Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate · R. Kelley Pace

J Real Estate Finan Econ (2010) 41:103–125
DOI 10.1007/s11146-009-9190-2
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
Darren K. Hayunga · R. Kelley Pace
Published online: 21 May 2009
© Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2009
Abstract Portfolio theory shows that diversification can enhance the riskreturn trade-off. This study uses the absolute location of commercial real
estate property along with spatial statistics to address the inherent problem
of determining geographical diversification based upon a set of economic and
property-specific attributes, some of which are unobservable or must be
proxied with noise. We find that commercial real estate portfolios exhibit
statistically significant spatial correlation at distances ranging from adjacent
zip codes to neighboring metropolitan areas. Given the common structure
Research supported by a grant from the Real Estate Research Institute. We thank
an anonymous referee, Richard Buttimer, the editor, Jeff Fisher, David Geltner,
Marc Louargand, Glenn Mueller, Tony Sanders, C.F. Sirmans, and seminar participants
at the RERI conference, UNC-Charlotte, and UT-Arlington for their suggestions and
guidance. Special thanks to Robert White of Real Capital Analytics for data.
D. K. Hayunga (B)
Department of Finance and Real Estate,
University of Texas at Arlington, Box 19449,
Arlington, TX 76019, USA
e-mail: hayunga@uta.edu
R. K. Pace
LREC Endowed Chair of Real Estate, Department of Finance,
E.J. Ourso College of Business Administration,
Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, LA 70803-6308, USA
e-mail: kelley@spatial.us
URL: www.spatial-statistics.com
104
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
of dependence found in the data series, we discuss feasible strategies for
obtaining diversification within direct-investment real estate portfolios.
Keywords Spatial statistics · Commercial real estate · Portfolio diversification
With the introduction of inefficiencies into the real estate market such as those
suggested by Roulac (1976), diversification of portfolios that directly invest in
real estate assets is more complex than stock and bond portfolios. Specifically,
the local or spatial nature of real estate markets introduces a trade-off between
specialization and spatial diversification.
On the one hand, specialization enables investors to continue learning
and trading in previously researched and traded assets. To the extent such
information is costly, investors may be able to obtain a more precise understanding of future payoffs at a lower price.1 In applying specialization to a
direct-investment real estate portfolio, a manager may reduce information and
management costs as well as potentially increase returns from greater localmarket information.
On the other hand, specialization in managing real estate portfolios implies
holding properties within a limited geographic area (e.g., neighborhood or
metropolitan area). Since neighboring properties experience similar supply
and demand functions, labor markets, and regulations, prices of these properties within close proximity of each other will be positively correlated. However,
traditional diversification theory advocates holding portfolio assets that are
less-than-perfectly correlated. Moreover, using standard portfolio theory, we
show that spatial correlation between properties is an unsystematic risk. Thus,
portfolios that directly invest in real estate and experience spatial correlation
between properties may not be efficient.2
In addition to moving towards efficiency, a spatially-diverse portfolio may
benefit real estate portfolio managers in a different manner. Relative to wellestablished financial assets, distinguishing between unsystematic and systematic risk is more difficult for direct real estate portfolios. First, most portfolios,
as well as the indices, especially for individual real estate markets, may not
have a large number of observations. For example, the NCREIF index for
Baton Rouge began in 1995 and observations occur only quarterly. Second,
1 In support of this hypothesis, Radner and Stiglitz (1984) find that mutual fund managers with
higher asset concentrations by industry outperform diversified funds. Van Nieuwerburgh and
Veldkamp (2007) develop a rational model of investors who choose to specialize in trading a
set of highly-correlated assets because of asset costs. They find that returns to specialization in
information acquisition can explain why investors do not hold fully-diversified portfolios.
2 A lack of spatial diversification may also cause a problem for those portfolio managers that
owe a fiduciary responsibility to plan participants and beneficiaries. Endowments, ERISA plans,
and foundations may owe a fiduciary duty to decrease risk for a given return, which can lead to
geographical diversification.
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
105
the returns depend upon appraisals, which complicates partitioning systematic
and unsystematic risk. Potential clients may have difficulty discerning which
part of a firm’s performance comes from systematic versus unsystematic risk.
If clients use indices based on a large number of properties as benchmarks,
firms may have an incentive to reduce unsystematic risk.
We examine the trade-off between specialization and spatial diversification
by joining portfolio theory with the tools of spatial statistics. While previous
studies have identified the importance of geographic diversification—with the
regions of study advancing from four or eight U.S. zones to Metropolitan
Statistical Areas (MSAs) to neighborhoods within a city—the literature does
not use spatial tools for systematic examination of spatial dependence among
real estate properties. It is not surprising to find that nearby properties exhibit
some degree of spatial interdependence, but research questions exist regarding
(i) how much initial spatial correlation is present for juxtaposed properties,
especially for different commercial property types since diversification by
property type has been shown to be effective in other studies; (ii) how quickly
does the spatial correlation decay; and (iii) at what distance does the spatial
correlation decay to zero—a zero correlation allows real estate to be treated
like other financial assets in terms of portfolio risk.
With respect to the initial correlation of nearby properties, we find that
base commercial real estate returns and capitalization (cap) rates exhibit
correlation values ranging from 0.31 to 0.39 over a separation distance from
1/2 to 2 miles. As separation distances increase, spatial correlations decrease
but maintain magnitudes over 0.10 out to approximately 30 miles, depending
upon the dataset. In fact, for some metropolitan areas comprised of two
or more major cities, the spatial correlations between properties within the
greater metropolitan area can exhibit correlations of approximately 0.30 out to
40 miles. Lastly, the average correlation drops to zero at separation distances
beyond 45 miles.
Using the empirical results, we execute portfolio simulations involving three
scenarios. The first simulation applies the empirical spatial correlations to a
portfolio concentrated with one metropolitan area (MA).3 The results suggest
that inter-neighborhood diversification is helpful but that no amount of intraMA diversification will produce an efficient portfolio. The next and most
aggressive strategy to remove spatial correlation is total inter-MA diversification. This leads to an equally-weighted portfolio holding one property
per MA. But while this portfolio composition mitigates spatial correlation,
an equally-weighted portfolio strategy is not macro-consistent. Based upon
2002 NCREIF property counts, 69% of the real estate held by institutional
investors is concentrated within the largest 16 MAs. There are simply not
3 The
term Metropolitan Area (MA) was adopted in 1990 by the U.S. Office of Budget and
Management and refers collectively to MSAs (urbanized place of over 50,000 people), Primary
Metropolitan Statistical Areas (Contiguous MSAs of over 1,000,000 people), and Consolidated
Metropolitan Statistical Areas (Combinations of PMSAs that form a larger, interrelated network).
