Original Article A quantitative analysis of European port governance P a t r i c k V e r h o e v e n a,b a n d T h o m a s V a n o u t r i v e a,c d e p a r t m e n t o f T r a n s p o r t a n d R e g io n a l E c o n o m ic s , U n iv e r s ity of A n tw e rp , P r i n s s t r a a t 13, B -2 0 0 0 , A n tw e rp , B e lg iu m . E -m a il: p a t r i c k .v e r h o e v e n @ e s p o .b e ; th o m a s .v a n o u t r iv e @ u a .a c .b e bE u r o p e a n Sea P o rts O r g a n is a tio n , T re u re n b e r g 6, B -1 0 0 0 , B r u s s e ls , B e lg iu m , d e p a r t m e n t of G e o g ra p h y , G h e n t U n iv e rs ity , K r ijg s la a n 281 S8, B -9 0 0 0 , G h e n t, B e lg iu m . Abstract The ever-changing environm ent in w hich ports operate has p u t strong pressure on the role of port authorities. The evolution of port governance has so far mainly b een analysed in qualitative term s, through expert know ledge and case studies. This article fills a research gap in providing a quantitative analysis of port governance in Europe, using data from a m ajor survey, w hich the European Sea Ports Organisation carried out in 2010 to prepare a new edition of its ‘Fact-Finding Report’. These reports have been m onitoring port governance diversity since the 1970s. The 2010 survey w as based on a new conceptual background, w hich takes into account the evolution of ports, as well as new perspectives on the role of port authorities. This article provides a quantitative assessm ent of the survey results, identifying elem ents th at m ay explain the governance diversity of European sea­ ports. This is done w ith the help of factor analysis. The results confirm the existence of different types of port governance models in Europe, w hich to som e extent correspond to the hypothetical typology according to w hich port authorities can be conservators, facil­ itators or entrepreneurs. Differences are m ainly geographically defined and the subdivision in H anseatic, Latin, Anglo-Saxon and new M ember State port authorities proves to be a valuable one. In addition to this geographical explanation of diversity, the analysis also detects different governance practices betw een small and large ports. Maritime Economics & Logistics (2012) 14, 178-203. doi:10.1057/mel.2012.6 Keywords: port authorities; port governance; autonom y; port strategies; port reform ; E uropean Union © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 M aritim e Econom ics & Logistics w w w .palgrave-journals.com /m el/ Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance Introduction It is a w ell-know n fact th at ports in Europe are diverse. G overnance is one of the key elem ents th at determ ine this diversity. W hen using the term ‘port govern­ ance’, we can distinguish two levels: the governance of the port and the govern­ ance of the port authority. The form er corresponds to the w ide cluster of econom ic, societal and public policy stakeholders th at relate to a port, w hereas the latter concerns the internal firm level or ‘corporate governance’ of the port authority (Brooks and Cullinane, 2007; De Langen, 2007). The term ‘port authority’ im plies a specific, th at is, public, form of port m anagem ent, b u t w e use it here as the generic term for the body w ith statutory responsibilities th at m anages a p o rt’s w ater an d land-side dom ain, regardless of its ow nership or legal form (De M onie, 2004). Port governance is a bro ad concept, w hich encom passes several dim en­ sions. Seven distinct groups of param eters can be used w hen analysing gov­ ernance practices: (i) devolution, (ii) corporate governance, (iii) operational profile, (iv) functional autonom y, (v) functional pro-activeness, (vi) investm ent responsibility and (vii) financial autonom y. Furtherm ore, governance practices are not stable in tim e an d space. W hile in the past cargo-handling in E uropean ports w as traditionally carried out by locally based com panies, horizontal and vertical integration of cargo-handling com panies have resulted in a m arket dom inated by global players. This evolution attracted the attention of both policym akers and researchers w hich often refer to the declining influence of port authorities, w hile global players gained bargaining pow er (Heaver et al, 2000; H eaver et al, 2001; Slack an d Frém ont, 2005; Olivier and Slack, 2006; Jacobs and Haii, 2007; Vanelslander, 2011). As a response to this evolution, several p ort authorities reposition them selves by adopting pro-active strategies an d developing activities in other nodes in the logistic chain, outside the ow n port perim eter. In addition to the changes in port governance over time, dif­ ferences across space exist. Suykens (1988; Suykens and Van de Voorde, 1998) identified three m ajor p ort governance traditions in Europe: the ‘H anseatic’ tradition of local, m ostly m unicipal, governance, w hich is dom inant in ports around the Baltic an d N orth Sea; the ‘L atin’ tradition of central governance, w hich reigns in France and countries around the M editerranean; and finally, the ‘Anglo-Saxon’ tradition of independent governance, w hich is characteristic of ports in the United Kingdom an d Ireland. Finally, governance practices m ay differ for other organisational reasons such as the size of the port and the port authority (for exam ple, nu m b er of em ployees). Despite the extensive literature on port governance (for an overview see, for exam ple, Verhoeven, 2010 and Pallis et al, 2010), studies generally describe general trends or lim it them selves to case studies. To our know ledge, there © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 179 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive exists no study w hich analyses port governance practices of a large n um ber of ports in a system atic way. In the p resent article, w e analyse port governance in Europe, using a rich database containing variables th at cover all aforem en­ tioned dim ensions of port governance. This inform ation w as collected by the E uropean Sea Ports O rganisation (ESPO). This organisation, w hich represents the com m on interests of E uropean port authorities, and its predecessor, the Com m unity Port W orking Group, have been m onitoring the diversity in port (authority) governance in Europe since the 1970s through a series of ‘FactFinding R eports’. T hroughout this period, the environm ent in w hich ports operate has changed dram atically, putting strong and m ultiple pressures on the role of port authorities. The Fact-Finding Reports w ere m ainly descriptive in natu re and did not allow a profound quantitative analysis. In 2010, ESPO pre­ pared a new edition of the report through a m ajor survey am ong European port authorities. The survey w as based on a new conceptual background th at takes into account the evolution of ports, as w ell as new perspectives on the role of port authorities. Concretely, the survey enquired about the objectives and functions of port authorities, com pared institutional fram ew orks, and analysed financial capabilities. This exercise yielded a rich database of observations and variables, suitable for in-depth quantitative analysis. In this article, we do not describe the actual findings of the survey, these can be found in the Fact-Finding Report itself (Verhoeven, 2011). We focus instead on a quantitative assessm ent of the principal elements that m ay explain the governance diversity of European seaports. This is done with the help of factor analysis, a commonly applied tool to explore data sets w ith m any variables, which are then sum m arised into a limited num ber of unobserved factors. The first tw o sections of the article introduce the conceptual background of the survey an d the survey data. In the following sections, w e describe the research m ethodology for the quantitative assessm ent and present the results of the factor analysis. A concluding section discusses the m ain findings and sets out issues th at require further research. Conceptual Background The 2010 edition of the ESPO Fact-Finding Report builds on the tradition of the original reports, but it is based on a new conceptual background. This was developed by Verhoeven (2010), taking into account the evolution of the port concept, as well as new perspectives on the role of port authorities. The latter are based on an extensive literature review, w hich revealed that, in recent tim es, a renewed interest in the role of port authorities has emerged. This role has come under severe and multiple pressures from stakeholders following im portant 180 