Centre for Studies in Democratisation CSD Students' Working Paper Series The democratic promise for development versus the Asian authoritarian miracle: Does regime type foster development? George Lindley georgelindley@live.ac.uk Working Paper n. 3/ 2011 Centre for Studies in Democratisation Department of Politics and International Studies University of Warwick Coventry CV4 7AL United Kingdom http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/pais/research/csd/ The Centre for Studies in Democratisation (CSD) was established at the University of Warwick in 1992 in response to a growing interest in the study of democracy at a theoretical and empirical level. Democratisation has become a central political theme and features now prominently on the foreign policy agenda of western countries. Members of CSD are seeking to understand why, how and when democracies emerge, sustain or collapse. They also investigate the reasons why democratisation can sometimes be problematic. Do not hesitate to contact us for more information! Renske Doorenspleet (Director): Renske.Doorenspleet@warwick.ac.uk Or visit our website: http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/pais/research/csd/ Abstract The relationship between democracy and development is one of the core issues for political scientists, with a history of antithetical conclusions. The promise of development and democracy is now further problematized by the ‘miraculous’ developmental success of East Asian and South-East Asian authoritarian regimes. In this essay we compare the promises of democracy for development and the reality of these leading authoritarian regimes, linking the latters’ specific political environment to their hyper development. To facilitate a meaningful analysis, the attributes of these regimes are connected with development defined both as GDP growth and Human Development (HD), before comparing and contrasting. The results of which are that first of all, both regimes rely on intermediaries for development, namely good governance, stability, property rights and successful choice of policies. Each of these is guaranteed often differently by the polar regime types. Secondly, we find that the respective consolidated regimes make a difference for different possibility, stages and rates of development. Accordingly, regime type does have an impact on development, but not as straight forwardly as perhaps hoped. Regime type is just one integrated component of the political environment that determines development. Keywords: autocracy, democracy, development, East Asia, good governance, GDP growth, Human Development, regime type, South-East Asia. The democratic promise for development versus the Asian authoritarian miracle: Does regime type foster development? George Lindley INTRODUCTION From the prediction of a ‘cruel dilemma’ (Bhagwati 2002) to that of a ‘virtuous circle’ (Bhalla 1997), the relationship between democracy and development has been thoroughly expounded upon, both in theory and empiricism. Development, like democracy, is a contentious term, with its meaning having undergone certain revisions for some of these theorists. Are we to take the traditional measurement of development; that of economic growth as Gross Domestic Product (GDP)? This is the simplest way of looking at development and most convenient for analysis and empiricism. However, the apparent failure of the trickle-down effect of wealth to the masses has led to a second and more recent conception of development; Human Development (HD). This fashionable new way of thinking is the one favoured by the UN which annually publishes the ‘Human Development Index’ (HDI). While Amartya Sen equates HD as allowing individuals to ‘flourish as human beings’ (quoted in Tsai 2006:234), here we are going to take a more palpable approach and consider it as the redistribution of ‘goods’ that the state produces collectively, specifically for our purposes; income, education and healthcare (Tsai 2006)). Both of these conceptions of development (HD and GDP growth) will be discussed here for two reasons. First, they both have their prominence in the literature. Second, they explain different trends. As established, development as GDP is potentially 1 misleading if the masses aren’t sharing the benefits, but then equally, HD depends on the total amount of benefits there are available for the state to redistribute. Increasing rates of HD can only be a short term trend and a potentially disastrous one if overall economic growth isn’t there as nourishment. The basic premise that we will we be working with is the following, ‘How authority is structured limits the range of economic policies that a regime can adopt and implement.’ (Kohli 1986:155) Favourable economic policies for induced development have been thoroughly analysed; openness to competition, use of international market, successful land reforms, public provision of incentives for investment, exportation and industrialization. (Sen 1997:2) The idea is not however to hone this list of policies and connect them to regime type, but to paint a picture of what developmental environments emerge from given political environments in terms of what kinds of policies and market conditions is the state likely to implement that will ultimately lead to type and rate of development (or therein lack of). Political environment then, is seen here as a platform upon which development is pursued. Accordingly, the political regime can only explain part of development, and different regime types may explain different elements of resulting development. For example, a certain regime type may be the reason why the state seeks development, but may be found lacking in facilitating it. Likewise, a given political environment may determine the sought of development that is promoted. The first part will be theoretical and will revolve around the arguments in favour of democracy as the ideal political regime type for growth. In the 2 second part, we will analyse leading authoritarian states who have achieved so called ‘economic miracles’. Of these, we will mainly be citing those in East and South-East Asia; salient examples being, China, South Korea and Indonesia (where their respective economic miracles have been attributed to authoritarian regimes). We can then move on to a comparison and analysis of development as GDP growth and development as HD for the two regime types. By comparing the positive reasons for development in democracies with the explanation of historic cases of authoritarian economic miracles, we are taking a slightly different line of enquiry than the predominant one in the literature, namely the contest between autocracy and democracy in terms of development promise, both in theory and in empiricism. The purpose here is to review the reasons themselves for development, above analysing generic regime types. These reasons may be diverging but equally valid as explanations for successful development. Sometimes reasons are the same and rely on an intermediary to explain development. Some important questions that will be investigated are: Why do certain authoritarian states excel? How do these reasons contrast with those that say democracy is the best political regime type for development? What do these reasons have in common? How sturdy are the arguments championing democracy as the ideal platform for development? What kind of development results from the polar political environments? Democracy as the ideal political environment for development With democracy being purely a political system, it does not a priori have a pretension to be a driver of development, as the ‘demos’ doesn’t have a say 3 in the economy nor in the family. (Bermeo 2009:23) Literature largely isn’t congruent on the why democracy effects development and some reasons follow contradicting logic. Each argument will be analysed for the type of developmental benefit it proposes and the argument’s congruency. Democracy overlaps with ‘good governance’. (Carbone 2009:124) ‘The current orthodoxy has it, democracy is the guarantor of good governance and democratic good governance is what will produce development’. (Leftwich 2000:147) While the two don’t equate, highly prized notions of accountability, transparency, responsiveness, participation, inclusivity, of the government are found in both concepts. (UNDP 1997:2-3) These attributes are valued for development in different ways and there will be greater discussion of them individually later in this section. The key point to discuss here is that citizens can choose their leaders (in consolidated democracies). In a democracy, if there is corruption (or an element of ‘bad governance’) within the government, then the party simply won’t be reelected. The ability to remove a leader is possible without the overthrow of the regime. Democracy then, has two clear qualities here over nondemocracies. First of all, governments are less likely to get away with widespread corruption and thus less likely to try it. Secondly, a change in government is an institutionalised recurrence; it has no effect on the economy. (Przeworski et al. 2000:212) The opposite is the case for autocracies, in which civilians (and/or the military) have to resort to drastic action to oust the ruling elite, ‘divert(ing) resources and energies away from production’1. (Przeworski et al. (2000:179) That being said, what does this 1 See Libya at the moment (April/May). 4 mean for policies? After all, as we have already seen, it is policies that are important for development2. Przeworski and Limongi ask quite rightly, what do people vote for; person or policy? What do leaders care about; a term in office or the good of the country? (1993:59) There are no straight forward answers to these questions. We can however draw the conclusion that while in reality democracy promises to avoid (prolonged) disastrous governance, it doesn’t guarantee the best selection of policies for development. This leads us to the second key argument. Democracies allocate resources better. This argument is based on the premise that democracies efficiently spend and invest the resources it has. At the heart of the matter is the benefit of widespread free information, allowing for more informed economic decisions. (Przeworski et al. 2000:144) ‘Free press, electoral competition, association, preferences and predictive endowments of individuals’ all are important pools of knowledge. (Przeworski and Limongi 1997:165) Amartya Sen develops this argument when he famously stated that there has never been a famine under democratic rule. ‘Political and civil rights, says Sen, gives people the opportunity to draw attention forcefully to general needs and to demand appropriate public action.’ (1997:2) Leaders are warned (earlier) about lifethreatening disasters resulting from policies (or lack of) thanks to freedoms such as speech and association (through protests, political pressure etc.) averting preventable disasters. In his paper (1997:2) he applies this line of thought to economic and social disasters as well as famine. Not just responsiveness (part of good governance) here then is key, but the ability of 2 See also Leftwich (2000:133) 5 governments to respond as opposed to in other forms of regimes. This is a direct link from democracy to the facilitation of development. Democratic rule ensures a fair and far-reaching redistribution of resources. Fair and far-reaching goods redistribution in turn, also has a positive causal stimulus for state-wide GDP growth. (Bermeo 2009:26) While it is doubtless that the egalitarian spread of resources is a positive for HD (especially if it is done through increased healthcare and education spending), is it true that democracies commit to fair redistribution in the same way it relieves absolute poverty? Most political economists would say it is. (Carbone 2009:129) Their theory needs translating into two parts. First of all, the poor (in healthcare, education as well as income) constitute an undivided large/majority segment of the population that is below the median standard of living. Then, governments respond to their voiced wishes in the in the name of democracy/vote seeking. The first part is often true without the second part resulting; inequality is rife within democracies. (Bermeo 2009:24) This is backed up by empirical investigations. (Mulé 1998:6-10, Carbone 2009:129)) Many reasons have been suggested to explain this; the poor itself is often divided over ethno-religious cleavages (Carbone 2009:131); the poor are disproportionately taxed; (Olson quoted in Tsai 2006:236), Democracy is about rights rather than redistribution (Bermeo 2009:28) etc.3 Whatever the case, the facts are clear; redistribution of resources is tentatively done. Quite interestingly though, there is the suggestion that inequality is mitigated in consolidated democracies. Carbone 3 See also Mulé (1998:10-19) who reviews even more alternative explanations before suggesting her own. 6 calls this the ‘Political Kuznets curve’. (Carbone 2009:131) Democratic rule provides a more stable environment for the economy. This is justified through a number of ways, again related to good governance. First of all, as we have already seen, leaders replace leaders in democracies without having an affect on the economy. Second, and most interestingly (as we’ll see later), is the premise that democracies guarantee property rights. Defendants of this argument maintain that property stays in the hands of the rightful owners by law and isn’t up for repartition. With this guaranteed, investors are more likely to invest because profit margins and contracts are protected and transparent. Of course it isn’t democracy that ensures property rights, but rule of law. But it is this same intermediary that is pursued in democracies in the name of securing constitutionalism, which also secures property. (Beetham 1997:83-84) As Olson puts it, ‘(Democracies) have the extraordinary virtue that the same emphasis on individual rights that is necessary to lasting democracy is also necessary for secure rights to both property and enforcement of contracts’. (1993:574) However, numerous theorists maintain that democracy does not necessarily guarantee property and contract rights, (Addison discussing the findings of Barro in Burnell 2002:46) (Przeworski and Limongi (1993:53)), for various reasons. Beetham, for one, suggests that the elite of either the economic or political sphere can make themselves exempt from the rule of law.(1997:84) Thus the reader is inclined to interpret that the protection of property rights is again a virtue of consolidated democracies, and not something that democratization incidentally guarantees. Property rights is an interesting argument because it is contradictory to the 7 popular claim that democracy acts to repartition the goods of society, the claim analysed in the previous paragraph. So although the argument is that property is safe from ruling despots, Przeworski and Limongi remind us that it isn’t just the leaders who unfairly take what isn’t theirs. ‘Capitalist property is threatened by organized workers, landlords’ property by landless peasant’. (1993:53) It seems therefore we have to reject either this argument for democracy favouring development or the one in the previous paragraph. If one is correct, it is ipso facto the reason why the other is incorrect. In conclusion to this part, we have one clear main reason why democracy facilitates development and avoids disasters (the allocation of resources), one reason to suggest that democracy promotes good governance, which in turn promotes development and finally two more unproven reasons that democracy facilitates HD or that democracy provides a necessary platform for development through stability. We must remind the reader that two parts constitute the ‘stability’ reason and not to dismiss the longevity of democracies as a benefit for development, even if the ability to secure property rights is