106
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
enough qualifying properties to allow all direct-investment portfolios to hold
one property per MA.
A different strategy is to hold a few properties per MA within a limited
number of MAs. This will reduce idiosyncratic risk, but simulations demonstrate that no combination entirely removes spatial portfolio risk. Further, as
more MAs are added, the portfolio converges to an equally-weighted portfolio
with one property per MA. Again, the equally-weighted portfolio reintroduces
management costs and a lack of specialization. Other potential strategies
include adding international real estate assets and indirect investments such
as REITs and the S&P/GRA Commercial Real Estate Indices derivative
contracts.
Overall, this study demonstrates that spatial correlation in real estate yields
unique results when compared to textbook finance models using nonspatial
financial assets. Whereas unsystematic risk decreases as less-than-perfectlycorrelated assets are added to a nonspatial portfolio (e.g., Fama 1976),
direct-investment real estate portfolios are inefficient if managers add more
properties within a localized market.
Geographical Diversification Literature
Diversification of real estate portfolios has been the subject of research for
over two decades. The two predominant paths of analysis are diversification
either by (1) property type or (2) geographic or economic regions. Initially,
Miles and McCue (1982) find that diversification by property type generates
better characteristics than a strategy based upon geographic regions. Subsequently, Hartzell et al. (1986) analyze commingled real estate fund returns
and find that geographic diversification is not as influential as diversification
by property type. One of the challenges in the Hartzell et al. (1986) study
is that four broad regional classifications form the basis for the geographical
diversification. Hartzell et al. (1987) refine the geographical area to eight areas
based upon common regional economies. They contend that by using smaller
economic regions, geographical diversification plays a role in real estate portfolio diversification.
The next progression in geographical diversification is the replacement of
regional or political boundaries (e.g., state borders) with economic definitions.
Wurtzebach (1988) removes geography boundaries and classifies cities based
upon their dominant industry employment type and employment growth
patterns. Subsequently, Mueller and Ziering (1992) test Wutzebach’s diversification strategy and find that economic diversification offers an improvement over geographic regions. Mueller (1993) also finds that a diversification
strategy based upon nine SIC code categories provides superior diversification
capabilities for a large real estate portfolio. Williams (1996) examines MSAs
and finds that economic-base diversification by industry and government
services at the MSA level yields diversification benefits.
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
107
Because diversification across heterogeneous regions should help reduce
idiosyncratic risk in a real estate portfolio, additional studies examine
other ways to identify location-specific economic forces. At the MSA level,
Goetzmann and Wachter (1995) identify families of cities based upon common
economic characteristics. Looking inside the MSA, Wolverton et al. (1998) find
gains in real estate portfolio efficiency through intracity diversification. Nelson
and Nelson (2003) use over 50 socioeconomic measures, depending upon the
year, to find that regions are not always contiguous.
Overall, the extant literature establishes that geographic grouping based
upon economic characteristics dominates geographic division based upon
political boundaries, and smaller regions, such as MSAs or neighborhoods,
are more appropriate for diversification than four or eight national regions.
Our contribution in this paper extends the understanding of geographic diversification, not as a function of any type of preconceived political or economic
definition, but as a direct function of the separation distance between actual
properties through the use of spatial statistics.
A challenge for any spatial-diversification study is the inherent problem in
capturing all the socioeconomic variables in a model. Even with a detailed and
extensive dataset, not every possible economic consideration will be modeled
due to a lack of prior understanding of economic boundaries, data availability,
and the unobservability of certain aspects (e.g., investor sentiment). Alternatively, basing geographical diversification of real estate portfolios on spatial
correlation factors as separation distance increases is a systematic method for
measuring idiosyncratic risk. As an example, Fik et al. (2003) demonstrate how
the use of Cartesian {x, y} coordinates and the unique location-value signature
of each real estate property increases a model’s ability to explain variability.
The application of separation distances and spatial statistics is new to
commercial real estate, however, prior use of spatial statistics is found in the
residential-market literature.4 Dubin (1998) models correlations between
houses as a function of distance in a hedonic pricing model using Baltimore
data. Basu and Thibodeau (1998) examine spatial correlation in Dallas house
prices and find spatial techniques generally improve ordinary least squares
(OLS). Dubin et al. (1999) present an overview of modeling spatial dependence in real estate.
Spatial Dependence and Portfolio Theory
To apply spatial statistics to commercial real estate portfolios, we begin by
examining the spatial implications of portfolio theory. Using the moments of
mean and variance, modern portfolio theory identifies the relation between
the relevant risk of an investment and its expected return. When a risk-free
4 See Cressie (1993) and LeSage and Pace (2009) for details regarding spatial statistics and
econometrics.
108
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
asset exists, the relation between the relevant risk of any portfolio holding
risky assets (including a real estate portfolio) and its expected return can be
expressed directly as the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of Lintner (1965)
and Sharpe (1964). Hence, the CAPM quantifies and prices relevant risk. Since
the CAPM assumes that all investors hold their entire wealth in the market
portfolio, the variance of the market portfolio quantifies the risk exposure for
all investors. Mathematically, this is expressed as the familiar equation for risky
asset j as,
r j − r f = β j Rm − r f ,
(1)
where the price of risk or the expected risk premium on the right-hand side
of the equation is the covariance between the returns of the market portfolio
and the risky asset j. In short, the risk premium demanded by investors is
proportional to beta.
A main insight provided by CAPM is that every asset, in equilibrium, must
be priced such that the risk-adjusted rate of return falls exactly on the security
market line. Thus, theory shows that investors can diversify away all risk except
the covariance of an asset with the market portfolio. In other words, a property
of the CAPM is the irrelevance of specific asset or idiosyncratic risk. Any risk
that is in excess of its covariance with the market is diversifiable.
We can apply this last statement directly to a real estate portfolio that
experiences spatial correlation between properties, and determine if there
exists any risk that is in excess of the covariance between the risky real estate
asset and the market portfolio. We begin, similar to Sharpe’s (1963) diagonal
model or Copeland et al. (2005, p. 152), with the simple return generating
equation of the market model,
R̃j = a j + bj R̃m + ˜ j,
(2)
where a j and bj are constants, R̃m is the market return, and ˜j is a random error
term. This general equation denotes that the return on any specific asset is a
linear function of the market return plus a random error term.