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance socio-econom ic changes in the port landscape. Scholars have issued various recom m endations for a ‘renaissance’ of port authorities, revisiting the traditional landlord, regulator and operator functions, and devising a com m unity m anager function that is intrinsically linked to the changing nature of port communities and stakeholders. In addition, scholars have also identified the scope of port authorities as one that ought to extend their activities beyond the local port perimeter, at regional or even at global level. Combining the functional profile and the geo­ graphical dim ension in a m atrix allows one to elaborate on the existential options of port authorities in a hypothetical typology consisting of three basic types: the ‘conservator’, the ‘facilitator’ and the ‘entrepreneur’. The basic features of each type are illustrated in Table 1. A ‘conservator’ port authority concentrates on being a good housekeeper an d essentially sticks to a rath er passive an d m echanistic im plem entation of the three traditional port authority functions at local level. Because of this low-profile attitude, conservator port authorities m ay ru n the highest risk of becom ing extinct in the future. A ‘facilitator’ p ort authority profiles itself as a m ediator and m atchm aker betw een econom ic and societal interests, hence the w ell-de­ veloped com m unity m anager function. Facilitator port authorities also look beyond the port perim eter and try to engage in strategic regional partnerships. It is the type of port authority, which so far seems to find m ost support in literature. The ‘en trep ren eu r’ port authority com bines the m ain features of the facilitator w ith a m ore outspoken com m ercial attitude as investor, service provider and consultant on all three geographical levels (local, regional and global). Because of this am bitious profile, it is also the type th at runs the highest risk of running into problem s caused by conflicts betw een the various functional levels. The conceptual fram ew ork is com pleted w ith the exploration of a num ber of governance-related elem ents th at m ay influence the extent to w hich a port authority will be a m ere conservator or will be able to take on facilitating and entrepreneurial responsibilities. Four essential elem ents can be identified: two form al and tw o inform al ones. The tw o form al elem ents consist of the legal and statutory fram ew ork on the one h an d an d the financial capability (that is, financial autonom y an d investm ent responsibility) on the other. The inform al elem ents relate to the balance of pow er w ith governm ent and the m anagem ent culture th at reigns w ithin the port authority. It should be noted th at these four elem ents are strongly interrelated. The pow er balance w ith governm ent will influence the legal and statutory fram ew ork, w hereas the financial capability of the port authority will determ ine the room its m anagem ent has to m ake p ro ­ active and intelligent use of port governance tools w ithin a given structural fram ew ork. In the Introduction, w e presented seven distinct governance dim ensions: (i) devolution, (ii) corporate governance, (iii) operational profile, (iv) functional © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 181 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive 182 © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Table 1: H y p o th e tic a l ty p o lo g y o f p o r t a u t h o r iti e s Type Conservator F a cilita to r Entrepreneur Landlord P assive re a l e s t a t e 'm a n a g e r': • c o n tin u ity a n d m a in te n a n c e • d e v e lo p m e n t m a in ly le f t t o o th e rs ( g o v e r n m e n t/p r iv a te se c to r) • f in a n c ia l re v e n u e from re a l e s ta te on 't a r i f f b asis A ctiv e re a l e s t a t e 'b r o k e f : • c o n tin u ity , m a in te n a n c e a n d im p ro v e m e n t • d e v e lo p m e n t b ro k er a n d c o - in v e s to r • in c lu d e s u rb an a n d e n v ir o n m e n ta l re a l e s t a t e b ro k erag e • f in a n c ia l re v e n u e from r e a l e s t a t e on co m m e rc ia l b a sis M ed ia to r in c o m m e rc ia l B2B re la tio n s b e tw e e n s e rv ic e p ro v id e rs a n d p o r t cu s to m e rs S tr a te g ic p a r tn e r s h ip s w ith in la n d p o rts , dry p o rts a n d o th e r s e a p o r ts R e g u la to r P assive a p p lic a tio n a n d e n fo r c e m e n t o f rules a n d re g u la tio n s m a in ly s e t by o th e r a g e n c ie s F in a n c ia l re v e n u e from re g u la to r ro le on 't a r i f f b a sis A ctiv e a p p lic a tio n a n d e n f o r c e m e n t o f ru le s an d re g u la tio n s th r o u g h c o -o p e r a tio n w ith lo c al, re g io n a l a n d n a t io n a l re g u la to ry a g e n c ie s + s e tt in g o f ow n ru le s a n d re g u la tio n s P ro v id e a s s is ta n c e t o p o r t c o m m u n ity to co m p ly w ith ru le s a n d r e g u la tio n s F in a n c ia l re v e n u e from re g u la to r ro le on 't a r i f f b a s is w ith d if f e re n tia l ch a rg in g o p tio n s fo r s u s ta in a b ility A ctiv e re a l e s t a t e 'd e v e lo p e ri: • c o n tin u ity , m a in te n a n c e a n d im p ro v e m e n t • d ir e c t in v e s to r • in c lu d e s u rb an a n d e n v ir o n m e n ta l re a l e s t a t e d e v e lo p m e n t • f in a n c ia l re v e n u e fro m re a l e s ta te on c o m m e rc ia l b asis • f in a n c ia l re v e n u e fro m n o n -c o re a c tiv itie s D irect co m m e rc ia l B2B n e g o tia tio n s w ith p o r t c u s to m e rs - a c tiv e p u r s u it o f m a rk e t n ic h e s D irect in v e s tm e n ts in in la n d p o rts , dry p o rts a n d o th e r s e a p o r ts Id e m f a c ilita to r + se llin g e x p e rtis e a n d to o ls o u ts id e th e p o r t F in a n c ia l re v e n u e from re g u la to r ro le on co m m e rc ia l b asis Maritime Economics & Logistics Functional dimension Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 M e c h a n is tic a p p lic a tio n o f c o n c e ss io n po licy (lic e n s e - is s u in g w indow ) D ynam ic u se o f c o n c e ss io n po licy , in c o m b in a tio n w ith r e a l e s t a t e b ro k er role 'L e a d e r in d is s a tis f a c tio n ' a s re g a rd s p e rfo rm a n c e o f p riv a te p o r t serv ic es pro v id e rs P ro v id e se rv ic e s o f g e n e ra l e c o n o m ic in t e r e s t a n d s p e c ia lis e d co m m e rc ia l serv ic es C om m unity m anager N ot a c tiv e ly d e v e lo p e d E co n o m ic d im e n sio n : • s o lv e h in te r la n d b o ttle n e c k s • p ro v id e tr a in in g a n d e d u c a tio n • p ro v id e IT se rv ic e s • p ro m o tio n a n d m a rk e tin g • lo b b y in g S o c ie ta l d im e n s io n : • a c c o m m o d a te c o n flic tin g in te r e s ts • lo b b y in g • p r o m o te p o s itiv e e x te r n a litie s Geographical dim ension Local Local + 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Source: V erhoeven (2 0 1 0 ). Regional D ynam ic u se o f c o n c e ss io n p o licy, in c o m b in a tio n w ith re a l e s t a t e d e v e lo p m e n t ro le S h a re h o ld e r in p r iv a te p o r t se rv ic e p ro v id e rs P ro v id e s e rv ic e s o f g e n e ra l e c o n o m ic in t e r e s t a n d co m m e rc ia l serv ic es P ro v id e s e rv ic e s in o th e r p o rts Id e m f a c ilita to r ty p e b u t e c o n o m ic d im e n sio n w ith m o re d ir e c t co m m e rc ia l in v o lv e m e n t Local + Regional + Global Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance O p erato r © 183 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive autonom y, (y) functional pro-activeness, (vi) investm ent responsibility and (vii) financial autonom y. The m eaning of these dim ensions is explained below. (i) The term ‘devolution’ is used here in the broad sense, to identify to w hich extent port m anagem ent has been privatised, decentralised a n d /o r corporatised. (ii) There is a difference betw een being corporatised in form and actually following principles of corporate governance that are custom ary in private undertakings. On the basis of the survey, the latter can be assessed from various perspectives, including the economic and non-economic objectives port authorities have, their organisational structure (including the appoint­ m ent of top m anagem ent executives and the composition of supervisory bodies), transparency through the use of public selection procedures to contract out land to port operators, and corporate social responsibility (CSR) policies and the use of