boston College Marteen Prak, Utrecht University Patrick O'Brien, LSE Alessandro Stanziani, EHESS Kaoru Sugihara, Tokyo University Peer Vries, University of Vienna ABSTRACTS State Formation and Empire: the construction of institutions for economic growth - Maarten Prak and Regina Grafe The fundamental question addressed in this chapter is, which role social norms, economic organisations, and political institutions played in the construction of political forms of governance and in turn how the polities thus constituted favoured or hindered economic growth across different parts of the globe. We envisage looking at the interplay between institutions and economic growth at three deeply interrelated levels. The first one encompasses mostly social and religious norms that regulate individual and family behaviour, including reproduction, economic strategies, or identity formation. To give but one example, Greif has argued that family structures that tended to impose a logic of collective behaviour in Asia and the Middle East, placed these societies in the very long run at an economic disadvantage vis-avis Western European family norms, which favoured individualistic behaviour. Other themes include religious attitudes to lending and wealth preservation. The second level looks at the written and unwritten rules, laws and the organisations they underpinned supported economic growth in the short, medium and long run. Thus, an intense debate exists about the role of trading diasporas and mercantile companies or guilds in fostering commercial expansion. Equally contested is how diverse ways of organising the crafts mostly across Eurasia impacted on skill formation and transmission, social welfare of workers, and inequality. Finally, the third level looks at political governance proper. Can we observe a systematic relationship between forms of political organisation, city states, territorial states, empires, and their ability and willingness to foster economic and social development? Was state capacity a necessary condition for growth? What determined legal and fiscal capacity to use the terms of Besley and Persson? Finally, can we historically observe why some societies seem to enter a virtuous cycles of institutional development and growth, while others seem trapped in the opposite predicament. Varieties of Industrialization - Kaoru Sugihara This chapter considers types of industrialization, which took place in different parts of the world, especially in Western Europe, East Asia and South Asia, in comparative perspective. The approach adopted is a reciprocal and multi-polar one, and takes all three regional patterns as substantially “autonomous”, in the sense that each region had an ability to respond to its local resource constraints such as the availability of land, water and energy resources, as well as the quality of labour, essentially in accordance with its own values and norms. While the scientific revolution in Western Europe was accompanied by a set of modern norms and values, and the industrial revolution in England enabled the exploitation of fossil fuels, incorporating vast resources of North America into the orbit of the high-wage, resource-intensive economy and raising the standard of living to a new height, land-scarce parts of East Asia (Japan and core regions of China) exhibited quite a different kind of response to industrial technology and modern institutions, leading to a labour-intensive and often resource-saving type of industrialization. The norms and values which drove the peasant household in Meiji Japan, from which an industrial workforce was drawn, paid more attention to general, managerial and interpersonal skills than to special, technical and individual ones, in order to work a small plot of land. The level of labour productivity did not match the West, but labour was comparably disciplined. Meanwhile, South Asia, handicapped by the poor quality of land and the high variability of annual and seasonal water supply but equipped with social norms and institutions to hold a very large population, took longer to proceed with industrialization. However, it now appears set to take advantage of abundant labour supply of an improved quality and rich stock of knowledge of negotiating with the diversity and uncertainty of nature. The chapter argues for the importance of understanding of global industrialization from a multi-polar perspective by appreciating vast regional differences in resource endowment and equally impressive social capacities to respond to them. It is a vital step towards understanding what entails to address the issues of global environmental sustainability. A Revolution in Two Steps: Great Reversals in World History – Jack Goldstone Attention has recently focused on the causes and timing of the “Great Divergence.” Yet “Divergence” is misleading; it suggests initial parity followed by sustained and growing difference. This is NOT the pattern of world history. Instead that pattern is one of repeated reversals, with initial divergence followed by convergence and inversion: the center of Europe’s growth shifted from the eastern Mediterranean and northern Italy to the Atlantic, then to the northwest, with England and the Netherlands moving from far behind to far ahead. Shortly thereafter this “little reversal” was followed by a “great reversal,” in which the leading manufacturing and imperial powers of the world economy – India and China – were left behind by the manufacturing and military rise of Britain. This great reversal was not final either; Britain was surpassed by two powers originally behind it: first Germany, then the United States. Today, the United States’ growth rate is far surpassed by that of China, and at some point it will inevitably fall behind in total economic output as well. In sum, world history shows a pattern of repeated reversals in global power, driven by the “Advantages of backwardness” and “satisfactions of success.” The Industrial Revolution was the most dramatic of such reversals, and had the greatest impact on the long-term increase of GDP; but it did not change this overall long-term pattern. Trade and the Emergence of a World Economy, 1600-1960 – Tirthankar Roy and Giorgio Riello The chapter will review four major themes that underlie the transformation of the world economy in the early modern and modern era. It will consist of fourth sections. The first section will present an overview of scale, commodity composition, and chronology, focusing especially on transoceanic trade of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries and the first wave of globalization. The narrative part will end with the mid-twentieth century decolonization, and that process reshaped the world trading order. The second section will discuss business history, in particular, the role of the East India Companies, European private firms, kinship groups and communities. It will draw lessons on the institutional foundations of commercialization. The third section will present a review of historiography. The section will touch on the significance of commercialization for economic growth in individual regions, and discuss the factor price literature on industrialization and deindustrialization (Jeffrey Williamson, for example). This discussion will also consider other growth-and-inequality-centred concepts connected with the history of world trade, such as, industrious revolution, world systems versus regional systems, and geographical constraints on trade. The fourth section will deal with a major theme in the history of trade, the link between Empire and globalization. A series of works in imperial history in recent years has traced the prehistory of the first wave of globalization in imperialism, especially British imperialism and the spread of settler societies (books written or edited by C.A. Bayly, John Darwin, James Belich, A.G. Hopkins, Niall Ferguson, among others, are examples). Others synthesizing this scholarship propose that the networks of exchange had a distinctly cultural aspect, not only in emphasizing British identity where there was scope to do so, but also in the existence of networks of trust (Gary Magee and Andrew Thompson), as well as a political and institutional dimension in the shape of military and naval protection and a uniform legal framework. In turn, the reinterpretation of the empire as an agent of a particular form of globalization based more on politics, settlements, and ethnicity than on communication links as in the present times, had roots in an older scholarship on the economic history of the empire (P.J. Cain and A.G. Hopkins, Lance Davis and Robert Huttenback). Much of this literature is written from the perspective of the imperial nation, overwhelmingly Britain. This section of the chapter will survey this scholarship, while looking beyond Britain towards other empires and colonized regions. Global Commodities and Commodity Chains - Bernd-Stefan Grewe The world economy has changed in significant ways during the past two centuries and the global interconnections have become more evident in many fields, most visible perhaps in trade and transport. In many countries, the growing integration of the global economy has provided the opportunity for substantial economic and income growth. But the process of globalization always had a dark side and a tendency towards an imbalance of profits and poverty within and between countries. The global political economy and the international division of labour and profit as evolved in the second half of the 19 th century can be studied by following the historical pathway of commodities. Commodity chains can be traced from the raw material, the transportation mechanics and the labour input into each of the material process up to its marketing on markets that often had barriers to inhibit new actors to enter them. This commodity chain approach in its different varieties can help us to better understand the growing global inequality. This chapter will present some of these approaches that follow the historical chains of some commodities. It will openly discuss the advantages, but also the limitations of the commodity history approach. The Rise of Global Finance - Youssef Cassis This chapter will discuss the rise of global finance since the mid-nineteenth century –when international capital flows started their long upswing wave, which would continue until 1914 and even 1931; while new financial institutions and markets emerged in all advanced economies, in particular with the rise of the big banks and the development of the securities markets. In order to deal with these two interconnected trends, the chapter will be structured around the development of financial centres in both the core industrial countries and the periphery, paying attention to the differences/similarities as well