Combining individual assets into a portfolio, Markowitz (1952) shows the
expected return and risk of that portfolio. The return is a function of the weight
of each asset in the portfolio, wj, and its return as specified by Eq. 2. Taking
expectations leads to the portfolio return of
E R̃p =
N
j=1
⎛
⎞
N
wj a j + ⎝
wj bj⎠ Rm .
(3)
j=1
The variance of the return is used to express portfolio risk, which is the sum
of the mean return differences squared. Thus, the portfolio variance is the sum
of the variance and covariance terms weighted by the portion of an asset’s
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
value to the entire portfolio as VAR(Rp ) =
109
N
N wi wj COV R̃i , R̃j , which can
i=1 j=1
also be expressed using correlations as in Eq. 4.
VAR(Rp ) =
N
N wi wj σi σjCORR R̃i , R̃j ,
(4)
i=1 j=1
where N is the total number of risky assets, wi and wj are the proportions
invested in each asset, σi and σj are the standard deviations of the two risky
assets, and CORR R̃i , R̃j is the correlation between the returns from asset
i and asset j. We show the correlation expression because we express our
empirical results in subsequent sections using correlations due to the well
known range of values from +1 to −1.
Equipped with the general equation for portfolio risk in Eq. 4, we can
examine a real estate portfolio with at least two spatially dependent risky
assets. Using the standard definition of covariance, COV R̃i , R̃j = E R̃i R̃j −
E R̃i E R̃j , and the standard assumptions (e.g., Blume 1971) where E ˜q = 0
and E ˜q Rm = 0 for q = i, j we can express portfolio risk as COV R̃i , R̃j =
bi bj σm2 + E ˜i ˜j or as the correlation equivalent of
bi bj σm2
E ˜i ˜j
+
.
(5)
CORR R̃i , R̃j =
σi σj
σi σj
A standard assumption in portfolio theory is that the error term ˜j in Eq. 2
is independent of the market portfolio and independent of error terms in
the return-generating process of other risky portfolio assets, thus, E(˜i ˜j) = 0
in Eq. 5. Substituting the remaining Eq. 5 into Eq. 4 yields VAR(Rp ) =
N N
wi wjbi bj[σm2 ].
i=1 j=1
Since σm2 is a constant that depends neither on i nor j and there is not a
variable that depends jointly on the indices
i and j, we can2regroup terms
N
N
N
2
such that VAR(Rp ) =
σm . And by
wi bi
wj bj σm2 =
wi bi
i=1
j=1
i=1
taking the square root of both sides, we see that portfolio risk expressed as
standard deviation in Eq. 6 depends upon the weighted average of the beta of
the individual assets, which is the standard result of, for example, Equation 2
in Blume (1971),
N
σ Rp =
wi bi σm .
(6)
i=1
The problem with spatial correlation in a real estate portfolio is that
COV(i , j) = 0 does not hold, thus, E(˜i ˜j) does not drop out as zero. The
question then becomes how far apart should properties be for COV(i , j) = 0
110
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
to hold? We put numbers to this question in the next section by applying spatial
statistics to multiple real estate datasets. Before examining the empirical results one point worth emphasizing is that the above analysis does not show that
eliminating the unsystematic spatial risk removes all portfolio risk. Obtaining
spatial independence between the random error terms is not the same as total
portfolio independence. The systematic portion in Eq. 5 is still present.
Commercial Property Results
We empirically examine commercial real estate data in this section to determine the necessary separation distances between commercial real estate
properties needed for COV(i , j) = 0 to hold. We use the spatial correlogram for many of our tests, the mathematical foundation of which is in the
appendix (found at spatial-statistics.com). In short, the correlogram computes
a correlation for an attribute (e.g., asset return) for every two properties as a
function of the distance between the properties. Small separation distances
should produce high correlations. As the separation distance increases, the
magnitude of the correlations should decrease.
We compute the experimental correlograms using two data sources. The
NCREIF dataset provides returns for apartment, industrial, office, and retail
properties. In addition to providing analysis for multiple property types, a
further benefit of the NCREIF data is the ability to test within an MA at the
zip code level. The other data source consists of apartment sale transactions,
which were provided by Real Capital Analytics (RCA). From both datasets,
we remove the observations from Alaska and Hawaii due to the spatial
discontinuity with the rest of the sample.
Spatial Correlation of NCREIF Returns
Since our focus in this section is the spatial aspects of real estate returns, we
initially control for time-series impacts by modeling the geometric mean of
four NCREIF quarterly returns from the second quarter of 2002 to the first
quarter of 2003. The resulting sample is 140 property returns. We compute
correlations for every observation pair and contrast them against the distances
of separation.5
In applying spatial statistics to real estate data, observations are not uniformly separated by a certain distance. Instead, real estate data are irregularly
spaced sample points. Therefore, it is standard practice to use intervals or
5 We
project the locations using the Transverse Mercator map projection (Snyder and Voxland
1989). This allows treating the points from a sphere (the Earth’s surface) as if they were on a plane
(a map).
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
111
bins such that observations at a certain separation distance plus observations
at separation distances close to the exact separation distance are grouped
together and the average correlation is used in the analysis (please see appendix for more detail about lags and lag tolerance). During the course of
our examination of spatial correlations, we find that the empirical results are
sensitive to the size of the bins. Our results detail the experimental correlograms that yield the most observations per interval using the smallest separation distances. The common suggestion in the literature is to have at least
30 pairs or 60 observations per interval (Journel and Huijbregts 1978, p. 194).
Using bins sizes with enough observations, Panel A of Table 1 details the
results using the NCREIF commercial real estate returns. The base returns
exhibit a spatial correlation of 0.38 at the separation distance of 2 miles. The
correlation decreases to 0.22 at 5.9 miles and 0.12 at 13.7 miles. The results
demonstrate that spatial correlation using base NCREIF returns is mitigated
by approximately 18 miles.