corporate accounting principles. (iii) The custom ary w ay to classify p ort authorities in operational term s is to distinguish betw een ‘landlord ports’, ‘tool ports’ and ‘service ports’, depending on whether, respectively, port authorities are not involved in (cargo-handling) operations at all, operate superstructure and related services or provide full operations in an integrated m anner. (iv) Functional autonom y is analysed from the perspective of the landlord and regulator function. The landlord function can be considered as the principal function of contem porary port authorities. Im portant issues here are land ow nership, as w ell as the ability and autonom y in contracting land out to third parties. The regulator function is to a large extent perform ed by the h arb o u r m aster’s office, w hich can be an integral part of the port authority structure or a separate entity. (v) Functional pro-activeness can be assessed at the level of the port authority’s ow n port(s) and beyond. The ‘own port’ dimension covers pro-active fulfilment of the traditional landlord and regulatory functions, as well as the comm unity m anager one, which is pro-active by nature. The ‘external’ dim ension looks at how port authorities transpose their functions beyond their ow n borders, including investm ent in hinterland networks, investm ent in other ports, export of regulatory and other expertise and so on. (vi) Investm ent responsibility concerns financial responsibility for the capital investm ent, administration, operation and m aintenance of the capital assets that constitute a port, including m aritim e access, terminal-related infrastruc­ ture, transport infrastructure w ithin the port area and transport infrastructure outside the port area. Also, sources of port authorities’ operating income are covered here, such as general port dues, land lease, services and public funding. 184 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance (vii) Financial autonom y concerns first of all the legal nature, calculation basis and autonom y that apply to different categories of port authority income charges, in particular general port dues. Financial autonom y of port authorities is also analysed in term s of decision m aking regarding new investments in capital assets, setting of wages, term s and service conditions of its ow n personnel and the requirem ent to m eet certain financial targets. T h e ESPO F a c t - F i n d i n g S u r v e y Survey design The 2010 Fact-Finding Report of ESPO is the first to be based on a Web-based survey that was addressed directly to individual port authorities in Europe, rather than to national port organisations, as was the case w ith previous editions. National port organisations were, however, instrum ental in encouraging their members to respond to the survey. The survey comprised 108 questions. Apart from a general section profiling the port(s) controlled by the port authority, it consisted of three m ain sections that were based on the conceptual framework described above: the first enquired about the objectives and functions of the port authority (landlord, regulator, operator, com m unity m anager); the second looked into the institutional framework of the port authority (ownership, legal status and form, organisational structure); and the final set of questions addressed the financial capability of the port authority (financial responsibility, financial autonomy). Response rate The survey w as m ade available to all port authorities in the 22 m aritim e M em ber States of the E uropean U nion and port authorities in four neighbouring countries th at are represented in ESPO: Iceland, Norway, Croatia and Israel. The survey was online from 1 April to 15 July 2010. One h u ndred and sixteen port authorities from the 26 countries represented in ESPO responded. Together, these 116 port authorities reported th at they m anage a total of 216 different ports. The total freight volum e handled by these ports in 2008 am ounted to 2 770 803.000 tonnes (Eurostat data com pleted w ith national statistics for Iceland an d Israel). Figure 1 illustrates the response rate p er country, expressed in percentage of the total volum e of cargo handled by all ports in each country. The bottom line of the figure show s th at the total sam ple of ports that responded to the survey handles 66.2 p er cent of the volum e of cargo handled © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 185 Verhoeven and V anoutrive B elgium B ú lg a ra Cr,;..;; .3 C y p ru s , Denm ark ::::■n F ir t la r d F ran ce Germ any Ire la n d , N orw ay P o la r d Í-0-1.juä : R o m an a Sio von a V U n ite d K ingdom , 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 ■ % of total volume o f cargo handled Figure 1: S u rv ey r e s p o n s e r a te s , e x p re s s e d in p e r c e n ta g e o f th e t o t a l v o lu m e o f c a rg o h a n d le d . by th e total E uropean p o p u latio n of ports in 2008. The response rate w as very high (75-100 p er cent) in Belgium , B ulgaria, Cyprus, Estonia, Germ any, Israel, Latvia, L ithuania, M alta, the N etherlands, Poland, Portugal, R om ania and Slovenia; it w as m ed iu m to high (50-74 per cent) in France, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Spain and the U nited Kingdom; it w as low to m edium (25-49 per cent) in D enm ark, F inland an d Sw eden. The response rates of Greece and N orw ay 186 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 M aritim e Econom ics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance w ere very low (less th a n 25 p er cent). It should be noted th at in countries w ith low er response rates the ports th at replied do form a representative sam ple of the governance diversity th at exists in these countries. Research M ethodology The research m ethodology w e used to assess the survey results consists of two m ain steps. The first concerns the selection and clean-up of the data generated by the survey, w hereas the second consists of the use of factor analysis, as data reduction technique, to help revealing the underlying factors th at m ay explain port governance diversity in Europe. As an interm ediate step, w e introduced a series of dum m y variables to test the hypothesis th at regional characteristics m ay constitute an im portant factor th at explains port governance diversity in Europe. Survey data and selection of variables As m entioned above, the Fact-Finding Survey contained 108 questions. These questions generated 269 individual variables. M ost of these variables are of nom inal, th at is, categorical nature, containing several answ er categories. First, w e m ade a selection of variables to m ake the data set m ore m anageable and, notably, to obtain a w orkable ratio betw een the num ber of variables and the n um b er of observations. Factor analysis requires th at there are m ore observa­ tions th a n variables. Variables th at generated no or only few observations were deleted and the m ost pertinent variables w ere selected from different questions th at w ere addressing sim ilar issues. In addition, som e variables w ere clustered into new ones. This resulted in a data set of 67 variables classified according to the them atic groups th at w e described in the previous section: devolution, corpo­ rate governance, operational profile, functional autonom y, functional p ro ­ activeness w ithin the port auth o rity ’s ow n p o rt(s), functional pro-activeness beyond the port auth o rity ’s ow n p o rt(s), investm ent and financial autonom y. In addition, a ‘size’ group w as created, w hich includes variables related to the volum es of total cargo, containers an d passengers handled in the port(s) m anaged by the p ort authority, as well as the num ber of staff the port authority em ploys (SZ_CARGO, SZ_CONTR, SZ_PASSG, SZ_STAFF). The ‘devolution’ (DV) variables m easure to w hat extent responsibility for port m anagem ent is transferred from central governm ent, through privatisation (DV_PRIVA), decentralisation (DV_DECEN) and corporatisation (DG_CORPT). An additional variable m easures w h eth er governance reform took place in 2000 © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 187 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive or later (DG_REFYR). The ‘corporate governance’ (CG) variables m easure the existence an d natu re of the port auth o rity ’s objectives and m ission statem ent (CG_OBJEC, CG_PROFI, CG_VALUE and CG_MISSI), competences and composi­ tion of supervisory boards (CG_CEOAP, CG_BORPO, CG_BORSZ), use of public selection procedures to contract land out (CG_SELEC), existence of CSR policy (CG_CSRPO) and accounting practices (CG_ACSEP, CG_ACAUD, CG_ACPUB, CG_ACANL). The ‘operational’ (OP) variables identify w hether the port authority directly or indirectly provides operational services, including technical-nautical services (OP_TECNA), ancillary services (OP_ANCIL), cargo-handling services (OP_CARHA), passenger-handling services (OP_PAXHA) and transport services (OP_TRANS). The ‘functional autonom y’ (FA) variables m easure to w hat extent the port authority can autonom ously take m anagem ent decisions as regulator (FA_ENTIT, FA_HMAST and FA_POUC) and landlord (FA_LANDO, FA_LANDP, FA_LANDD). The ‘functional pro-activeness’ variables are split betw een those that cover the port authority’s ow n port(s) (PO) and those that go beyond its own port(s) (PB). The first group measures the degree in which the port authority assum es a facilitating or entrepreneurial attitude in its different functions w ithin the area of the port(s) it has directly under its supervision. This relates to its function as landlord (PO_CLAUS, PO_URBAN) and regulator (PO_ENVIR, PO_ RULES, PCLSUSTA), as well as the economic (PO_BOTTL, POJMPLE, POJTSYS, PO_PROMO, PO_TRAIN) and societal (PO_SOCIE) dim ension of its community m anager function. The second group measures to w hat extent the port authority is active beyond the port(s) it has directly under its supervision, in terms of relations w ith other ports (PB_STRAP, PB_DINVE), export of regulatory expertise (PB_ REGEX), provision of operational services (PB_SERVI), investm ent in hinterland networks (PB_HINTE) and provision of training (PB_TRAIN). The ‘investm ent’ (IR) variables look at the extent to which the port authority bears investment responsibility for the m ain capital assets that constitute the port (IR_CAPAS) and looks at its m ain sources of income (IR_INCOM, IR_PDUES, IR_LEASE, IR_SERVI, IR_PUBFU). The last category seeks to m easure the financial autonom y (FI) of port authorities through analysis of general port dues (FI_PRICE, FI_NEGOT, FI_PROMO, FLCROSS, FLLEVEL, FI_COLLE, FI_BENEF) and other variables (FI_WAGES, FLRESUL, FLTARGT). Table 2 contains a full description of all variables, including the regional dum m y variables th at are explained in the follow ing subsection. Introduction of regional dummy variables As an interm ediate step, w e added five dum m y variables, in order to test the hypothesis th at the region w here the port authority is located determ ines the governance diversity of E uropean port authorities. These dum m y variables 188 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 Table 2: Port go v ern an ce variables 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 189 D escription Category Type SZ_ CARGO Total volum e o f g o o d s h an d led by th e p o rts m an ag ed by th e p o rt au th o rity , in 2009, in to n s Total volum e o f co n ta in e rs h an d led by th e p o rts m anaged by th e p o rt au th o rity , in 2009, in to n s T otal n u m b er o f p a s se n g e rs h a n d le d by t h e p o rts m an a g e d by t h e p o rt a u th o rity , in 2 0 0 9 T otal s ta f f em p lo y e d by t h e p o rt a u th o rity , in FTE P ort a u th o r ity is Located in t h e Flanse reg io n P ort a u th o r ity is Located in t h e New Flanse reg io n P ort a u th o r ity is Located in t h e A nglo-Saxon reg io n P ort a u th o r ity is Located in t h e Latin reg io n P ort a u th o r ity is Located in t h e New Latin reg io n P ort a u th o r ity is p re d o m in a n tly p riv a tely o w n ed P ort a u th o r ity is p re d o m in a n tly o w n ed a t Local Level Size Size Size Size Region Region Region Region Region D evolution D evolution C ontinuous C ontinuous C ontinuous C ontinuous C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical P ort a u th o r ity h as c o rp o ra tis e d form G o v ern an ce reform to o k p lac e in 2 0 0 0 o r Later P ort a u th o r ity h as g e n e ra l fo rm al o b je c tiv e s E conom ic o b je c tiv e p o rt a u th o r ity is m ax im isa tio n o f ow n p ro fit E conom ic o b je c tiv e p o rt a u th o r ity is m ax im isa tio n o f a d d e d v alu e P ort a u th o r ity h as a m issio n s ta te m e n t S u pervisory b o d y p o rt a u th o r ity h a s e n d r e s p o n s ib ility t o a p p o in t CEO S u pervisory b o d y p o rt a u th o r ity h a s s ig n if ic a n t n u m b er o f e le c te d p o litic ia n s Num ber o f m em b ers in t h e su p e rv iso ry b o d y o f t h e p o r t a u th o rity P ort a u th o r ity u se s p u b lic s e le c tio n p ro ce d u re to c o n tr a c t Land o u t P ort a u th o r ity h as a CSR policy P ort a u th o r ity m a in ta in s s e p a ra te f in a n c ia l a c c o u n ts P ort a u th o r ity h as i ts f in a n c ia l a c c o u n ts a u d ite d by an e x te r n a l a u d ito r P ort a u th o r ity p u b lis h e s its f in a n c ia l a c c o u n ts P ort a u th o r ity h as a n i n te r n a l a n a ly tic a l a c c o u n tin g p ro cess P ort a u th o r ity p ro v id es t e c h n ic a l- n a u tic a l se rv ic es P ort a u th o r ity p ro v id es a n c illa ry se rv ic es P ort a u th o r ity p ro v id es c a rg o -h a n d lin g serv ices P ort a u th o r ity p ro v id es p a s se n g e r-h a n d lin g se rv ic es P ort a u th o r ity p ro v id es tr a n s p o r t serv ices P ort a u th o r ity is t h e o n ly e n tity w ith s ta tu to r y r e s p o n s ib ilitie s fo r t h e p o rt(s ) i t m an a g e s Flarbour m a s te r is fully in te g r a te d in t h e p o rt a u th o rity P ort a u th o r ity em p lo y s its ow n p o lice force P ort a u th o r ity is t h e m ain o w n e r o f p o rt Land P ort a u th o r ity is a b le t o s e ll p o rt Land D evolution D evolution C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e C o rp o rate g o v e rn a n c e O p e ra tio n a l pro file O p e ra tio n a l pro file O p e ra tio n a l pro file O p e ra tio n a l pro file O p e ra tio n a l pro file F u n c tio n a l a u to n o m y F u n c tio n a l a u to n o m y F u n c tio n a l a u to n o m y F u n c tio n a l a u to n o m y F u n c tio n a l a u to n o m y C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ateg o rical C ontinuous C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical C ategorical sz_ CONTR sz_.PASSG sz_ STAFF RG._HANSE RG._NWHAN RG._ANGL0 RG._LATIN RG._NWLAT DV..PRIVA DV._DECEN DV._C0RPT DV._REFYR CG_.OBJ EC CG_.PROFI CG_.VALUE CG_.MISSI CG_.CEOAP CG_.BORPO CG_.BORSZ CG_.SELEC CG_.CSRPO CG_.ACSEP CG_.ACAUD CG_.ACPUB CG_.ACANL OP._TECNA OP._ANCIL OP._CARHA OP._PAXHA OP._TRANS FA_.ENTIT FA_.HMAST FA_.POLIC FA_.LANDO FA_.LANDS A quantitative analysis of European port governance Maritime Economics & Logistics Code 190 © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Table 2 co n tin u e d Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 Code D escription Category FA._LANDP FA._LANDD PO _CLAUS PO _URBAN PO _ENVIR PO _RULES PO _SUSTA PO _B0TTL PO .IMPLE PO _ITSYS PO _PROMO PO _TRAIN PO _S0CIE C o n trac tin g o f Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity Port a u th o r ity PB _STRAP PB _DINVE PB _REGEX PB _SERVI PB _HINTE PB _TRAIN IR_.CAPAS IR_.INCOM IR_.PDUES IR_.LEASE IR_.SERVI IR_.PUBFU FI_ PRICE FI_ NEGOT FI_ PROMO FI_ CROSS FI_ LEVEL FI_ COLLE FI_ BENEF FI_ IN VES FI_ WAGES FI_ RESUL FI_ TARGT Port a u th o r ity h a s s tr a te g ic p a rtn e rs h ip s w ith o th e r p o rts Port a u th o r ity h a s d ire c t in v e s tm e n ts in o th e r p o rts Port a u th o r ity e x p o rts re g u la to ry e x p e rtis e t o o th e r p o rts Port a u th o r ity p ro v id e s o p e ra tio n a l s e rv ic es in o th e r p o rts Port a u th o r ity in v e s ts in h in te rla n d n etw o rk s o u ts id e ow n p o rt Port a u th o r ity p ro ce ss t r a i n in g /e d u c a tio n a l p ro g ram m es o u tsid e its own p o rt D egree o f in v e s tm e n t re s p o n s ib ility p o rt a u th o r ity fo r t h e m ain c a p ita l a s s e ts t h a t c o n s titu te t h e p o rt T o tal o p e ra tio n a l in co m e o f t h e p o rt a u th o rity , in 2 0 0 9 , in Euro G en eral p o rt d u e s form h ig h e s t p e rc e n ta g e o f in co m e Land Lease form s h ig h e s t p e rc e n ta g e o f in co m e Serv ices form h ig h e s t p e rc e n ta g e o f in co m e Public f u n d in g form s h ig h e s t p e rc e n ta g e o f in co m e G en eral p o rt d u e s are c o m m ercial prices G en eral p o rt d u e s are n e g o tia b le Port a u th o r ity can g ive co m m e rc ia l p ro m o tio n s on g e n e ra l p o rt d u es Port a u th o r ity can c ro ss-su b sid ie s b e tw