inherently false. The Asian miracles: Authoritarian development Now we hope to account for the main political conditions that have promoted, enabled and facilitated the phenomenal development of various East and South-East Asian states, bearing in mind that the region under question is more complex than perhaps is thought. It must be stressed that there is no communal model of development by way of which all the success 8 stories have followed4. As a consequence, what we will discover in this paragraph are four key characteristics that pertain to multiple authoritarian case studies in East and South-East Asia, rather than a comprehensive set of specific economic policies with a linear line drawn to Confucius authoritarianism. Although distinguished here for point of comparison, these characteristics overlap with each other (just like the characteristics in the previous section did). Crucially for this essay, we will consider how likely these characteristics are products of autocratic rule, and the specific connection between political environment and resulting development. State capacity. China, South Korea and Taiwan have particularly profited from what is called high ‘state capacity’. (Low 2004:18) Linda Low defines this as, ‘The government’s ability to get its job done, including mobilising society, extract resources, steer development and legitimate regime’. (Low 2004:18) State capacity was hugely important to these states because economic development was a mixture of state-led protectionism and market based growth, which were structurally imposed by strong states. (Beeson 2004:31)) A crucial reform for development in South Korea, China, Japan and Taiwan is that of land very early on. In creating a relatively equal structure to society, growth induced by competition ensued. (Bhalla in Hadenius 1997:212-213) Then, as the example of South Korea best shows5, a boom in GDP lead to increased HD as a large majority of the population 4 For further clarity see Bradford (1986:119) who contrasts Korea, Taiwan, Singapore and Hong Kong. 5 HD increase in South Korea between 1960 and 1992 made it one of the most remarkable performers measured by UNDP (Mehrotra et al. 1998:264) 9 was able to equally and directly profit from the economic development. Improved human resources in turn aided GDP growth by means of a virtuous circle (as hypothesized in the previous section). (Mehrotra et al. in Low 2004:290-291) The link between state capacity and development here is purely an autocratic one. Adrian Leftwich argues, ‘(For development), it is inevitable that non-consensual steps will have to be taken, especially where a new developmentally committed regime comes to power facing a legacy of immense inequality in wealth and opportunity which requires urgent attention.’ (Leftwich 2005:693) Hence GDP growth is facilitated by autocracy in that the latter doesn’t respect the rights/opinions of the minorities. This doesn’t mean HD is limited, in fact the opposite seems to be the case, the leader chooses to pursue HD to legitimize the regime. State autonomy. Unlike but not unrelated to state capacity, state autonomy is the ability of a state to plan long-term development. (Deans in Low 2004:138) Where there is just one ruler or political party, long-term developmental policies are safeguarded from being retracted or modified throughout subsequent revisions of office. (Dent in Low 2004:81) Monoparty rule is not of course a condition exclusive to autocracies, it is however more often than not the reality. For Taiwan this was the Kuomintang up to 2000, for South Korea it was rule under Park Chung-hee 1961-1979, for China the Communist Party and for Indonesia this was rule under Suharto 1967-1998. This has allowed for GDP growth where contentious developmental policies have been pursued. A further way autocracies have an autonomous role to pursue development is through the emancipation from 10 the consumption-in-the-now demands from social forces. (Przeworski and Limongi 1993:54-55) Indeed this has been the case for the hard saving and investing countries where GDP growth has been made possible in China6, Taiwan, and South Korea, (as well as Japan, Hong Kong and Singapore). (Bhalla 1997:209) Autocracy here is useful in facilitating such extreme development because leaders such as Park Chung-hee are able to suppress demands for consumption forcing firms to invest. (Przeworski and Limongi 1997:164) Political stability. As we have seen from the previous section on the merits of democracy, political stability, albeit generated in a different way in autocracies, is beneficial for development. Political stability is linked with state capacity and autonomy by way in which they are all generated. Capacity and autonomy are consolidated in a stable environment often by the absence, or where once present, destruction of civil society. (Leftwich 2005:164) The latter mechanism was the case for Korea, Indonesia and China. (Leftwich 2005:164) Secondly, a stable political situation was secured in East Asia, despite autocrat rule and repression, by improving the income and standards of living for the masses7. (United Nations 1995:102) President Suharto of Indonesia, for example, improved infant mortality and 6 To get an idea of these phenomenal rates of investment, in 2005 China was investing close to 50% of its GDP. (Huang 2008:172). 