Spatial Correlation of NCREIF Return Residuals
Equation 5 above shows that spatial correlation is an idiosyncratic risk beyond
the systematic risk of the market portfolio. Thus, we next investigate the spatial
nature of the unsystematic portion of the property returns. We regress the
market return on the individual property returns and use the resulting residuals
to compute the correlogram. We use the NCREIF National Property Index
Table 1 Spatial correlations
as a function of separation
distance using NCREIF
commercial real estate returns
Avg. separation
distance (in miles)
Number of
observations
Panel A: base returns
2.0
58
5.9
108
9.8
154
13.7
116
17.6
152
Panel B: market model residual returns
2.0
58
5.9
108
9.8
154
13.7
116
17.6
152
Panel C: property type residual returns
2.0
58
5.9
108
9.8
154
13.7
116
Panel D: aggregate model residual returns
2.0
58
5.9
108
9.8
154
13.7
116
Experimental
correlogram
0.38
0.22
0.10
0.12
−0.04
0.36
0.19
0.13
0.10
−0.07
0.29
0.12
0.11
−0.07
0.25
0.12
0.12
−0.05
112
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
(NPI) as our proxy for the market portfolio.6 Both the overall model and the
individual beta estimate on the market portfolio are significant at the 5% level,
however, the adjusted R2 is 0.01.
After controlling for the market return, we model the residual return correlations across separation distance. Panel B of Table 1 details the results. There
is a slight reduction in the magnitude of the spatial correlations compared to
the base returns, however, the reduction is not dramatic.
Given that the market model is somewhat limited over the short sample
period, we investigate other determinants of real estate returns. The NCREIF
data include office, retail, multifamily, and industrial property types, therefore,
we consider a model that controls for the four types since this variety of diversification is well established in the literature. We also examine various economic
variables as well as proxies for size and quality. Insomuch as Wurtzebach
(1988), Mueller and Ziering (1992), and Mueller (1993) find that economicallybased diversification is preferable to purely geographic diversification, we
incorporate the economic variables detailed by Mueller (1993) and Cheng and
Black (1998) in the following model.7
Ri,t = β0 + β1 · ln(AV ESQFT) + β2 · ln(NU MU N IT S)
+ β3 · ln(MV L AST) + β4 · APT + β5 · I N D + β6 · OFF ICE
+ β7 · RET AI L +
12
β j · POP +
j=8
20
βk · EMPLOY
k=13
+ β21 · RAT I O + β22 · MIG + i,t
6 In
the spirit of Stambaugh (1982) we also examine using the global equity indices of Russell
Global Index and MCSI World Index as a proxy for the market model. Despite the fact that the
Russell Global Index is based upon approximately 10,000 global stocks or 98% of the investable
global universe, we find that equities are not a significant fit for US commercial real estate
properties.
7 The economic variables control for aspects of the real estate demand curve (Miles et al. 2007,
p. 26). Demand for retail space and apartments is a function of household composition and
population. Along with the overall population for a specific zip code, we break out population
by five age groups with breakpoints at 19, 34, 49, and 65, which is consistent with Cheng and
Black (1998). We execute the model with and without the breakpoints and find no difference
in the results. We also include the demand-side variables of median income and average house
price scaled by median household income. The demand for other commercial property—office
buildings, factories, and warehouses—is more closely tied to labor force and employment. To
control for these effects along with the economically-based diversification noted in Mueller (1993)
we use employment levels using the 2002 North American Industry Classification System codes
of 1) mining and agriculture, 2) utilities and construction, 3) manufacturing, 4) wholesale and
retail trade along with transportation and warehousing, 5) information, finance, insurance, real
estate, and profession, scientific and technical services, 6) education and health care, and 7) arts,
entertainment, and food services. Lastly, we account for changes in population and employment
using the migration of persons into the zip code.
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
113
where
Ri,t
AVESQFT
NUMUNITS
MVLAST
APT
IND
OFFICE
RETAIL
POP
EMPLOY
RATIO
MIG
the rate of return on the ith property for the tth quarter,
average square feet,
average number of units, which is used by some apartment
complexes instead of the avesqft. measure,
average market value from t − 1 quarter,
dichotomous variable equal to 1 if the property is an
apartment complex and 0 otherwise,
dichotomous variable equal to 1 if the property is an industrial
building and 0 otherwise,
dichotomous variable equal to 1 if the property is an office
building and 0 otherwise,
dichotomous variable equal to 1 if the property is a retail
building and 0 otherwise,
population as one continuous variable and divided into five
age groups,
employment by industry,
ratio of average house price to median household income, and
migration of persons into a zip code.
This specification explains more of the variation in property returns compared to the market model—the adjusted R2 is 0.15. Almost all of explanatory
power is due to the property-type variables. Each is significant with p-values
less than 0.01. The only significant economic variable is migration with a
p-value of 0.06.
As before, upon controlling for property type, employment, population,
et cetera, we use the residuals to compute the correlogram. Panel C of
Table 1 details the results. Compared to the base returns in Panel A, the
findings in Panel C demonstrate a material reduction in residual correlation
at most separation distances. Initial correlation decreases from 0.38 to 0.29.
At 5.9 miles, residual correlation is 0.12 versus 0.22 using base returns. Also,
the findings suggest that the point of randomness is found by 13.7 miles in
separation distance as compared to 17.6 miles using base returns.
Note that the residuals from a regression using returns as the dependent
variable can behave differently from a spatial perspective than just using the
raw returns. As one extreme, if the correlations between property returns all
stem from property type and economic variables, the resulting residuals will
not show any correlation over space. As another extreme, suppose that two
contiguous properties have almost perfect spatial dependence when controlling for other factors, but each property has many other characteristics that
cause the returns to diverge. In this case, the raw returns will show a smaller
correlation than the residuals—which will display very high levels of spatial
dependence. Consequently, controlling for various property characteristics can
result in residuals that display either lower or higher spatial dependence than
the raw returns.
114
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
Given the success of property type to examine return correlation our last
specification examines the market model along with property type and the
economic variables. Modeling property returns using this aggregate model we
find that property-type variables are the main determinants of returns.
The results in Panel D of Table 1 detail the spatial correlations after
controlling for the various factors in the aggregate model. The findings in
Panel D are similar to Panel C with a slight reduction in the initial residual
correlation—from 0.29 to 0.25. As before, spatial correlation is mitigated if
properties are separated by approximately 13 miles.
Apartment Cap Rates
The correlogram results thus far provide the benefits of examining diversification across property types and within a zip code submarket. However, a
concern of the NCREIF data is that the values are based on appraisals. The
use of appraisals is a potential issue because empirical evidence suggests that
appraisals smooth changes in property values, which causes downward-biased
estimates of total return volatility (Geltner 1991).