e e n d iffe re n t so u rc e s o f in co m e Port a u th o r ity a u to n o m o u s ly s e ts t h e Level o f g e n e ra l p o rt d u es Port a u th o r ity a u to n o m o u s ly c o lle c ts g e n e ra l p o rt d u es Port a u th o r ity is fin a l b e n e fic ia ry o f g e n e ra l p o rt d u es Port a u th o r ity a u to n o m o u s ly d e c id e s o n p o r t in v e s tm e n ts Port a u th o r ity s e ts w ag es, te rm s a n d c o n d itio n s o f serv ic e o f its ow n p e rs o n n e l Port a u th o r ity d e c id e s a u to n o m o u s ly how t o a llo c a te t h e a n n u a l f in a n c ia l resu lt Port a u th o r ity d o e s n o t hav e t o m e e t c e rta in f in a n c ia l t a r g e ts p o rt Land t o th ir d p a rtie s is g o v e rn e d by p riv a te Law is free to s e t d u ra tio n s o f Land u se c o n tra c ts a c tiv e ly u ses p e rfo rm a n c e cla u se s in te r m in a l a g re e m e n ts e n g a g e s in u rb an rea l e s ta te m a n a g e m e n t e n g a g e s in e n v iro n m e n ta l Land m a n a g e m e n t s e ts ow n re g u la tio n s t h a t go b ey o n d Legal req u irem e n ts g e n e ra lly g o e s b e y o n d Legal req u ire m e n ts in a c tio n s to e n h a n c e s u s ta in a b ility is Leader in so lv in g v a rio u s ty p e s o f b o ttle n e c k s a s s is ts a n d f a c ilita te s p o rt co m m u n ity w ith im p le m e n ta tio n o f re g u la tio n s ru n s IT sy ste m fo r t h e e n tire p o rt co m m u n ity Leads t h e o v e ra ll p ro m o tio n a n d m ark e tin g o f t h e p o rt p ro v id e s t r a in in g /e d u c a tio n a l p ro g ram m es fo r t h e p o r t c o m m u n ity is Leader in v ario u s s o c ie ta l in te g r a tio n in itia tiv e s F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l F u n c tio n a l Type a u to n o m y a u to n o m y p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss p ro -a c tiv e n e ss F p ro -a c t b e y o n d own F p ro -a c t b e y o n d ow n F p ro -a c t b e y o n d own F p ro -a c t b e y o n d own F p ro -a c t b e y o n d own F p ro -a c t b e y o n d own In v e s tm e n t In v e s tm e n t In v e s tm e n t In v e s tm e n t In v e s tm e n t In v e s tm e n t F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y F in an cial a u to n o m y p o rt p o rt p o rt p o rt p o rt p o rt C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ontinuous C ontinuous C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical C ateg o rical A quantitative analysis of European port governance w ere based on the geographical typology th at w as developed by Suykens (Suykens, 1988; Suykens and Van de Voorde, 1998). His typology, however, does not take into account the fall of the iron curtain, w hich has brought a n um b er of new ports around the Baltic Sea, the M editerranean and the Black Sea in the com petitive arena. These w ere u n d er planned econom y regimes for alm ost 50 years an d u n d erw en t varied liberalisation processes after the political changeover. These ports can be brought together in tw o additional regions: ‘New H anse’, consisting of countries around the Baltic Sea; and ‘New Latin’, consisting of countries in the East M editerranean and the Black Sea. In this way, w e can classify the port authorities in five regional groups: • H anse (RG_HANSE): B elgium , D en m ark , F inland, G erm any, Iceland, the N e th e rla n d s, N orw ay a n d Sw eden. • New H anse (RG_NWHAN): Estonia, Latvia, L ithuania and Poland. • Anglo-Saxon (RG_ANGLO): Ireland and the United Kingdom. • Latin (RG_LATIN): Cyprus, France, Greece, Israel, Italy, M alta, Portugal and Spain. • New Latin (RG_NWLAT): Bulgaria, Croatia, Rom ania and Slovenia. M ost port authorities participating in the survey are either to be found in the H anse (38 per cent) or Latin (35 p er cent) region; third comes the AngloSaxon region (14 p er cen t). The tw o ‘n ew ’ regions contain relatively few port authorities (New H anse 7 p er cent an d New Latin 6 per cent). Factor analysis After cleaning up the results of the survey and adding the regional dum m y variables, the database still contained 72 variables. Applying a data reduction technique m ay therefore help to reveal the relations betw een governance practices of port authorities in Europe an d explain port governance diversity. Factor analysis is com m only applied to explore data sets w ith m any variables, w hich are th e n sum m arised into a lim ited num ber of unobserved factors. Doing this, the analysis tries to keep the n u m b er of factors as low as possible while m aintaining a m axim um of the inform ation, w hich is present in the original data. For each factor, the factor loadings indicate to which extent they are corre­ lated w ith each variable. If the factor loadings of two variables show similarities, these variables are related. On the basis of the resulting pattern, factors are often labelled and accordingly, clusters of observations can be detected (Stevens, 2002). Two problem s rem ain w h en analysing the ESPO database. First, a con­ siderable am ount of observations has m issing values for one or m ore variables. Second, m ost variables are categorical in nature. Classical factor analysis, © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 191 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive however, assum es continuous an d norm ally distributed variables. Among others, N isenbaum et al (2004) an d Vanoutrive et al (2010) applied binary (categorical) factor analysis to get insight in questionnaires containing an extensive list of binary yes/no questions. The software employed in these studies, Mplus (Muthén and M uthén, 2006), allows one to carry out factor analyses with a mix of both continuous and categorical variables. Furthermore, this package can handle missing data w ithout omitting valuable information, as is the case with standard list-wise or pair-wise deleting options in other software. A lthough the chosen technique can handle m issing data, w e deleted 6 from the 116 observations because these six port authorities did not provide data on m ore th a n 40 p er cent of the variables. Furtherm ore, the categorical variables w ere re-coded in b inary variables as this did not bring along an im portant loss of inform ation, th at is, som e rare categories w ould not positively contribute to an analysis of the m ain p atterns p resent in the data. Finally, w e attributed the label ‘m issing’ for the cargo variable instead of a value of zero to ports, w hich do not h andle any cargo at all. Given the lim ited n um ber of ports w ith only passenger traffic, w e do not expect th at this affects the results in a m ajor way. We estim ate tw o m odels, one w ith and one w ithout the regional dum m y variables. These variables have a value of one if the port belongs to the Hanse, New Hanse, Anglo-Saxon, Latin or New Latin region, respectively, and a value of zero if not. As these dum m y variables are m utually exclusive, and to avoid th at this pre-specified clustering influences the results and their interpretation, w e will first look at the m odel w ithout these regional variables and use the m odel w ith the regional variables to check our findings. R es u lts of t h e Factor Ana lysis Number of factors and factor loadings As in standard factor analysis, the eigenvalues are used to select the n um ber of factors. Figure 2 pictures the scree plot w hich shows the eigenvalues. The tw ists in a scree plot indicate possible values for the num ber of factors. The second criterion, taking the sam e num ber of factors as there are eigenvalues larger th a n one, could not be applied as this w ould im ply a large n u m b er of factors. The scree plot suggests a m odel w ith four or five factors. After an exam ination of both m odels, w e prefer a m odel w ith four factors as the results w ere easier to in terpret th a n those of the five-factor m odel. The results (Varimax rotated) are given in Table 3. Factor loadings ^ 0 .4 are show n in bold as these are considered m eaningful. Note th at values ^ 0 .3 are also large en­ ough to be im portant. 192 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European p o rt governance 14 model 3© ? 