as the interactions between them. The chapter will follow a chronological sequence in order to convey the dynamics of change brought about by economic forces (long-term economic growth, financial crises, financial innovations, etc.), political choices (regulation and deregulation, nationalisations and privatisations, etc.) and international relations (war and peace, colonisation and decolonisation, etc.). It will be divided in four main parts: the first modern globalisation from the 1860s to 1914; wars and depression, 1914-1945; growth and regulation, 1945-1980; and deregulation and globalisation, 1980-2008. An epilogue will consider the effects of the financial debacle of 2008, as well as the rise of new economic powers, above all China, on global finance. Migration and Labour Regimes - Alessandro Stanziani Since the eighteenth century, comparative analyses of labor institutions and labor markets have been developed as if the boundary between free and unfree labor were universally defined. Thus free labor in the West is frequently contrasted with serf labor in Russia, slaveries in the Atlantic, the Indian Ocean world, Africa and some Asiatic regions. This chapter intends to show: -1 that the historical definitions and practices of labor, labor relationships and mobility require to be reassessed and, -2 that the history of wage labor and that of slavery (and serfdom) are not distinct but are intimately linked and enter one single global process. In particular: Point 1. Between the mid-seventeenth century and WWI, in most Western countries labor was similar to service, and wage conditions resembled those of domestic servants, with numerous constraints imposed on work mobility. From the sixteenth to the end of the nineteenth century in Britain and Europe, free labor, even where a contract existed, was considered the property of the employer and a resource for the whole community to which the individual belonged. 1 bis One major implication of this point is that the long-term movement of labor and its rules hardly confirm the traditional argument that labor freedom supported the Industrial Revolution. On the contrary, the Industrial Revolution was accompanied by subjecting workers to increasingly tough regulations and punitive sanctions. Increasing legal constraints on labor— not increasing free wage labor—went hand in hand with the Industrial Revolution. 2 In colonies, a similar trend was at work: colonization and then plantation gave rise to extreme forms of dependency, not only under slavery, but also before and after it (e.g., white indentured labor in the 17th-18th centuries, then “colored” indentured immigration in the nineteenth century). 3 these institutions and practices were related. From the institutional perspective, the transmutation of villeinage, war captives, seamen, convicts into an imperial context supported the European (including Russian) expansion of the sixteenth through the early eighteenth centuries. Then, later, it would have been impossible to develop the indenture contract in the British Empire if the British wage earner had not been a servant, subject to the multiple Master and Servant Acts. The same was true for France. 3 These connections cannot be interpreted only as an influence of the “center” over the “periphery”. England or France sought to export their own notions and practices of labor into their colonies. Yet the outcome varied between, saying, northern American colonies, India and Africa. Those different issues require to be detailed and explained. For example, the evolution of labor relationships and jurisprudence in India influenced the evolution of the Masters and Servants Acts in Britain. After institutions, labor practices: 4 Why so many constraints on labor mobility? Unfree labor and forms of coercion were perfectly compatible with market development— economic growth between the seventeenth and the mid-nineteenth century in Russia, Europe, and the Indian Ocean region was achieved through the wide use of bondage and legal constraints on labor. This was not so because the population was somehow lacking for demographic crisis, but because, despite the increase in population, consistent labor intensive growth took place throughout Eurasia at that time. Family units, landlords, estate owners, proto-industrial and manufacturing employers, and state and public administrations all required labor. Quantitative evidence on labor/capital intensification not only in the colonial world and the plantation system or Russia, but also in Europe (including Britain until the mid-nineteenth century) will be added. 4 bis. There was a strong correspondence between labor intensive growth and rules limiting the mobility of labor between the mid-seventeenth and the end of the nineteenth century. Labor demand exceeded population increase and efforts to limit the mobility of labor and increase coercion were the response to this. Nominal wages smoothly increased but real wages did not progress until after 1870 (“pessimism perpetuated”, Allen, Feinstein). Yet, despite coercive rules, people did move. This was so because of the tensions and unfair competition between competing actors all seeking to retain labor without increasing wages: small and big estate owners; the state (for recruiting, colonization) and private actors; family units and landlords, or merchants; rural and urban world. The final issue between ambitions and real dynamics depended on the stickiness of labor markets, regional differentiation, technical solutions and political-institutional distribution of power. Issues were different not only (and not so much) in different countries, but also in different areas of the same country. Labor mobility and labor relationships in south-east England and the North was different, the same was true in Russia, India or North America. The final outcome in labor mobility must also be related to broader geo-political factors such as Empire building and Empire dislocation. 