To protect against the specific panel of data driving the results, we compute
correlograms based on cap rates of apartment complexes from January 2001 to
December 2003. The cap rates offer another real estate measure using marketdriven transaction prices. Further, the cap rates provide over one million
individual pairs to compute the experimental correlogram, which allows us to
detail smaller separation distances.
Table 2 presents the results of spatially modeling the base cap rates. Similar
to the NCREIF results, the initial spatial correlation is 0.39. With more data,
the results demonstrate a slower spatial correlation decay—correlation values
of 0.18 extend out to approximately 21 miles. The results demonstrate that the
base cap rates obtain zero spatial correlation at approximately 32 miles.
Similar to our treatment of the NCREIF returns, we next examine the
spatial characteristics of cap rate residuals. We examine residual returns after
controlling for the building features of size, the number of units, and age.
We do not examine the market model or economic variables with this dataset
because the cap rates are a point-in-time measure resulting in insufficient data
to estimate a market model for these returns.
Table 3 present the results after controlling for structural features. Overall,
the residual results are quite similar to the base cap rates with slight reductions
in correlation at the same separation distances. The initial correlation is 0.36
and the separation distance when spatial correlation is effectively mitigated is
approximately 32 miles.
To summarize the empirical results thus far, we find that for both NCREIF
returns and RCA cap rates the initial correlation is approximately 0.38. Additionally, the greatest reduction in spatial correlation occurs at approximately
5 miles. This distance is likely referencing the neighborhood submarket and
suggests a portfolio should realize diversification benefits by holding properties
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
115
Table 2 Spatial correlations
as a function of separation
distance using RCA cap rates
Avg. separation
distance (in miles)
Number of
observations
Experimental
correlogram
0.5
1.4
2.3
3.3
4.2
5.1
6.0
7.0
7.9
8.8
9.8
10.7
11.6
13.5
14.4
15.3
16.3
17.2
20.9
24.6
28.4
31.2
32.1
740
1,254
1,498
1,890
2,216
2,310
2,428
2,416
2,582
2,614
2,602
2,470
2,446
2,436
2,330
2,296
2,422
2,310
1,876
1,672
1,488
1,312
1,290
0.39
0.35
0.28
0.34
0.31
0.21
0.21
0.20
0.23
0.19
0.26
0.18
0.23
0.26
0.17
0.19
0.20
0.22
0.18
0.13
0.14
0.11
0.04
Table 3 Spatial correlations
as a function of separation
distance using RCA cap
rate residuals
Avg. separation
distance (in miles)
Number of
observations
Experimental
correlogram
0.5
1.4
2.3
3.3
4.2
5.1
6.0
7.0
7.9
8.8
9.8
10.7
11.6
13.5
14.4
15.3
16.3
17.2
20.9
24.6
28.4
31.2
32.1
740
1,254
1,498
1,890
2,216
2,310
2,428
2,416
2,582
2,614
2,602
2,470
2,446
2,436
2,330
2,296
2,422
2,310
1,876
1,672
1,488
1,312
1,290
0.36
0.33
0.27
0.33
0.30
0.19
0.18
0.19
0.22
0.19
0.24
0.16
0.21
0.25
0.15
0.16
0.18
0.21
0.18
0.21
0.13
0.09
0.04
116
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
beyond the neighborhood. This thought meets prior expectations and is intuitively appealing as neighborhoods have previously been characterized as
lacking diversification. For example, Goodman (1977) defines neighborhoods
as “small urban areas with. . . a common set of socioeconomic effects.” Beyond
the neighborhood, the results suggest that a portfolio manager will receive a
reduction in spatial correlation, however, spatial correlations can exist out to
20 miles in separation distance, and farther.
CMSAs
The return and cap rate results use strict Euclidean distance. Our next test
examines the return correlations of primary metropolitan statistical areas
(PMSAs) that comprise a larger consolidated metropolitan statistical area
(CMSA). For example, the Fort Worth-Arlington and Dallas PMSAs form the
Dallas-Fort Worth CMSA.
We examine the return correlations between PMSAs to ensure spatial
discontinuity is not affecting the results. For example, the western portion of
the U.S. has large expanses of rural land, and since commercial properties
cluster in metropolitan areas, we want to ensure large distances between
sample observations are not driving the results.
We use NCREIF data to compute PMSA return correlations. Unlike the
previous two datasets, NCREIF MAs offer a data panel due to the availability
of a significantly longer time series for major metropolitan areas. The shortest
continuous time series is 27 quarters, the longest is 98 quarters, and the
average is slightly greater than 16 years. To isolate the spatial component,
we model PMSA residuals after controlling for time-series effects using the
vector autoregressive (VAR) model similar to Englund et al. (2002). The combination of contiguous PMSAs and sufficient time series yields 28 PMSA-pair
observations.
The residuals from the VAR model should produce time-series white noise.
However, we find that 50% of the PMSA pairs continue to exhibit residual
positive correlations with p-values less than 0.10. Both the mean and median
correlation of these statistically-significant observations is 0.42. The range of
separation distances is from approximately 9 miles to almost 84 miles. The
results exhibit a cluster of observations with an average residual correlation of
0.40 ranging from 23.8 to 38.9 miles in separation distance.
We also find that three PMSA pairs exhibit correlations of 0.44, 0.47, and
0.65 at separation distance greater than 40 miles. These correlations are not
inconsistent with prior findings. In fact, these results introduce a point that
we will reinforce later. Keeping in mind that these residual correlations are
PMSA pairs that are part of a contiguous CMSA, the high correlations at
greater distances alert real estate portfolio managers to the need to expand
beyond MAs. Separation distances as great as 83 miles, in this case Chicago
and Milwaukee, can experience significant return correlation when the PMSAs
are part of a larger socioeconomic region.
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
117
Residential Property
In addition to multiple commercial property databases and attributes, we
examine the impact of residential property on the spatial aspects of commercial
property. While most commercial real estate investment portfolios will not
incorporate residential property, local housing markets can serve as a proxy for
phenomena that also affect the behavior of commercial property. Additionally,
residential returns can provide a better proxy for the market model than
the NPI index in the previous section since residential returns are specific
to the local market and are subject to similar real estate supply and demand
functions. The standard spatial equilibrium model in urban economics predicts
similar longer-run movements in different real estate sectors because each is
driven by common fundamentals (Rosen 1979; Roback 1982). We examine
residential returns in this section and then combine commercial and residential
data types in the next section.