7 Note however, while income inequality was kept at low levels in South Korea and Taiwan, it was exacerbated in Indonesia (and other South-East Asian countries (Higgot and Nesadurai 2002:5-6)) leading to civil unrest in the 90’s. (Higgot and Nesadurai 2002:10) (Leftwich 2000:136) 11 literacy rates while successfully combatting poverty8 (Higgot and Nesadurai 2002:10) ergo securing his legitimacy as a president. Autocracies then, need to perceivably develop (GDP as well as HD) to guarantee the survival of the mildly tyrannical regime, both of which are necessary conditions for transformative development. Accordingly, stability is reliant on the elite selecting the right policies; too many wrong policies, (such as the pursuit of petrochemicals in South Korea and shipbuilding in Taiwan and China (United Nations 1995:94)), again not only squanders development, but also the regime and thus the venerated platform for development that we have discussed. Determined developmental elite. High state capacity and autonomy would be meaningless, in fact dangerous, if the government wasn’t intent on pursuing development for the masses over self-interested goals such as glory or corruption. When under autocrat rule, the governments of South Korea and Taiwan, then later in Indonesia, Thailand and Malaysia all were indeed distinguished for actively pursuing development, (Low 2004:15-18) (guaranteeing political stability.) Illustrious by what Mark Beeson calls ‘pilot agency’, or powerful bureaucrats with the sole purpose of planning economic development. This was an invention of Japan9, and then replicated in Taiwan and South Korea. (Beeson in Low 2004:30) Policies were ‘depoliticized’ and selected for their developmental attributes for economic 8 Between 1976 and 1996, poverty was reduced from 60% of the population to less than 12% (Barbone et al. 2007:44) 9 Japan’s famous MITI: Ministry of International Trade and Industry 12 criteria. (Low 2004:12) Through state intervention, the market could be steadily liberalised and steered towards advancing the industries that gave the country its comparative advantage10 (Jomo in Low 2004:54) that was needed to close the development gap with the first world. As well as the shiny qualities of state autonomy and capacity, good governance, under the guise of nationalism and regime legitimization, again is at work here as a major determinant of development.11 To sum up, developmentally determined elite, enjoying high state capacity and autonomy in a stable political environment, led to miraculous development as GDP growth, as well as improvement in HD. In the high stakes game of rapid development, well-meaning autocrats repressed society, providing autonomy and capacity for the state. By way of virtuous circle, repression was legitimized by palpable development. Autocratic rule thus created an environment where HD was obligatory to secure the stability of the regime and the survival of the rulers. Comparison and analysis of democracy and the authoritarian miracles Having listed the political qualities for development of both democracy and leading autocracies, we must now compare the findings. Some additional 10 See steel industry in South Korea, Taiwan and China (United Nations 1995:95-96) 11 Liew claims that it was in fact good governance that led to Chinese growth in the 1980’s and 1990’s and not regime type. (Cited in Polterovich and Popov 2007:75) 13 questions that are to be addressed in this final part include; are the reasons for growth in polar regime types mutually exclusive? And; how important is political environment for development? We will then draw together the key developmental characteristics to make a series of conclusions. One of the main contributions to the developmental success of the authoritarian states analysed was that of state autonomy. Democracies, on the other hand, promise just the opposite; they are attached to society and responsive to its demands. (White 1998:13) Autonomy facilitated the rapid development through contentious long-term planning, whereas solidarity in democracy ensures the pressure to develop and the avoidance of policy disasters. Hence, a change of government is presented as a strength of democracies, and lack of governmental change is presented as a strength of autocracies; the two are arguing past each other. Nonetheless, Adrian Leftwich explains that the ruling elite in democracies are prevented from implementing radical change, (as seen in the authoritarian miracles), by being restrained in the name of respecting the wishes of the parties who didn’t win the elections but still represent large scathes of the population. (Leftwich 2005:696-699) If the winner of the elections were allowed to ‘re-write the policy book’ perhaps in their favour, then a large and powerless part of the population would feel that they have lost too much in the electoral process, and revolt now that their interests are threatened. Horizontal accountability, as a negative power of control on the elite, prevents this from happening. Accordingly, it seems that while democracy promotes development, it opposes miracle development. However, this isn’t the case for all democracies; in homogenous mono-party 14 societies there is nothing to stop the legitimate elite from reforms if