5 This world did not collapse with the French Revolution or the British Industrial Revolution, but only with the second Industrial Revolution and the rise of the welfare state, between 1870 and 1914 when “new” labor contract and eventually collective agreements were introduced in so many countries as France, England, Belgium, Italy, and Germany. 6 Origins of this shift: first, the political movements since the 1870s and increasing power of unions, then socialist parties altered the social and political equilibrium. This outcome added to the first raise of the welfare state in all the mentioned countries between 1875 and WWI. Both those processes increased the cost of labor and encouraged the adoption of labor saving processes. 7 Yet this process involved only a minority of workers in the West (mainly workers in large units), while small units, agriculture, and, above all, the European colonies were only marginally affected until the mid-twentieth century at the earliest. This selective welfare was one of the major origins of the violent conflicts and unrest of the twentieth century supported by artisans, small units, agrarian groups and the colonial world. Still nowadays, in Europe, the defense of the welfare state for Europeans and the free circulation of labor (mostly non-European immigrants) are seen as in opposition between them. The Environment and the World Economy - John McNeill This chapter will address a handful of the countless aspects of the linkage between economic globalization and environmental change. These include: (1) the global redistribution of useful crops and animals, and unhelpful diseases and weeds, resulting from the navigation of the high seas after 1492. This goes a bit beyond the Columbian Exchange (of A. Crosby) by including more African instances and more recent biological exchanges and invasions, especially those generated by shipping; (2) the environmental consequences of international markets for hides and furs in the 16th-18th centuries, drawing on the work of J.F. Richards; (3) the environmental implications of the creation and expansion of plantation economies, mainly in the American tropics after 1640; (4) the global environmental implications of industrialization, first in the UK, later elsewhere, including post-1980 in mainland E and SE Asia. This will concern raw materials such as cotton, wool, iron, tin, palm oil, bison hide, etc. (5) climate change and the global economy, including the impacts of the Little Ice Age upon economies, and the impact of industrial economies upon the climate; (6) a conclusion that ruminates on the concept of the Anthropocene. Sub-Saharan Africa - Gareth Austin Over the last seventy years, specialists in African history have challenged the traditional perception that economic change in the Sub-Saharan subcontinent was largely absent or essentially exogenous. Yet the old view continues to frame the way in which many social scientists view African issues. This is partly because the revisionist research has tended to be local in focus, whereas the older views have been restated at a general level, in the categories of successive theories (dependency and world systems, rational-choice institutionalism) that have themselves been used to re-dress (rather than redress) the narrative of European exceptionalism: against which Sub-Saharan Africa continues to be used as a convenient ‘other’. This chapter offers a broad description and analysis of economic change in the region, accepting the truism that environments and experiences have always varied greatly within it, but working towards a synthesis that does not treat the exceptional cases (notably Ethiopia, in several respects) not as mere outliers but seeks to integrate them within the explanation, as ‘proving the rule’. In placing Sub-Saharan Africa within the global history of economic change, the chapter will: 1. Highlight the overlapping perspectives of both comparison and (entangled) connection: asking about the distinctiveness and otherwise of African economic history, and what that history reveals about the sources of economic change in human history generally; while noting that, over many centuries, the strategies of African decision-makers (from households to ruling elites) in response to the domestic constraints that they faced often involved exploiting resources derived from other world regions. 