We compute residential returns from the Neighborhood Change Database,
a dataset that geographically standardizes the U.S. decennial census based
upon year 2000 census tracts. We compute 9000 base residential returns initially aggregated at the zip code level. The resulting correlogram specifications
use over forty million pairs. Table 4, Panel A details the time period from 1970
to 1990.
The residential results demonstrate a similar magnitude of initial spatial
correlation as commercial properties—an average of 0.35. The difference is
that the separation distance is 30.61 miles. As separation distance increases
spatial correlation decays monotonically to zero at a separation distance of
approximately 1,100 miles; a considerably longer distance than the commercial
property results.
Table 4 Spatial correlations
as a function of separation
distance using residential
returns from 1970 to 1990
Avg. separation
distance (in miles)
Panel A: base returns
30.61
153.05
306.10
459.15
612.20
765.25
918.30
1,010.13
Panel B: residual returns
15.31
30.61
76.53
153.05
229.58
306.10
382.63
428.54
Number of
observations
Experimental
correlogram
345,901
513,825
709,321
832,363
816,794
670,650
652,836
722,171
0.35
0.35
0.19
0.14
0.12
0.09
0.06
0.01
4,783,788
6,198,538
4,178,956
4,888,290
5,898,176
6,483,273
7,302,486
7,112,267
0.19
0.17
0.22
0.22
0.20
0.07
0.09
0.03
118
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
Similar to commercial returns, it is reasonable to expect that there exist
observable determinants that explain a portion of the correlation. Thus, we
regress the base residential returns by some typical determinants of housing
prices. As expected, all independent variables are statistically significant at the
5% level. The specification is
Ri,t = β0 + β1 · ln(EDUC12) + β2 · ln(EDUC16) + β3 · ln(H OMEPOP)
+ β4 · ln(I NCOME) + β5 · ln(SI Z E) + β6 · ln(BLT OC70)
+ β7 · ln(BLT OC59) + β8 · ln(BLT OC49) + β9 · ln(BLT OC39) + i,t ,
where
Ri
EDUC12
EDUC16
HOMEPOP
INCOME
SIZE
BLTOC
the rate of return on the ith house,
persons 25 years old or older who completed high school,
persons 25 years old or older who completed college,
number of persons 25 years old or older,
average family income,
aggregate number of rooms in the home, and
total occupied housing units built up to the year specified in
the variable.
Using the residuals, we compute the return correlations for each observation within census tracts. The residuals are not aggregated across zip codes
but left within census tracts since each observation is the remaining portion
not explained by the model, and, thus, is unique information. This method
produces millions of observations within each bin.
Table 4, Panel B details the residential residual returns findings. At the
shortest separation distance of 15.31 miles, the initial spatial correlation is 0.19.
This magnitude of spatial correlation persists out to approximately 230 miles.
While the degree of spatial correlation is not surprising, it is important to
note that, using on millions of observations, residential properties extending
150–225 miles in separation distance demonstrate an empirical correlation of
roughly 0.20.
Combining Commercial and Residential Types
Given the voluminous amount of data available for residential real estate, we
examine the effect of including the residential property type in the commercial analysis. Inclusion in the correlogram is based upon the rationale that
commercial and residential markets are affected by similar socioeconomic
conditions at common locations. Another argument comes from the kriging
spatial literature (see Goovaerts 1997, pp. 185–258). The reasoning follows that
if the secondary residential returns are correlated with the primary commercial
returns, then one can utilize observations at sites where they are both recorded
to estimate this correlation. Hence, we match residential returns by location
and include them as an explanatory variable in the NCREIF commercial
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
119
Table 5 Spatial correlations as a function of separation distance using NCREIF commercial real
estate residual returns after controlling for residential property returns
Avg. separation
distance (in miles)
Number of
observations
Experimental
correlogram
2.0
5.9
9.8
58
108
154
0.31
0.11
0.01
return specification along with the other property characteristics. We lag
the residential returns one quarter to avoid potential simultaneity between
commercial and residential prices in the same quarter. The other change from
the previous NCREIF specification is that the market return as well as the
property-type and economic variables are removed since residential real estate
is a proxy for fundamental characteristics at common locations.
The lead residential returns appear to be a quality proxy for the socioeconomic determinants of commercial returns. The findings in Table 5 suggest
that spatial correlation is mitigated at about 10 miles in separation distance; a
distance shorter than the residual results using the Aggregate Model in Panel
D of Table 1.
Applying Empirical Results to Portfolio Theory
Given the empirical findings in the previous section, we next consider portfolio
implications under three scenarios. At one end of the spectrum is the scenario
whereby a commercial real estate portfolio holds properties greater than
40 miles. Using U.S. Census Bureau centroids, we note that there are no MAs
within the largest 50, as measured by population, that are within 45 miles of
any of the other largest 50 MAs.8 Further, 4,945 out of the 4,950 pairs of the
most populated 100 MAs are at least 45 miles apart, and 11,162 out of the
11,175 pairs of the largest 150 MAs are separated by at least 45 miles. Overall,
99.88% of the possible pairs from the 270 conterminous U.S. MAs are over
40 miles in separation distance.
Hence, a strategy to effectively mitigate spatial risk in a real estate portfolio
is to hold one property per MA, regardless of the type of property. By
holding one property per MA, the portfolio will not experience intra-MA
spatial correlation and, given the sufficient spacing of each MA, inter-MA
correlation is not an issue. This strategy is intuitively appealing since real estate
markets are localized and allocating properties across MAs should create a
more diversified portfolio.
8 The MAs referenced here are distinct metropolitan areas and not PMSAs; otherwise, a real estate
portfolio manager may experience spatial correlations based upon the CMSA results above.
120
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
To examine this strategy further and based upon a reviewer’s comments,
we execute another test using the NCREIF data from Table 1. Instead of
modeling residuals after controlling the market return, property-type, or
demand variables, we spatially model residuals after controlling for the unconditional average for an entire metro area. For continuity, we maintain the
same separation distances as in Table 1. The results (not tabled) demonstrate
that properties within the first two bins and separated by 2 and 5.9 miles,
respectively, yield spatial correlations of approximately 0.14. After 5.9 miles,
the spatial correlation is mitigated. These results reinforce two main points of
this paper: (i) adjacent or juxtaposed properties will experience neighborhood
and MA socioeconomic factors that are difficult to diversify, and (ii) unique
MAs appear to be sufficient for portfolio diversification as the unconditional
MA average is effective in removing correlation for distances beyond a neighborhood submarket.