1 2 a 4 5 6 r 3 9 10 E g e n v a lu e num ber Figure 2: S c re e p lo t o f t h e m o d e ls w ith a n d w ith o u t r e g io n a l d u m m y v a ria b le s . Note th at the presence of m issing an d binary data and the relatively lim ited n um b er of observations, together w ith a rath er large n um ber of variables, can explain the low values of test statistics indicated at the bottom of Table 3. In addition to the fact th at the first 23 eigenvalues stay above 1, also the Root M ean Square Error of A pproxim ation (RMSEA) stays above 0.1 even for a m odel w ith ten factors, w hile a m oderately well-fitting m odel has an RMSEA < 0.10 (Gilbert an d Meijer, 2006) or even RMSEA < 0 .0 8 (Stevens, 2002, p. 433) (num bers for the m odel w ithout regional dum m y variables). A lthough fit statistics suggest that the model does not perform well, m any factor loadings have values ^ 0 .4 and we could detect patterns that correspond with the literature. As a consequence, we did not try to im prove the m odel by om itting variables as this w ould im ply a loss of inform ation. In general, the results of the m odels w ith and w ithout region dum m y variables are similar, w hich is a first indication th at this clustering of ports in regions could also reflect differences in governance practices. This will be ex­ plored further in the next section, w hich discusses the results. Table 4 already m arks the correspondence betw een the factors in both m odels. Description of the factors In this section, w e describe the four factors individually, looking first at the factor in the m odel w ithout region dum m y variables and th en com paring it w ith © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 M aritim e Econom ics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 193 194 Table 3 : F a c to r lo a d in g s o f t h e 4 - f a c t o r m o d e ls w ith o u t re g io n d u m m y v a r ia b le s ( le f t) a n d w ith re g io n d u m m y v a r ia b le s ( r ig h t) © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 Variable Factorl Factor2 SZ_CARG0 SZ_PASSG SZ_STAFF IR_CAPAS IR_INC0M CG_B0RSZ RG_HANSE RG_NWHAN RG_ANGL0 RG_LATIN RG_NWLAT DV_PRIVA DV_DECEN DV_C0RPT DV_REFYR CG_0BJ EC CG_PR0FI CG_VALUE CG_MISSI CG_CE0AP CG_B0RP0 CG_SELEC CG_CSRP0 CG_ACSEP CG_ACAUD CG_ACPUB CG_ACANL 0P_TECNA 0P_ANCIL 0P_CARHA 0P_PAXHA 0P_TRANS FA_ENTIT FA_HMAST FA_P0LIC FA_LAND0 FA_LANDS 0 .1 4 - 0 .0 3 - 0 .0 4 0 .1 2 0 .1 3 0.54 Factor3 Factor4 Factorl Factor2 Factor3 Factor4 0.1 3 - 0 .0 7 0 .1 1 -0 .0 1 0 .0 6 0 .2 2 0 .0 8 - 0 .0 4 0 .1 4 0 .1 0 - 0 .1 2 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .2 4 - 0 .1 0 0 .3 0 - 0 .2 4 - 0 .1 4 0.1 0 0 .0 4 - 0 .2 6 - 0 .3 2 0.3 2 0.3 5 0.53 - 0 .0 6 0.2 1 0 .1 5 0.1 1 - 0 .2 7 0 .3 7 0 .0 2 — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — 0.95 — — — — 0 .2 6 0 .0 0 0.71 0 .2 3 -0.71 -0.52 0.43 -0.48 - 0 .3 9 - 0 .1 1 0 .0 9 -0.58 -0.49 0.54 0 .3 0 - 0 .2 2 -0.48 - 0 .1 1 0 .1 8 - 0 .3 3 - 0 .3 7 - 0 .3 4 0 .1 1 0 .3 5 -0.42 -0.73 0.45 -0.55 -0.48 - 0 .0 1 0.57 0 .0 2 0.80 0.3 1 0.45 - 0 .0 7 0 .2 1 0 .0 4 0 .2 1 - 0 .0 1 0 .3 6 - 0 .0 4 - 0 .2 4 0 .3 8 0.41 0 .2 2 - 0 .1 0 0.46 0.49 0.74 0.86 0.53 0.51 - 0 .0 9 0 .0 5 - 0 .2 3 0 .0 4 - 0 .3 1 - 0 .0 9 0 .0 4 0 .2 4 - 0 .0 6 - 0 .0 4 0.40 - 0 .2 6 - 0 .1 9 - 0 .0 4 - 0 .0 9 - 0 .2 2 0 .1 9 - 0 .3 7 0 .3 7 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .5 6 0 .1 0 -0.73 -0.68 -0.55 -0.49 -0.41 - 0 .2 1 - 0 .2 5 - 0 .2 2 - 0 .0 7 - 0 .1 1 0.40 0 .2 0 - 0 .1 2 - 0 .2 0 0.93 -0 .2 3 0.42 0.0 1 - 0 .1 8 0.4 1 -0 .2 4 -0.42 -0.58 - 0 .2 7 - 0 .1 0 0 .1 9 0 .0 2 0.0 3 0.0 3 0.3 3 - 0 .0 3 - 0 .2 6 0 .3 9 0 .0 2 0 .0 7 - 0 .4 0 - 0 .1 5 - 0 .0 5 -0 .0 3 - 0 .0 6 0.64 -0.82 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .1 8 -0.84 -0.54 - 0 .2 7 0 .3 8 - 0 .2 9 -0 .2 4 - 0 .0 2 -0.63 -0.71 0.55 0 .3 1 -0 .2 1 -0.45 - 0 .1 2 0 .2 2 -0 .3 1 -0.44 - 0 .1 9 0 .1 4 0 .3 2 -0.48 -0.76 0.47 -0.53 -0.48 0.67 0 .0 1 - 0 .1 3 0 .0 8 0 .3 2 0 .1 9 - 0 .0 1 - 0 .3 8 - 0 .2 2 - 0 .1 1 - 0 .3 0 0 .0 5 -0.41 0 .1 9 - 0 .1 0 -0.68 -0.51 -0.65 - 0 .0 1 - 0 .1 5 - 0 .3 7 - 0 .2 8 - 0 .2 3 - 0 .2 9 - 0 .3 4 - 0 .0 3 - 0 .1 8 0.42 - 0 .1 6 -0.88 0.21 - 0 .1 5 -0.92 -0.56 0.1 7 0.2 0 0.3 9 -0.66 0.2 5 0.2 5 -0 .0 1 0.42 0.1 7 - 0 .1 8 0.13 - 0 .1 7 - 0 .2 2 - 0 .0 4 -0.49 -0.68 - 0 .1 4 -0 .2 1 -0 .1 3 0.0 2 - 0 .1 8 - 0 .0 7 - 0 .1 8 - 0 .1 5 0 .0 5 0.65 0 .0 4 0.80 -0 .1 3 - 0 .1 0 0 .0 0 - 0 .2 8 0 .1 5 0 .0 3 - 0 .2 7 - 0 .1 8 0 .3 0 0 .1 0 0 .2 6 0 .0 4 0 .2 3 0 .3 3 0 .1 6 - 0 .2 5 0.53 0.42 0.81 0.88 0 .3 7 0.52 - 0 .1 9 - 0 .1 2 - 0 .2 0 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .3 8 - 0 .1 9 - 0 .0 7 0 .1 8 - 0 .1 0 -0 .1 3 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 FA_LANDP FA_LANDD P0_CLAUS POJJRBAN P0_ENVIR P0_RULES P0_SUSTA P0_B0TTL - 0 .2 3 0.45 0.61 0 .2 3 - 0 .0 7 0.40 0 .3 4 0 .3 0 0 .2 5 0 .1 0 0.1 3 - 0 .3 2 0 .3 0 0 .0 8 0 .2 6 0 .3 3 0 .2 8 0 .1 8 0 .2 6 0.54 0.42 0 .0 6 0.1 1 0 .3 3 0.43 0.78 0.44 0.41 0 .2 0 0 .2 9 0 .0 6 0.63 0.52 - 0 .2 3 0 .2 2 - 0 .0 9 0 .3 0 -0.64 0 .0 5 - 0 .1 3 -0.82 -0.61 - 0 .3 5 - 0 .3 1 -0.59 - 0 .1 1 - 0 .0 8 0.66 - 0 .1 7 0 .3 2 0.43 - 0 .3 3 0.44 0 .0 7 -0.47 0 .1 2 0 .1 0 0 .0 7 0 .0 0 0 .2 7 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .1 1 - 0 .1 6 - 0 .0 8 - 0 .1 2 0 .1 6 - 0 .0 7 - 0 .1 8 - 0 .2 0 0 .0 9 - 0 .2 9 - 0 .3 2 -0.50 - 0 .1 3 - 0 .2 5 - 0 .3 6 - 0 .2 3 - 0 .2 9 - 0 .0 1 - 0 .0 8 - 0 .1 2 -0.45 - 0 .0 7 - 0 .1 9 0.0 1 - 0 .1 3 - 0 .0 5 0.1 1 - 0 .3 4 0 .0 5 -0.40 -0.43 -0.47 - 0 .1 1 0.1 1 0 .0 7 0 .0 5 - 0 .1 9 -0 .0 3 - 0 .1 0 - 0 .0 7 0 .2 0 - 0 .1 6 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 2 -0 .0 4 - 0 .2 8 - 0 .0 8 0 .0 0 0 .0 2 0.0 3 0 .1 9 - 0 .0 2 - 0 .3 -0 .2 3 0.80 0 .1 7 0.2 1 -0.44 - 0 .3 0 - 0 .1 7 - 0 .3 8 0.0 3 -0.48 0 .0 0 - 0 .3 0 0 .1 4 - 0 .0 6 0 .1 0 0.1 3 0.46 -0.58 - 0 .1 9 0.40 0.58 0 .1 7 0 .0 2 - 0 .2 4 - 0 .2 9 0 .0 6 0 .2 3 -0 .1 1 0 .3 4 0 .3 7 0 .2 3 0 .2 2 0 .0 7 0 .3 7 0 .1 9 -0.42 -0.51 -0.51 0.64 - 0 .2 9 - 0 .2 3 0 .3 6 0 .3 3 0 .0 2 0.60 0.47 -0 .2 4 0 .0 8 0 .1 3 0 .3 4 -0.58 - 0 .0 6 -0 .2 1 -0.79 -0.68 - 0 .3 8 -0 .2 3 -0.56 - 0 .0 5 -0 .0 1 - 0 .2 3 - 0 .2 5 - 0 .2 5 - 0 .3 7 -0.57 -0.43 - 0 .2 4 - 0 .1 6 - 0 .4 2 0 .0 8 - 0 .3 6 0 .2 2 0 .2 3 - 0 .2 8 - 0 .1 5 -0.44 -0.40 0 .0 4 - 0 .0 5 - 0 .2 2 0 .1 8 - 0 .1 5 0.49 - 0 .0 9 - 0 .2 4 0.0 6 0.1 0 0.0 5 -0 .0 3 0.0 9 - 0 .2 7 0.0 9 0.01 - 0 .0 6 0.0 2 0.2 7 0.3 7 0.1 9 0.1 6 - 0 .1 6 0.0 5 0.11 - 0 .0 4 0 .3 4 -0.54 -0.48 - 0 .0 2 0.3 5 0.01 - 0 .2 2 - 0 .0 7 0.1 8 -0.54 -0 .2 1 - 0 .3 6 0.0 5 0 .1 5 -0 .3 3 0 .2 6 0 .0 4 0 .2 9 0 .2 0 0 .1 4 0 .0 7 0 .2 0 0.52 0 .0 1 0 .0 0 0 .2 7 0 .1 2 0 .2 3 0.54 -0 .2 1 0 .3 1 0 .3 3 -0 .3 1 0 .3 2 0 .1 7 -0.44 0 .0 7 0 .0 2 - 0 .0 4 0 .0 0 0 .1 8 -0 .0 1 - 0 .1 4 - 0 .1 2 - 0 .1 0 0 .0 0 Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 Notes: fa c to r Loadings a re Varim ax ro ta te d ; v a lu e s > 0 . 4 in b o ld ; RMSEA m o d e l w ith o u t reg io n d um m y v a ria b le s (Left): 0 .1 5 5 ; RMSEA m o d e l w ith reg io n dum m y v a ria b le s (r ig h t): 0 .1 6 2 . A quantitative analysis of European port governance Maritime Economics & Logistics PO JM PLE P0_ITSYS P0_PR0M 0 P0_TRAIN P0_S0CIE PB_STRAP PB_DINVE PB_REGEX PB_SERVI PB_HINTE PB_TRAIN IR_PDUES IR_LEASE IR_SERVI IR_PUBFU FI_PRICE FI_PR0M 0 FI_CR0SS FI_LEVEL FI_C0LLE FI_BENEF FIJNVES FI_WAGES FI_RESUL FI_TARGT -0.58 195 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive Table 4: C o rre s p o n d e n c e b e tw e e n f a c to r s in m o d e ls w ith a n d w ith o u t d u m m y v a ria b le s Model w ith o u t dum m y variables Relationship M odel w ith dum m y variables F a c to r 1 F a c to r 2 F a c to r 3 + + + F a c to r 1 F a c to r 4 F a c to r 2 F a c to r 4 - F a c to r 3 the corresponding factor in the m odel w ith the dum m y variables. For each factor, loadings higher th a n 0.3 are represented in individual tables. In each table, variables w ith an estim ated residual variance low er or equal to 0.5 are highlighted in bold. Estim ated residual variances indicate how m uch of each variable is explained through the entire m odel, th at is, com prising all factors. The annex gives the estim ated residual variances for all variables. Factor 1 : Latin - H anseatic contrasts in autonom y an d pro-activeness Table 5 illustrates that Factor 1 is generally characterised by positive loadings for variables that relate to functional pro-activeness, both w ithin (PO) and beyond (PB) the ow n port. Negative loadings exist for variables that relate to financial (FI) and functional autonom y (FA), as well as devolution (DV). Variables on corporate governance (CG) dem onstrate a mixed picture. Positive loading exists for the size of the supervisory boards (CG_BORSZ), but a negative one on politicians being significantly present in them (CG_BORPO). Negative loadings exist on profit maximisation as the m ain economic objective (CG_PROFI) and the external audit of financial accounts (CG_ACAUD). A positive