Introduction; Monopoly Economics 302 - Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior Instructor: Songzi Du compiled by Shih En Lu Simon Fraser University January 6, 2016 ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 1 / 25 What’s this class about? Game theory “game”: interaction of people. In life you have to interact with others, therefore you have to know how to play games. Applying game theory to study markets Economics of information ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 2 / 25 Why is this class hard? Abstract reasoning Abstraction: focusing on one or a few aspects of a complex situation. Using math. You need to know differential calculus. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 3 / 25 This Course Read the syllabus! My office hours: Tuesday 10:30-12:20 in WMC 4657 (but not this week). TAs’ OHs: 2 hours/week Textbooks: none required. See syllabus for recommended text. Slides will be posted at http://www.sfu.ca/~songzid/302. Take your own notes! ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 4 / 25 Homework 7 assignments. Discuss problems with each other - most of you will learn a lot from each other - but write your own solutions. Due at the end of lecture on Tuesday 20% of your grade Each problem is graded for completeness. Use them as practices for exams. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 5 / 25 My Expectations Never fall behind. The class material is cumulative. You should understand everything in a week’s lecture slides by the end of the week. Everybody should really do the assignments and practice exams. You cannot learn game theory by listening to lecture and reading lecture slides. The final grade distribution will be set according to the Economics department guidelines. You will not be penalized for low class averages on exams. Half of the quiz and midterm points can be transferred to the final. Read the syllabus and course policies carefully and never ask for an exception: the answer is NO. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 6 / 25 Derivatives and Maximization 6 5 f HxL 4 f ' H1L 3 2 1 1 2 3 4 5 f 0 (x) is the slope of the tangent line at the point (x, f (x)). At maximum of f (x), f 0 (x) = 0. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 7 / 25 Derivatives and Maximization (f (x) + g (x))0 = f 0 (x) + g 0 (x) Product rule: (f (x)g (x))0 = f (x)g 0 (x) + f 0 (x)g (x). f (x) = ax k , where a and k are constants. Then f 0 (x) = ak · x k−1 . f (x) = ln(x), then f 0 (x) = 1/x. Review: quotient rule and chain rule. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 8 / 25 What Is a Monopoly? A firm that is the only one in the market, i.e., no firm produces a close substitute. As a result, a monopoly does not lose all its demand when it raises price above marginal cost: it has market power. A monopoly picks a point on the market demand curve. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 9 / 25 Sources of Monopoly Government policy 1 2 Directly owned/regulated by the state (ICBC) Patents (drugs), copyrights (music), trademarks (brand names), licenses (nightclubs), etc. Large efficient scale 1 2 Natural monopoly: decreasing average cost over the relevant range of quantities (utilities) Network externalities on the demand side (Microsoft Office) Firm actions 1 2 Control of essential input (DeBeers) Being more efficient than other firms and/or preventing entry (Walmart) - this is different ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 10 / 25 Profit Maximization Today, we assume that the monopoly charges the same price to every customer. No price discrimination. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 11 / 25 Profit Maximization Today, we assume that the monopoly charges the same price to every customer. No price discrimination. Notation: P = price per unit, q = quantity. Demand curve D(P) — the number of people willing to buy at price P; their willingness-to-pay is greater than P. Inverse demand curve: P(q), firm’s cost function: C (q) Profit: π(q) = P(q)q − C (q) (Total Revenue - Total Cost) First-order condition: π 0 (q) = P(q) + P 0 (q)q − C 0 (q) = MR(q) − MC (q) = 0 ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 11 / 25 Profit Maximization (II) FOC: Marginal Revenue = P(q) + P 0 (q)q = C 0 (q) = Marginal Cost This pins down the monopoly quantity qm . Read the price off the demand curve: Pm = P(qm ). Note: Because P 0 (q) < 0, we have MR < P whenever q > 0. In words: the monopolist chooses the quantity where marginal revenue equals marginal cost and charges the maximum price that bears that quantity. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 12 / 25 Profit Maximization: Some Caveats We have assumed that the demand and cost functions are differentiable, and the good is perfectly divisible. We have assumed that the second-order condition (π 00 (q) < 0) holds, i.e. that MR intersects MC from above. We will usually deal with decreasing MR and increasing MC , in which case this automatically holds. Just like for perfectly competitive firms, you need to check that the monopoly wouldn’t prefer shutting down. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 13 / 25 Example Demand: D(P) = 12 − 12 P Monopolist’s cost: C (q) = q 2 Find the monopoly price and quantity. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 14 / 25 Example Demand: D(P) = 12 − 12 P Monopolist’s cost: C (q) = q 2 Find the monopoly price and quantity. Monopolist solves: max q · 2(12 − q) − q 2 q FOC: 2(12 − q) − 2q − 2q = 0. Monopoly quantity qm = 4, monopoly price Pm = 16. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 14 / 25 Welfare 20 15 P 10 5 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 q Continue with our example: MC (q) = 2q and P = 24 − 2q ⇒ qm = 4. Set equal the marginal social cost and benefit (willingness-to-pay) ⇒ 2q = 24 − 2q ⇒ q = 6. Units between 4 and 6 yield a benefit between 16 and 12, but only cost between 8 and 12. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 15 / 25 Welfare Both the consumers and the monopolist would be better off if: two additional units were produced by the monopolist and sold at a price of 12 to consumers whose willingness-to-pay is between 16 and 12 the monopolist keep the “regular” price of Pm = 16, which is for consumers whose whose willingness-to-pay is above 16 this improvement assumes that the monopolist is able to identify consumers who have lower willingness-to-pay. For example: price discounts offered to students (student ID), senior citizens (driver’s licence), etc. The monopoly outcome is not Pareto efficient: everyone (consumers and the monopolist) could be better off! ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 16 / 25 Welfare 20 15 P 10 5 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 q The deadweight loss (inefficiency) is the area between the demand and marginal cost curves, from the actual quantity to the efficient quantity, = 12 × (6 − 4) × (16 − 8) = 8 in this example. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 17 / 25 Price, Marginal Cost and Elasticity at the Monopolist’s Optimum Remember FOC: P(q) + P 0 (q)q = C 0 (q) P − MC = − dP dq q ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 18 / 25 Price, Marginal Cost and Elasticity at the Monopolist’s Optimum Remember FOC: P(q) + P 0 (q)q = C 0 (q) P − MC = − dP dq q P−MC P q 1 = − dP dq P = , where is the price elasticity of demand: =− dq/q dP/P Equivalently, markup = ECON 302 (SFU) P − MC 1 = . MC −1 Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 18 / 25 Price, Marginal Cost and Elasticity at the Monopolist’s Optimum Remember FOC: P(q) + P 0 (q)q = C 0 (q) P − MC = − dP dq q P−MC P q 1 = − dP dq P = , where is the price elasticity of demand: =− dq/q dP/P Equivalently, markup = P − MC 1 = . MC −1 Markup over marginal cost gets lower as elasticity increases: the firm’s market power decreases. What happens when → ∞? ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 18 / 25 Example Continued We found qm = 4 and Pm = 16. Marginal cost is C 0 (q) = is 100%. Thus = P P−MC ECON 302 (SFU) = 16 16−8 d 2 dq (q ) = 2q, so it is 8 at qm . The markup = 2. Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 19 / 25 Example Continued We found qm = 4 and Pm = 16. Marginal cost is C 0 (q) = is 100%. Thus = P P−MC = 16 16−8 d 2 dq (q ) = 2q, so it is 8 at qm . The markup = 2. Now lets find directly using the demand D(P) = 12 − 12 P. = ECON 302 (SFU) dq dP − q P =− Lecture 1 − 12 4 16 = 2. January 6, 2016 19 / 25 Estimated Price Elasticities of Demand in U.S., 1990s Salt Matches Toothpicks Airline travel, short-run Gasoline, short-run Gasoline, long-run Residential natural gas, short-run Residential natural gas, long-run Coffee Fish (cod) consumed at home Tobacco products, short-run Legal services, short-run Physician services Taxi, short-run Automobiles, long-run 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.7 0.1 0.5 0.25 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.6 0.6 0.2 Movies Housing, owner occupied, long-run Shellfish, consumed at home Oysters, consumed at home Private education Tires, short-run Tires, long-run Radio and television receivers Restaurant meals Foreign travel, long-run Airline travel, long-run Fresh green peas Automobiles, short-run Chevrolet automobiles Fresh tomatoes 0.9 1.2 0.9 1.1 1.1 0.9 1.2 1.2 2.3 4.0 2.4 2.8 1.2 – 4.0 4.6 Source: http: //scholar.harvard.edu/files/alada/files/price_elasticity_of_demand_handout.pdf ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 20 / 25 Why Would a Government Create a Monopoly? Monopolies come with a deadweight loss. Why create them? The government might take control of a monopoly that would exist anyway (e.g. utilities). The government can generate revenue or reduce expenditures by selling the right to form a monopoly (e.g. certain toll highways). The government might want to encourage innovation through patents and copyright. The alternative would be to subsidize, which increases the need for revenues and could therefore increase deadweight losses elsewhere. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 21 / 25 What Can Government Do about Monopolies? Divestiture: monopolies that control a key resource can be forced to sell off some of that resource. For example, AT&T had to sell off its local operations in 1982. In other cases, such as natural monopolies, the government can still affect the price: 1 2 through taxes (or subsidies); directly through regulation. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 22 / 25 Taxes and Monopolies Does taxing a monopoly improve efficiency? It does redistribute money from the monopoly (and its customers) toward the government. Just like under perfect competition, there is a tax wedge between the curves determining quantity. Here, they are the MR and MC curves (rather than the supply and demand curves). Once you know the quantity, read the price paid by consumers (consumer’s price, Pc ) off the demand curve. The price received by the monopoly (monopolist’s price, Pm ) is Pc less the tax. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 23 / 25 Taxes and Monopolies: Per-unit Tax Return to our example: MC (q) = 2q, P(q) = 24 − 2q and MR(q) = d(P(q)q) = 24 − 4q. dq We found qm = 4 and Pm = 16 with no taxes. Now suppose there’s a per unit tax of 6. Find the new quantity, price paid by consumers and price received by the monopolist. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 24 / 25 Taxes and Monopolies: Per-unit Tax Return to our example: MC (q) = 2q, P(q) = 24 − 2q and MR(q) = d(P(q)q) = 24 − 4q. dq We found qm = 4 and Pm = 16 with no taxes. Now suppose there’s a per unit tax of 6. Find the new quantity, price paid by consumers and price received by the monopolist. Monopolist solves maxq P(q)q − C (q) − 6q. 24 − 4qm = 2qm + 6 With tax: qm = 3, Pc = 18, Pm = 18 − 6 = 12. Per-unit tax of 6 increases the consumer’s price by only 2. Does tax leads to the efficiency of P(q) = MC (q)? No, we are even farther away from market clearance. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 24 / 25 Taxes and Monopolies: Ad Valorem (Sales) Tax Instead of a per unit tax of 6, in the previous example suppose there’s a percentage tax (sales tax) of 100% of the price received by the monopoly (equivalently, 12 of the price paid by consumers). ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 25 / 25 Taxes and Monopolies: Ad Valorem (Sales) Tax Instead of a per unit tax of 6, in the previous example suppose there’s a percentage tax (sales tax) of 100% of the price received by the monopoly (equivalently, 12 of the price paid by consumers). Monopolist solves: max q 1 (24 − 2q)q − q 2 , 1+t where t = 100%, FOC: 1/2 · (24 − 4qm ) − 2qm = 0, or qm = 3. Consumer’s price Pc is still read off the demand curve: Pc = 18. But what does the monopoly get now? Monopolist’s price 1 Pm = 1+t Pc = 9. 1 In words: total revenue is 1+t = 12 of what it was without tax at every q. Thus so is marginal revenue ⇒ MR(q) = 12 − 2q. Setting MR = MC gives: 12 − 2qm = 2qm , or qm = 3. ECON 302 (SFU) Lecture 1 January 6, 2016 25 / 25