Note, however, that a strategy of one property per MA is not macroconsistent. The design implies an equal weighting across MAs and not all
large-scale real estate portfolios can hold one property per MA due to a lack
of acceptable properties in mid- to small-sized MAs. For example, the largest
16 MAs in the third quarter of 2002 comprised 68.9% of the total properties
reported to NCREIF. The largest 35 MAs held 85.0% of the NCREIF property
counts.
Intra-MA portfolio
Given macro-inconsistency, we consider owning properties within the same
MA, but in diverse neighborhoods. We note that some of the greatest rate of
decay in spatial correlation occurs beyond juxtaposed properties. We create
portfolios using a square grid of properties where the adjacent properties are
5 and 10 miles apart. We compute other non-square configurations and find
that the results are not sensitive to the configuration but are a function of
the number of properties that have sufficient separation distance to mitigate
spatial correlation. We use the results of the RCA cap rate residuals in
Table 3 since the number of observations is sufficient to generate correlation
values at separation distances consistent with CMSA findings (greater than
20 miles) and the residuals account for some observable determinants of prices.
Keeping with the theory above, we use correlation values to compute the
portfolio standard deviations, thus, without lose of generality, we standardize
the standard deviations to unity and focus on the relative improvement of
increasing the separation distance.
Figure 1 presents the increase in portfolio standard deviations due to spatial
correlation using an intra-MA strategy. The standard deviation values in Fig. 1
indicate the unsystematic portion of portfolio risk due to the spatial correlation
between the properties.
The top line in Fig. 1 is the relative portfolio risk with each portfolio
property separated by 5 miles. The bottom line is the relative portfolio risk
using separation distances of at least 10 miles. Of course, 10 miles in separation
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
121
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
σp 0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
4 9 16
25
36
49
64
81
100
121
144
N
Fig. 1 Portfolio standard deviation as a function of the number of real estate properties if
a portfolio holds intra-MA properties only. Values demonstrate the increase in unsystematic
portfolio risk due to the average spatial correlation between portfolio properties. The top line
marked with stars represents a portfolio with at least 5 miles of separation distances between
properties. Using diamond markers, the bottom line is the additional unsystematic risk with
properties separated by at least 10 miles. The values not connected by a line use properties with
10 miles of separation distance, which require MSAs larger than exist in the US
distance decreases unsystematic risk, although the reduction is not as great
for smaller portfolios (i.e., 4 or 9 properties) as it is for portfolios of 25 or
36 properties. We extend the values of the 10-mile portfolio (unconnected
diamonds) for reference purposes. These portfolio are unfeasible as there are
no MAs large enough to hold the number of properties each 10 miles apart.
Both graphed scenarios in Fig. 1 demonstrate that there is practical limit
for reducing intra-MA unsystematic risk—no matter the size of the portfolio,
lingering spatial risk will be present since properties are not sufficiently separated.9 Although not graphed, we find that portfolios with properties separated
by 15 or 20 miles still experience unsystematic spatial risk. Thus, no amount of
intra-MA diversification will entirely mitigate spatial portfolio risk.
Value-weighted portfolio
As a final scenario, we envision holding a few properties within an MA over
a small number of MAs. This strategy yields a value-weighted portfolio that
9 Additionally,
the values do not account for levered cash flows, which will increase portfolio risk.
122
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
can be based upon a metric like MA population. A portfolio manager may
be able to reduce unsystematic risk by spreading property holdings across a
few MAs without incurring exorbitant search and portfolio management costs.
Hence, we build real estate portfolios holding 25 properties using portfolio
weighting based upon Census populations as of the year 2000. We assume
the portfolio manager mitigates intra-MA spatial risk to the greatest extent
possible by holding properties at the longest separation distances within an
MA. Figure 2 details the findings.
In general, this value-weighted portfolio reduces unsystematic risk when
compared to the intra-MA strategy but still does not entirely mitigate spatial
portfolio risk. A manager will gain the greatest reduction in portfolio risk by
holding properties in the largest six MAs, which is consistent with Cheng and
Roulac (2007) who also examine geographic diversification across multiple
MSAs. The results of their “Mixed MSA” scheme indicate the greatest reduction in portfolio risk at approximately the seventh MSA. Despite the reduction
in unsystematic risk of these portfolios, the six-MA portfolio in Fig. 2 is still
inefficient—13% of the unsystematic spatial risk remains. Another overall
issue with the value-weighted portfolio is that it converges to an equallyweighted portfolio. As properties are added, beginning with the nine-MA
portfolio, the next new city adds one property that is taken from the previously
smallest city holding two properties.
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
N
5
10
15
20
Fig. 2 Portfolio standard deviation as a function of the number of metropolitan areas in a value
weighted portfolio. Portfolio weights based upon metropolitan population as of the year 2000.
Values demonstrate the unsystematic portion of portfolio risk due to spatial correlation between
the properties
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
123
In summary, the three scenarios (one property per MSA, all properties in
one MSA, and value weighted) demonstrate that spatial correlation in real
estate portfolios is different than traditional finance models using nonspatial financial assets. Whereas unsystematic risk is reduced in the standard
finance textbook as more less-than-perfectly-correlated stocks are added to
an equity portfolio, real estate portfolios are inefficient if they hold multiple
properties within a localized market such as a neighborhood or MA. Since
no amount of intra-MA diversification will produce an efficient portfolio, a
portfolio manager directly investing in real estate assets must look to interMA diversification.
Conclusion
Real estate is a field built on the notion of location, yet the literature has not
employed formal spatial techniques to examine the effects of geography on
commercial property portfolios. Consistent with the importance of location
on commercial property prices, we use spatial statistics to quantify the spatial
correlation between commercial real estate properties. Understanding the
spatial component within a commercial portfolio is essential since fundamental
portfolio theory shows that spatial correlation is an unsystematic risk that
should not be compensated by the market.