2. Similarly, distinguish different timescales of change in African economic history (from the ‘conjunctures’ of colonization, decolonization and ‘Structural Adjustment’ to the very long-term, mostly cumulative struggle to overcome environmental obstacles to higher labour productivity, in pursuit of greater food security and prosperity), noting when the latter interact (as in the population take-off in the twentieth century, made possible by a very long-established set of cultural responses to age-old labour scarcity, but also by political and technological changes over a few decades). The Americas – Alejandra Irigoin Research in global history has been shaped in the last 15 years by the influence of the Great Divergence debate and the extraordinary development of China’s economy. This has helped to de-centre historical research away from Europe and to reframe her own history. It has also challenged narratives available for the early modern period more generally. A new scholarship of reciprocal comparisons now is changing the historiography of Africa, India, South East Asia and Europe. Paradoxically the Americas have been estranged from this debate as the historical research on –and from- the continent has withdrawn to an Atlantic World realm and economic historians have mostly focused on comparative legacies of factor endowments and political institutions within. Yet, as in the core of Pomeranz’ arguments, the Americas played a substantial role in setting off the divergent path of England, and Europe more generally, towards modern economic growth in the 19th century. In addition to relatively more favourable access to coal and the ‘ghost acreage’ that offered Europeans an escape forward from an otherwise inevitable Malthusian trap, the New World silver and crops obtained by means of a particular political economy of colonialism serve the argument for the European divergence. In that light the contribution that this recent research has brought to the understanding of early modern New World has been minimal. This interpretation suffers from the conventional - if slightly partial- characterization of the role of the New World in the period as merely a producer of food, fibres and silver with coerced forms of labour for the profit of their European metropolis. Little or nothing is said of her role as consumer; whereas paradoxically the American silver is presented as the prime mover of the expansion and integration of the early modern global economy there has not been an equivalent inquiry on the returns that the American mined bullion apportioned to these regions. Thus the Americas by 1800 remain absent –or partly mischaracterized- in the explanations for the early modern globalization. This chapter will re-introduce the region in the development of the great divergence and highlight the role of consumer of European and Asian goods, technologies and services – which together with African labour- flowed to the New World from both the Pacific and the Atlantic. This, it is argued, organized the establishment and settlement of Europeans in the New World. Bringing back the New World to global history of the pre-industrial period may well still shed new light on the various divergences that separate the early modern from the modern period. Economic Change in East Asia in 1700-1950 – Debin Ma Abstract: This chapter surveys main economic trends and economic changes during 1700-1950 in East Asia. It offers a brief survey of main existing political and economic institutions before 1850 and assesses the initial conditions on the eve of East Asia’s forced opening by the West. These assessments will be conducted in relation to the ongoing Great Divergence debate. The main part of the paper will be an assessment of economic modernization in Japan, China and Korea from the 1850s onward. Changing Destinies in the Economy of Southeast Asia - J. Thomas Lindblad This chapter focuses on the spectacular economic changes that have taken place in Southeast Asia from the late nineteenth century up to today. Three key themes are discussed: global connections of this region, the emergence of national economies within the region, and decisive shifts in terms of economic structure. The logical point of departure is the way in which the region was traditionally linked to the world economy. Then follows the establishment of colonial rule throughout the region (with the notable exception of Thailand), in turn facilitating the formation of cohesive national economies. The final stage is marked by a shift away from agriculture in favour of manufacturing and services in the aftermath of decolonization. As a result of such changes, the potential for rapid economic growth has increased substantially but so has the vulnerability to external shocks as became all too apparent during the Asian financial crisis in the late 1990s. Since the late nineteenth century, Southeast Asia’s position in the world economy has changed from being a loosely integrated supplier of raw materials in the periphery into becoming a self-assertive dynamic force at the forefront of economic development with considerable potential for further economic integration. Colonization and Structural Change in India – Bishnu Gupta The paper will look at the changing comparative advantage in India’s international trade. From being a major exporter of textile, under what conditions India became a net importer. I will focus not only on the effect of colonization and British trade policy, but also the effect of the industrial revolution on the handloom sector in a globalized world. The paper will discuss the nature of deindustrialization, but also the emergence of new industries that were facilitated by the colonial connection, such as tea and others like cotton textiles, which developed despite policies of free trade. The paper will analyse the changing structure of trade over the long nineteenth century.