support is nearly unanimous. (White 1998:20) A couple of useful examples to consider are the astonishing developmental successes of Botswana and Singapore; both democracies, which have both had the same parties in power since 1966 and 1965 respectively. It seems then only a certain type of liberal democracy favours extreme development, which isn’t possible in states where multiple cleavages give rise to a plurality of parties. So what does democracy buy in return for conservatism? As mentioned before, the guarantee of the pursuit of development, through the intermediary of good governance. Our case studies, however, ascertain that autocracies enjoy this intermediary too; does this mean that they too enjoy this guarantee? The fact that authoritarian states in this essay pursued development is why they were chosen as case studies, they do however misrepresent the reality of authoritarian states. To quote Surjit Bhalla, ‘For every Confucian authoritarian success there are at least ten non-Confucian authoritarian failures.’ (Bhalla 1997:214) Notwithstanding, our case studies have enjoyed good governance through the necessity to develop to ensure legitimacy of the regime (which is a key characteristic for stability). Legitimacy has come from phenomenal development in East and South-East Asia, in countries where rapid development was successful. Democracy on the other hand can rely on other factors (such as adhering to the constitution (Leftwich 2000:145)) to guarantee legitimacy which contributes to stability where development can’t be (or inherently isn’t) rapid or generally palpable. Moreover, improved chance of survival in democracies (Przeworski and 15 Limongi 1993:63) means steady and enduring development. If we take into consideration our previous conclusion that democracies are self-limiting in capacity and autonomy to develop rapidly, we have then, a crucial difference between regime types: Democracies are more likely to provide a stable platform on which development can be built and avoid policy disaster, but they are also inherently less likely to facilitate development to the miraculous degree that autocracies are able to.12 A further trend to point out between the two is that the advantages of regime type only come from consolidated regimes and at different stages in development. For democracy, first, good governance isn’t an inherent trait and at times the elite still enjoy certain extra-constitutional privileges above the rest of society. (Tsai 2006:262) Second, the benefits for development that democracy promises through property rights and effective allocation of resources through freedoms are annulled where the latter is in its infancy. (Addison 2002:47-48) Third, any hope of generating equality through the redistribution of resources is only possible when democracies are consolidated. (Mulé 1998:6-10) Finally democracy, as a developmental benefit in itself, (UNDP cited in Poltervich and Popov 2007:74), as ‘the good life’, must be recurrently institutionalised into the ‘hearts and minds’ for the freedoms to be appreciated and valued. For autocracies, the regime characteristics of stability and autonomy, which makes transformative development possible, are only a reality themselves where power is 12 Przeworski in Hadenius draw a similar conclusion; democracies are ‘less likely to go boom or bust’. (1997:166) 16 consolidated; where rule is accepted, stable and long-term. In furthering this conclusion, it is pertinent for our comparison to connect these consolidated regime types, and specifically their advantages, to their respective stages of development. Rapid development of the autocracies in our examples has only been through catch-up via industrialisation where the comparative advantage of a country is wagered on and maximized by state autonomy and capacity, using techniques and technology imported from the developed world. (Bhalla 1997:202-203) (Kim and Park 2004:118) However, quite interestingly, the advantages of democracy for development carry further weight when the state is better developed. As well as securing development politically, freedoms ensure better flow of information for better political decisions in more developed, information rich and complicated economy. (Przeworski et al. 2000:144) The advantages of democracy are also needed for research and design, allocating human resources where they are most suited, and generally for development on unknown grounds. To highlight from the previous paragraph, we didn’t argue that different regimes necessary favour different types of development (HD or GDP), only that they facilitate growth at different stages. In terms of HD, both democracy and the autocratic success stories alleviate absolute poverty and ensure basic education and healthcare and a comparison of the degree to which isn’t possible here. Despite these findings, no regime promises to unequivocally reduce inequality. For the South-East Asian autocracies inequality was exacerbated, even though for the East Asian autocracies, 17 specifically South Korea, almost incomparably reduced income inequality. For democracies, even being responsive to the masses (and hindering stateled investment (Przworski et al. 2000:144) (Leftwich 2000:158)) doesn’t necessarily guarantee equality. Income inequality is more likely a result of the (often gradual) marketization of the economy that both regime types pursue. What is noteworthy, however, is that where autocratic rule in South Korea evened the playing field as part of the transformative beginning for of long-term development (which wasn’t possible in democratic South Africa), democracy (once consolidated) offers a possible solution to inequalities later down the line of development if such policies are chosen. (Kohli 1986:160) To sum up, where our two regime types overlap in their positive causal relationship to development they rely on intermediaries such as good governance and stability (sought through legitimacy), which they guarantee/enable in different ways. Where democracy and our authoritarian case studies divide is particularly state autonomy and how they earn legitimacy, which results in varied state capacity, development promotion, growth rates and disaster prevention, among other attributes. The positive attributes of our consolidated authoritarian case studies suit them for initial development whereas consolidated democracy can have a positive impact on more developed states (who may increasingly define development differently). Neither regime type reliably ensures more substantial HD prospects than the other, (especially not for income equality). Conclusion 18 In this essay we have seen that democracy and autocracy diverge in promises for development. Generally, democracy seems to promote development and prevents developmental disasters. Autocracies, on the other hand, facilitate rapid and transformative development, where GDP growth is an obsession and HD is an obligation. We have also seen how the two regime types compare. This is exclusively through the intermediaries of good governance, stability and property rights, successful choice of policies (that often provides legitimacy) (not to mention economic factors, namely market liberalisation). Both regimes claim to foster these intermediaries in their respective environments and often do so in divergent ways. We are thus left with little evidence that it is regime type per se is the key determinant of HD or GDP growth13. Although it has a sizeable impact on the economic environment, it is just one integrated component that leads to policy choice. One tentative conclusion of this linkage has been that perhaps democracy is more likely to foster good governance, but where good governance meets state capacity and autonomy (which seems more likely to be found in autocracy), growth (and sometimes HD) can increase all the more dramatically. There are however some problematic implications with this conclusion. First of all, our analysis and conclusion of the developmental prospects of autocracy and democracy are more accurately those of two more relatively narrow sets of conditions; consolidated democracy and the Confucius authoritarian developmental states of Asia (that for purposes here we can 13 Leftwich makes a similar conclusion in stating that it’s not regime type that is important, but ‘kind and character’ of the state. (2000:133) 19 call consolidated autocracies). Advantages have been outlined from systems where their respective attributes work, leaving substantial middle ground where neither system takes root. We have also seen that the two can roughly merge in the middle where democracies have just a single party, but the applicability of such a system is also limited in reality. Secondly, and as an extension to the question, we perhaps should be asking what regime type better offers a prospect for sustainable development. Where rapid development has been a possibility, one is left wondering whether the ‘miracle success’ should be as coveted as often is done in the literature. (We are of course talking about development beyond raising HD to acceptable levels and eliminating absolute poverty). For the benefit of the environment14 and perhaps income equality15, is the miracle growth of East and South-East Asia desirable and something to be replicated across the world, especially when it doesn’t seem to promise guaranteed superior HD compared to democracy? Perhaps then, from a global perspective, the fact that democracies develop conservatively is not a vice after all, but a virtue. 14 See Higgott and Nesaduri on Thailand (2002:10-14) and Islam on China (1980:315) for the devastating effects this ‘miraculous’ development has had on the environment. 15 As well as the example in the text of Indonesia and South-East Asian countries, see also the autocratic development and the high resultant GINI coefficient of Brazil (Kohli 1986:158) 20 References Addison, T. (2002) ‘Economics’ in P. Burnell (ed) Democratization through the looking-glass, Manchester, New York: Manchester University Press, pp.41-55. Barbone, L., Cord, L., Hull, K., and Sandefur, J. (2007) ‘Democracy and poverty reduction: Explorations on the Sen conjecture’, in N. Dinello, and V. Popov (eds) Political institutions and development: Failed expectations and renewed hopes, Cheltenham, Northampton: Mass. Edward Elgar, pp.43-71. Beeson, M. (2004) ‘The rise and fall (?) of the developmental state: The vicissitudes and implications of East Asian interventionism’, in L. Low (ed) Developmental states: relevancy, redundancy reconfiguration? New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. Beetham, D. (1997) Democratization, 4(1), ‘Market economy and or pp.29-40. democratic polity’, pp.76-93. Bermeo, N. (2009) ‘Poverty, inequality, and democracy: Does electoral democracy boost economic equality? Journal of Democracy Volume 20, Number 4, pp.21-35. Bhagwati, J. (1995) ‘The new thinking on development’, Journal of Democracy 6(4), pp.50-64. Bhagwati, J. (2002) ‘Democracy and development: Cruel dilemma or symbiotic relationship?’, Review of Development Economics, 6(2), pp.151-162. Bhalla, S.S (1997) ‘Freedom and economic growth: A virtuous cycle?’ in A. 21 Hadenius (ed) Democracy's victory and crisis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp.195-241. Bradford, C.I. (1986) ‘East-Asian models: Myths and lessons’, in J. P. Lewis and V. Kallab (eds) Development strategies reconsidered, New Brunswick, N.J., U.S.A: Transaction Books, pp.115-128. Carbone, G. (2009) ‘The consequences of democratization’, Journal of Democracy, (20)2, pp.123-137. Deans, P. (2004) ‘The People’s Republic of China: The post-socialist developmental state’, in L. Low (ed) Developmental states: relevancy, redundancy or reconfiguration? New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. pp.133-146. Dent, C.M. (2004) ‘The new international political economy of East Asia and the developmental state’, in L. Low (ed) Developmental states: relevancy, redundancy or reconfiguration?, New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. pp.79-100. Higgott, R. and Nesadurai, H. (2002) ‘Rethinking the Southeast Asian Development Model (SEADM): governance questions in’, CSGR Working Paper Bringing ethical and No. 92/02 pp1-22. Huang, Y. (2008) Capitalism with Chinese characteristics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Islam, I. (1980) in A. Chowdhury, and I. Iyantul (eds) Beyond the Asian crisis: The path to economic growth, Elgar Publishing Limited. Jomo, K.S. (2004) ‘Southeast Asian developmental states in comparative East Asian perspective’, in L. Low, (ed) Developmental states: relevancy, redundancy or reconfiguration? 22 New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. pp.57-78. Kim, K. and Park, I.W. (2004) ‘East Asian financial crisis and reformation of the Korean state’, in L. Low, (ed) Developmental states: relevancy, redundancy or reconfiguration?, New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. pp.117-132. Kohli, A. (1986) ‘Democracy and development’, in J.P. Lewis and V. Kallab (eds) Development strategies reconsidered, New Brunswick, N.J., U.S.A.: Transaction Books pp.153-182 Leftwich, A. (2000) States of development: On the primacy of politics in development, Cambridge: Polity Press. Leftwich, A (2005) ‘Democracy and development: Is there institutional incompatibility?’, Democratization, (12)5, pp.686-703. Low, L. (ed) (2004) ‘Introduction and Overview’, in Developmental states: relevancy, redundancy or reconfiguration? New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. pp.3-28. Mehrotra, S., Park, I. and Baek, H. (2004) ‘Social policies in a growing economy: The role of the state in the Republic of Korea’, in S. Mehrotra and R. Jolly (eds) Development social achievement and with a human face: Experiences in economic growth, Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp.264-296. McGuire, M.C. and Olson, M. (1996) ‘The economics of autocracy and Majority rule: The invisible hand and the use of force’, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV, pp.72-96 Mulé, R. (1998) ‘Does democracy promote equality?’ Democratization, (5)1, pp.1-22. 23 Olson, M. (1993) ‘Dictatorship, democracy, and development’, The American Political Science Review, (87)3 pp.567-576. Polterovich, V. and Popov, V. (2007) ‘Democratization, institutional quality and economic growth’, in N. Dinello, and V. Popov, (eds) Political institutions and development:Failed expectations and renewed hopes, Cheltenham: Mass. Edward Elgar, pp.72- 100. Przeworski, A. and Limongi, F. (1993), ‘Political regimes and economic growth’, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, (7)3, pp.51-69. Przeworski, A. and Limongi, F. (1997) ‘Democracy and development’ in A. Hadenius (ed) Democracy's victory and crisis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp.163-194. Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M.E., Cheibub, J.A. and Limongi, F. (2000) Democracy and development: Political institutions and material well-being in the world, 1950-1990, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sen, A. (1997) ‘Human rights and Asian values: What Kee Kuan Yew and Le Peng don’t understand about Asia’, The New Republic (217)2, 3, pp.1-9. Tsai, M. (2006) ‘Does political democracy enhance human development in developing countries?’, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, (65)2, pp.233-268. UNDP (1997) ‘Governance for Sustainable Human Development’ A UNDP policy document, United Nations Development Program. United Nations (1995) Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific: The lessons of East/South-east Asian growth experience, New 24 York: United Nations. Varshney, A. (2000) ‘Why have poor democracies not eliminated poverty? A suggestion’, Asian survey, Vol. 40, No.5, pp.718-736. White, G. (1998) ‘Building a democratic developmental state: social democracy in the developing world’, Democratization (5)3, pp.1-32. 25