Using return and cap rate data, this paper examines the magnitude of initial
spatial correlation, spatial correlation as a function of separation distance,
and the distances of separation between commercial properties needed to
essentially eliminate spatial dependence. With respect to the initial correlation
of nearby properties, we find that base commercial real estate returns and cap
rates exhibit correlation values ranging from 0.31 to 0.39 over a separation
distance from 1/2 to 2 miles. As separation distances increase, spatial correlations decrease but maintain magnitudes over 0.10 out to approximately
30 miles, depending upon the dataset. The average correlation drops to zero at
separation distances generally beyond 45 miles.
These findings, combined with intra-MA simulations, suggest that interneighborhood diversification is helpful in moving towards efficient portfolios.
However, no amount of intra-MA diversification will entirely dispose of spatial
portfolio risk. To effectively diversify, real estate portfolios require inter-MA
diversification with the most beneficial diversification strategy being one property per MA regardless of the type of property. But inter-MA diversification
has its limits as, by one NCREIF measure, 69% of the portfolio-quality real
estate is concentrated in the largest 16 MAs. There are not enough qualifying
properties for all real estate portfolios to hold an equally-weighted portfolio.
The results suggest that combining intra-MA and inter-MA properties is one
of the best strategies for reducing the unsystematic spatial risk while trading off
the portfolio management costs of holding geographically-diverse properties.
The fact that this combination portfolio still does not eliminate spatial portfolio
risk provides motivation for using international direct-real estate holdings and
124
D.K. Hayunga, R.K. Pace
indirect real estate investments in portfolios. A further consideration of the
results of this study is to apply the correlations found here in a constrained
optimization framework that determines the trade-off between diversification
and increased portfolio management costs.
References
Basu, S., & Thibodeau, T. (1998). Analysis of spatial autocorrelation in house prices. Journal
of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 17, 61–85.
Blume, M. (1971). On the assessment of risk. Journal of Finance, 26(1), 1–10.
Cheng, P., & Black, R. (1998). Geographic diversification and economic fundamentals in apartment markets: A demand perspective. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 4(2),
93–105.
Cheng, P., & Roulac, S. (2007). Measuring the effectiveness of geographical diversification. Journal
of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 13(1), 29–44.
Copeland, T., Weston, J., & Shastri, K. (2005). Financial theory and corporate policy. Reading:
Pearson Addison Wesley.
Cressie, N. (1993). Statistics for spatial data. New York: Wiley.
Dubin, R. (1998). Predicting house prices using multiple listings data. Journal of Real Estate
Finance and Economics, 17, 35–59.
Dubin, R., Pace, R. K., & Thibodeau, T. (1999). Spatial autoregression techniques for real estate
data. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 7, 79–95.
Englund, P., Hwang, M., & Quigley, J. (2002). Hedging housing risk. The Journal of Real Estate
Finance and Economics, 24(1–2), 167–200.
Fama, E. (1976). Foundations of finance. New York: Basic Books.
Fik, T., Ling, D., & Mulligan, G. (2003) Modeling spatial variation in housing prices: A variable
interaction approach. Real Estate Economics, 31(4), 623–646.
Geltner, D. (1991). Smoothing in appraisal-based returns. Journal of Real Estate Finance and
Economics, 4, 327–345.
Goetzmann, W., & Wachter, S. (1995). Clustering methods for real estate portfolios. Real Estate
Economics, 23(3), 271–310.
Goodman, A. (1977). Comparison of block group and census tract data in a hedonic housing price
model. Land Economics, 53, 483–487.
Goovaerts, P. (1997). Geostatistics for natural resources evaluation. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Hartzell, D., Hekman, J., & Miles, M. (1986). Diversification categories in investment real estate.
AREUEA Journal, 14(2), 230–254.
Hartzell, D., Shulman, D., & Wurtzebach, C. (1987). Refining the analysis of regional diversification for income-producing real estate. Journal of Real Estate Research, 2(2), 85–95.
Journel, A., & Huijbregts, C. (1978). Mining geostatistics. New York: Academic.
LeSage, J., & Pace, R. K. (2009). Introduction to spatial econometrics. Boca Raton: CRC.
Lintner, J. (1965). The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock
portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics, 47, 13–37.
Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77–91.
Miles, M., Berens, G., Eppli, M., & Weiss, M. (2007). Real estate development. Washington, DC:
Urban Land Institute.
Miles, M., & McCue, T. (1982). Historic returns and institutional real estate portfolios. AREUEA
Journal, 10(2), 184–198.
Mueller, G. (1993). Refining economic diversification strategies for real estate portfolios. Journal
of Real Estate Research, 8(1), 55–68.
Mueller, G., & Ziering, B. (1992). Real estate portfolio diversification using economic diversification. Journal of Real Estate Research, 7(4), 375–386.
Nelson, T., & Nelson, S. (2003). Regional models for portfolio diversification. Journal of Real
Estate Portfolio Management, 9(1), 71–88.
Spatial Statistics Applied to Commercial Real Estate
125
Radner, R., & Stiglitz, J. (1984). A nonconcavity in the value of information. In M. Boyer, &
R. Khilstrom (Eds.), Bayesian models in economic theory. New York: Elsevier.
Roback, J. (1982). Wages, rents, and the quality of life. Journal of Political Economy, 90(4), 1257–
1278.
Rosen, S. (1979). Wage-based indexes of urban quality of life. In P. Mieszkowski, & M. Straszheim
(Eds.), Current issues in urban economics. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Roulac, S. (1976). Can real estate returns outperform common stocks? Journal of Portfolio
Management, 2(2), 26–43.
Sharpe, W. (1963). A simplified model for portfolio analysis. Management Science, 9(2), 277–293.
Sharpe, W. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk.
Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425–442.
Snyder, J., & Voxland, P. (1989). An album of map projections. Washington, DC: US Government
Printing Office.
Stambaugh, R. (1982). On the exclusion of assets from tests of the two-parameter model: A
sensitivity analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 10(3), 237–268.
Van Nieuwerburgh, S., & Veldkamp, L. (2007). Information acquisition and under-diversification.
NYU working paper. New York: NYU.
Williams, J. (1996). Real estate portfolio diversification and performance of the twenty largest
MSAs. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 2(1), 19–30.
Wolverton, M., Cheng, P., & Hardin, W. (1998). Real estate risk reduction through intracity
diversification. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 4(1), 35–41.
Wurtzebach, C. (1988). The portfolio construction process. Parsippany: Prudential Real Estate
Investors.
Copyright of Journal of Real Estate Finance & Economics is the property of Springer Science & Business
Media B.V. and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the
copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for
individual use.