loading appears for the use of public selection procedures to land contracts (CG_SELEC). Although the factor loadings are not high for operational variables (OP), they are generally negative (except for transport services (OP_TRANS)). In sum m ary, w e could say that, som ehow paradoxically, Factor 1 m atches lim ited autonom y w ith a substantial degree of pro-activeness. If w e com pare this picture w ith the m odel th at has regional variables included, w e find that Factor 1 has a strongly positive loading for the Latin region (RG_LATIN) and a strongly negative one for the H anse region (RG_HANSE). Factor 2: Large corporately governed port authorities Table 6 show s th at Factor 2 has positive loadings for size-related variables (incom e (IR_INCOM), n u m b er of staff (SZ_STAFF) and volum e of cargo (SZ_CARGO)). Positive loadings also exist for transparency-related variables in the category of corporate governance (for example, w here it concerns financial accounts (CG_ACSEP, CG_ACAUD, CG_ACPUB) and the use of public selection 196 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance Table 5 : L o a d in g s F a c to r 1 (w ith a n d w ith o u t d u m m y v a ria b le s ) Model w ith o u t region dum m y variables (F a cto r 1) P o sitiv e f a c t o r > 0 .7 PB_STRAP, CG_B0RSZ lo a d in g > 0 .6 > 0 .5 > 0 .4 > 0 .3 N e g a tiv e f a c t o r lo a d in g < —0 .8 < - 0 .7 PB_HINTE, POJJRBA N CG_SELEC, PB_TRAIN FA_P0LIC, P0_CLAUS, PB_DINVE, CG JJB JEC , P0_TRA IN, PB_REGEX, P0_SUSTA 0P_TRANS, P0_B0TTL, P0_S0C IE FI_LEVEL FA_HMAST, DV_DECEN FI_PRICE, FLC0LLE < - 0 .6 < - 0 .5 < - 0 .4 FI_WAGES, CG_CE0AP, FA_LANDP, FA_LAND0, DV_REFYR CG_B0RP0, FA_LANDS, CG_PR0FI, CG_ACAUD, FA_ENTIT < - 0 .3 DV_C0RPT, 0P_ANCIL, FI_BENEF, 0P_CARHA, 0P_TECNA, F I J N VES Model w ith region dum m y variables (F a cto r 1) P o sitiv e f a c t o r lo a d in g > 0 .8 > 0 .6 > 0 .5 > 0 .4 > 0 .3 N e g a tiv e f a c t o r lo a d in g < - 0 .8 < - 0 .7 < - 0 .6 < - 0 .5 < - 0 .4 < - 0 .3 RG_LATIN CG_B0RSZ, PB_STRAP, PB_HINTE PO JJR B A N , CG_SELEC FA_P0LIC, PBJRAIN P 0 J L A U S , C G JJBJEC, P 0 J R A I N , P0_B0TTL, PB_DINVE, P0_SUSTA, IR_PUBFU , PB_REGEX, 0 P J R A N S , C G J S R P 0 RG_HANSE, DV_DECEN FIJEVEL, FA_HMAST, CG_B0RP0 FI_C0LLE, C G JE 0 A P FI_PRICE, F A JA N DP, FIJVAGES, DV_REFYR, FA JA N D O F A JN T IT , F A JA N D S , CG_ACAUD, 0P_ANCIL FI_BENEF, 0PJECNA N ote: V ariables w ith an e s tim a te d re s id u a l v a ria n c e < 0 . 5 0 a re in d ic a te d in b o ld . procedures for contracting out land to third parties (CGJ3ELEC)). It furtherm ore has positive loadings on functional pro-activeness, both w ithin (PO) and beyond the ow n p ort (PB). W ithin the investm ent category, a positive loading is present for land lease being the highest percentage of operational incom e (IR_LEASE) an d a negative one for public funding being the highest percentage (IR_PUBFU). A negative loading also appears for private ow nership of the port authority (DV_PRIVA). In sum m ary, Factor 2 com bines the size of the port authority w ith principles of good corporate governance and functional pro-activeness. Com pared w ith the corresponding Factor 4 in the m odel w ith regional dum m y variables, we notice th at these do not appear in the list of significant variables. The regional adherence does not therefore play a role. Factor 3 : N ew European public conservators It appears from Table 7 that Factor 3 shows predom inantly negative loadings, especially for variables that relate to operational involvement in port services (OP), © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 197 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive Table 6: L o a d in g s: F a c to r 2 ( w ith o u t d u m m y v a r ia b le s ) a n d F a c to r 4 (w ith d u m m y v a ria b le s ) Model w ith o u t region dum m y variables (F a cto r 2 ) P o sitiv e f a c to r lo a d in g > 0 .7 > 0 .6 > 0 .5 > 0 .4 SZ STAFF, P 0 ITSYS, SZ CARGO, CG ACPUB, CG ACANL CG_CSRP0, CG_SELEC, IR_LEASE, P 0_S 0C IE , PB_TRAIN, CG_MISSI > 0 .3 < - 0 .4 CG VALUE, P 0 RULES, PB HINTE IR_PUBFU 0*1 V O N e g a tiv e f a c to r lo a d in g CG_ACAUD, IRJNC0M CG_ACSEP PB REGEX > 0 .8 IR_PDU ES, FA_LANDD, 0P_TRANS, DV_PRIVA Model w ith region d um m y variables (F a cto r 4) P o sitiv e f a c to r lo a d in g CG_ACAUD, CG_ACSEP, IRJNC0M SZ_STAFF PB REGEX, CG SELEC, SZ CARGO, PO ITSYS, CG ACANL > 0 .8 > 0 .6 > 0 .5 > 0 .4 > 0 .3 CG_ACPUB, CG_MISSI, PB_TRAIN, IR_LEASE, PB_HINTE, DV_C0RPT < - 0 .4 0*1 V O N e g a tiv e f a c to r lo a d in g CG CSRPO IR_PUBFU 0P_TRANS, FA_LANDD, IR_PDUES Note: V ariables w ith an e s tim a te d re s id u a l v a ria n c e < 0 . 5 0 a re in d ic a te d in b o ld . Table 7: L o a d in g s: F a c to r 3 ( w ith o u t d u m m y v a r ia b le s ) a n d F a c to r 2 (w ith d u m m y v a ria b le s ) Model w ith o u t region dum m y variables (F a cto r 3 ) P o sitiv e f a c to r lo a d in g > 0 .4 CG_0BJEC, > 0 .3 N e g a tiv e f a c to r lo a d in g < - 0 .7 DV_REFYR, IRJNC0M, CG_ACSEP 0P_TECNA OP ANCIL CG_ACPUB, 0P_CARHA < - 0 .6 < - 0 .5 < - 0 .4 0*1 V O PO B0TTL, OP PAXHA, FI INVES, FI TARGT, PB SERVI, DV PRIVA, FI COLLE, OP TRANS, FI CROSS CG CSRPO, PO PROMO, FI PRICE, PO SUSTA, FI RESUL Model w ith region d um m y variables (F a cto r 2 ) P o sitiv e f a c to r lo a d in g N e g a tiv e f a c to r lo a d in g > 0 .6 RG_NWLAT > 0 .4 FI_TARGT > 0 .3 < - 0 .6 < - 0 .5 < - 0 .4 < - 0 .3 DV REFYR, RG NWHAN (0 .2 9 9 ) CG_ACPUB, 0P_ANCIL P 0_S0C IE , P0_SUSTA, 0P_TECNA, P0_B0TTL FI CROSS, PB REGEX, PO RULES, PB TRAIN, CG CSRPO FI COLLE, CG VALUE, OP PAXHA, PO TRAIN, IR LEASE, FA POLIC, CG_B0RP0 Note: V ariables w ith an e s tim a te d re s id u a l v a ria n c e < 0 . 5 0 a re in d ic a te d in b o ld . corporate governance (transparency) (CG), functional pro-activeness w ithin (PO) and beyond the port (PB), as well as financial autonom y (FI). A negative loading also exists for private ow nership of the p ort authority (DV_PRIVA), w hereas a positive loading appears for the variable th at indicates w hether the port authority obtained its present legal form in the last decade (DV_REFYR). 198 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance Factor 3 bears resem blance to the ‘co nservator’ type of port authority that w as identified in Table 1. Com pared w ith the corresponding Factor 2 in the m odel w ith regional dum m y variables, w e see a strong positive loading for the New Latin region (RG_NWLAT) an d a m odest positive loading for the New H anse region (RG_NWHAN). Factor 4: Anglo-Saxon private entrepreneurs Finally, Table 8 shows that Factor 4 has positive loadings for devolution variables (DV), m ost strongly for privatisation (DV_PRIVA). It also has a strongly positive loading for the variable that indicates that the provision of services forms the highest percentage of income of the port authority (IR_SERVI). This corresponds with the positive loading for the variables that indicate that the port authority provides cargo-handling services (OP_CARHA) and has m aximization of its ow n profit as an economic objective (CG_PROFI). The factor has negative loadings on financial autonom y variables (FI). A negative loading appears on politicians being significantly present in the supervisory board of the port authority (CG_BORPO). This factor has elem ents of the entrepreneurial type indicated in Table 1. The negative loadings on financial autonom y (FI) seem paradoxical, however. Factor 4 relates negatively to Factor 3 in the m odel w ith regional dum m y variables. Taking this into account, it is obvious th at the Anglo-Saxon regional variable (RG_ANGLO) plays a very im portant role. Table 8: L o a d in g s: F a c to r 4 ( w ith o u t d u m m y v a ria b le s ) a n d F a c to r 3 (w ith d u m m y v a r ia b le s ) Model w ith o u t region dum m y variables (F a cto r 4 ) P o sitiv e f a c to r > 0 .9 DV_PRIVA lo a d in g > 0 .8 IR SERVI > 0 .4 DV C0RPT, CG PR0FI > 0 .3 SZ_STAFF, 0P_CARHA, CG_ACANL N e g a tiv e f a c to r lo a d in g < - 0 .5 CG_B0RP0 < - 0 .4 FI_BENEF, FI_PR 0M 0, CG_MISSI < - 0 .3 FA_ENTIT, FI_C0LLE, IR_PDUES, FI_CR0SS Model w ith region dum m y variables (F a cto r 3 ) P o sitiv e f a c to r lo a d in g > 0 .4 N e g a tiv e f a c to r lo a d in g < - 0 .9 > 0 .3 < - 0 .8 < - 0 .6 < - 0 .5 < - 0 .4 < - 0 .3 CG_B0RP0, RG_HANSE CG_0BJEC, PB_STRAP, FI_PR 0M 0, CG_B0RSZ, IR_LEASE, IRJNC0M DV_PRIVA RG ANGLO 0P_CARHA, CG_PR0FI DV C0RPT, IR SERVI, FI INVES OP TECNA, FI PRICE FI RESUL, IR CAPAS Note: V ariables w ith an e s tim a te d re s id u a l v a ria n c e < 0 . 5 0 a re in d ic a te d in b o ld . © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 199 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive Conclusions and Research Agenda T here exists a w ide range of studies, w hich discuss port governance in general or focus on particular aspects. However, up until now, research on port gov­ ernance practices w as lim ited to case studies or rath er descriptive analyses. The p resent study extends this research by analysing a large n u m ber of E uropean port authorities (n = 110) in a quantitative m anner, using factor analysis. The 2010 ESPO Fact-Finding Survey proved to be a valuable source of inform ation to explore differences in governance practices betw een E uropean ports. The results confirm the existence of different types of port governance in Europe, w hich to som e extent correspond w ith the hypothetical typology according to w h ich p o rt au th o rities can be con serv ato rs, facilitators or e n tre p re n eu rs. Differences are m ainly geographically defined and the su b ­ division in H anseatic, Latin, Anglo-Saxon and new M em ber State port au th o ­ rities proves to be a valuable one. Taking into account that, proportionally, m ost port authorities in Europe belong to either the Hanse or Latin tradition, the difference betw een them translates itself in a N orth-S outh duality w hich not only involves sim ple ow nership differences, but also covers m any other gov­ ernance elements, especially functional and financial autonomy, which is typically m ore lim ited in the south. In addition to this geographical explanation of diversity, w e could also detect differences in term s of governance practices betw een sm all and large ports. The latter generally follow a m ore pro-active approach and score higher on transparency-related variables. The findings of our analysis invite m ore in-depth research. The principal factors should be explored further to explain apparent paradoxes, such as the lim ited functional and financial autonom y th at Latin port authorities seem to com bine w ith a pro-active facilitator approach. The sam e goes for the o u t­ spoken entrepreneurial profile of Anglo-Saxon port authorities th at seem s to be b o u n d by lim ited financial autonom y. This in-depth research will be done through com parative case study analysis. The m ost pertinent variables can furtherm ore be transform ed into perform ance indicators in order to keep track of evolutions in port governance practices over time. Finally, the potentially harm onising influence of EU law and policy on E uropean port governance should be analysed (Verhoeven, 2009). Acknowledgement The authors w ish to th an k the in dependent review ers of this article and Pro­ fessor Dr Eddy Van de Voorde for review ing an earlier version. 200 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance References Brooks, M.R. an d Cullinane, K. (eds.) (2007) Introduction. In: Devolution, Port Governance a n d Port Performance. Am sterdam , the Netherlands: Elsevier, pp. 3-28. De L angen, P.W. (2007) S takeholders, conflicting interests an d governance in po rt clusters. In: M.R. Brooks an d K. C ullinane (eds.) D evolution, Port Governance a n d Port Performance. A m sterdam , the N etherlands: Elsevier, pp. 457-477. De M onie, G. (2004) M ission an d role of p o rt authorities after privatisation. Paper presen ted a t the ITMMA PPP Sem inar; N ovem ber, A ntw erp, Belgium. Gilbert, P.D. a n d Meijer, E. (2006) M oney an d Credit Factors. O ttaw a, Canada: B ank of C anada. Bank of C anada W orking p ap er 2006-3. Heaver, T., M eersm an, H., M oglia, F. an d Van de Voorde, E. (2000) Do m ergers an d alliances influence E u ro p ean shipping an d po rt com petition? M aritim e Policy & M a n a g em en t 27(4): 363-373. Heaver, T., M eersm an, H. and Van de Voorde, E. (2001) Co-operation and com petition in international co n tain er tran sp o rt: Strategies for ports. M aritim e Policy & M a n a g em en t 28(3): 293-305. Jacobs, W. an d Haii, P.V. (2007) W hat conditions supply chain strategies of ports? The case of Dubai. GeoJournal 68(4): 327-342. M uthén, L.K. a n d M uthén, B.O. (2006) M plus User’s Guide, 4 th edn. Los A ngeles, CA: M uthén and M uthén. N isenbaum , R., Ism ail, K., W essely, S., U nw in, C., Hull, L. an d Reeves, W.C. (2004) D ichotom ous factor analysis of sym ptom s reported by UK an d US veterans of the 1991 Gulf War. P opulation H ealth M etrics 2 (8). Olivier, D. an d Slack, B. (2006) R ethinking th e port. E n viro n m en t a n d P lanning A 38(8) : 1409-1427. Pallis, A.A., V itsounis, T.K. an d De L angen, P.W. (2010) Port econom ics, policy an d m anagem ent: Review of a n em erging research field. Transport Reviews 30(1): 115-161. Slack, B. an d Frém ont, A. (2005) T ransform ation of po rt term inal operations: From the local to the global. Transport Reviews 25(1): 117-130. Stevens, J. (2002) A p plied M ultivariate Statistics for the Social Sciences, 4 th edn. M ahw ah, NJ and London: Law rence E rlbaum A ssociates. Suykens, F. (1988) Op w eg n a a r een E uropese havenpolitiek? In: J. Blockx (ed.) Liber A m icorum Lionel Tricot. A ntw erpen, Belgium: Kluwer, pp. 493-498. Suykens, F. an d Van de Voorde, E. (1998) A q u arter of a century of p o rt m an ag em en t in E urope: Objectives a n d tools. M aritim e Policy & M a n a g em en t 25(3): 251-261. Vanoutrive, T., Van M alderen, L., Jourquin, B., Thom as, I., Verhetsel, A. and W itlox, F. (2010) Mobility m anagem ent m easures by employers: Overview and exploratory analysis for Belgium. European Journal o f Transport an d Infrastructure Research 10(2): 121-141. Vanelslander, T. (2011) C om petition Concerns in Ports a n d Port Services. Paris, France: O rganisation for E conom ic C o-operation a n d D evelopm ent, OECD DAF/COM P/W P2(2011)5. V erhoeven, P. (2009) E uropean ports policy: M eeting contem porary governance challenges. M aritim e Policy & M a n a g em en t 36(1): 79-101. V erhoeven, P. (2010) A review of p o rt auth o rity functions: Towards a renaissance? M aritim e Policy & M a n a g em en t 37(3): 247-270. V erhoeven, P. (2011) European Port Governance: Report o f a n Inquiry into the Current Governance o f European Seaports (The ESPO ‘Fact-Finding Report’) . Brussels, Belgium : E uropean Sea Ports O rganisation. © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 201 Verhoeven and Vanoutrive Appendix Table A: E s tim a te d re s id u a l v a r ia n c e s Variable Model w ith o u t region d um m y variables Model w ith region dum m y variables E stim ated residual variance E stim ated residual variance SZ CARGO SZ_PASSG 0 .6 3 0 .9 7 0 .7 0 0 .9 8 SZ STAFF IR_CAPAS 0 .5 1 0 .8 7 0 .5 0 0 .8 4 IR INCOM CG BORSZ RG_HANSE 0 .1 9 0 .4 6 0 .2 5 0 .4 0 0 .1 4 RG NWHAN RG ANGLO RG_LATIN — — 0 .8 9 0 .0 7 0 .0 1 — — RG NWLAT DV PRIVA DV_DECEN - 0 .2 0 0 .4 4 0 .4 6 0 .0 9 0 .2 2 DV CORPT DV REFYR CG_0BJEC 0 .5 7 0 .5 9 0 .5 8 0 .5 2 0 .5 5 0 .6 0 CG PROFI CG_VALU E 0 .5 3 0 .7 7 0 .4 8 0 .6 9 CG MISSI CG CEOAP CG_BORPO 0 .6 5 0 .5 4 0 .3 6 0 .7 8 0 .5 7 0 .1 6 CG SELEC CG CSRPO CG_ACSEP 0 .4 6 0 .5 0 0 .2 8 0 .3 9 0 .5 3 0 .2 5 CG ACAUD CG ACPUB CG_ACANL 0 .0 4 0 .4 0 0 .5 9 - 0 .0 2 0 .3 4 0 .6 9 OP TECNA OP_ANCIL 0 .3 5 0 .3 3 0 .3 7 0 .3 5 OP CARHA OP PAXHA OP_TRANS 0 .3 8 0 .7 5 0 .6 1 0 .4 3 0 .8 0 0 .6 6 FA ENTIT FA HMAST FA_POLIC 0 .6 2 0 .3 9 0 .6 9 0 .6 8 0 .3 0 0 .6 2 FA LANDO FA LANDS FA_LANDP 0 .6 8 0 .7 5 0 .6 2 0 .6 8 0 .7 0 0 .6 1 FA LANDD PO CLAUS PO_URBAN 0 .8 4 0 .6 8 0 .5 5 0 .8 0 0 .7 2 0 .5 7 PO ENVIR PO_RULES 0 .8 7 0 .7 9 0 .8 6 0 .7 7 PO SUSTA PO BOTTL P O JM P L E 0 .6 5 0 .5 7 0 .8 0 0 .6 0 0 .5 3 0 .8 5 PO ITSYS 0 .5 7 0 .6 2 — 202 © 2012 M acmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 A quantitative analysis of European port governance T a b le A co ntin u e d Variable Model w ith o u t region d um m y variables Model w ith region dum m y variables E stim ated residual variance E stim ated resid u a l variance P 0 PROMO P 0 TRAIN P0_S0C IE 0 .8 5 0 .7 6 0 .5 4 0 .9 3 0 .7 3 0 .4 9 PB STRAP PB DINVE PB_REGEX 0 .3 5 0 .7 1 0 .3 9 0 .3 6 0 .7 3 0 .3 9 PB SERVI PB HINTE PB_TRAIN 0 .7 6 0 .4 7 0 .5 0 0 .8 8 0 .5 1 0 .4 9 IR PDUES IR_LEASE 0 .7 5 0 .6 9 0 .8 4 0 .6 4 IR SERVI IR PUBFU FI_PRICE 0 .3 4 0 .6 5 0 .4 3 0 .6 1 0 .6 4 0 .3 5 FI PROMO FI CROSS FI_LEVEL 0 .7 9 0 .7 3 0 .2 9 0 .8 5 0 .7 6 0 .3 2 FI COLLE FI BENEF F IJN V E S 0 .2 2 0 .6 5 0 .6 6 0 .3 4 0 .8 2 0 .5 9 FI WAGES FI RESUL FI TARGT 0 .6 2 0 .8 8 0 .7 6 0 .6 0 0 .8 4 0 .7 6 © 2012 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1479-2931 Maritime Economics & Logistics Vol. 14, 2, 178-203 203