How financial and social incentives affect worker absenteeism; evidence from a regime shift within a firm. Karl Over Aarbu and Gaute Torsvik October 26, 2012 Summary A regime shift in sickness absence compensation This paper examines a regime shift in the compensation of sickness absence. The data is from the customer service centre of an insurance company. Agents work in teams. In 2001 the firm added a team bonus, based mainly on team sales, to the workers’ salaries. Since the bonus was intended to become a permanent pay supplement, a union agreement obliged the firm to negotiate its design with labour representatives. One of their requirements was that workers sickness absence should be compensated: if a team member called in sick, the team could assign the average team sales to the person being absent. At the commence of 2004 the firm decided to terminate the negotiated bonus scheme, but it did not relegate the performance bonus. Instead of a permanent bonus plan the management introduced quarterly campaigns. It was mainly a change in names. There was, however, one significant adjustment; with short term campaigns the firm was no longer obliged to negotiate the outline of the bonus with worker representatives. When the management unilaterally could design the bonus scheme, they decided to abolish the compensation of worker absence. Hence, in the first quarterly campaign introduced in April 2004 an absent worker would get zero sales as long as he or she was not at work. The overall magnitude of the bonus was kept at the same level as before, but it was partly individualized. In the performance pay contract that the firm refused to renew in 2004 the sales bonus agents received depended solely on team sales; if the average sales in the team was above 102 % of the team‘s sales budget each team-member would earn an additional 2000 NOK. After the reform 50% of the 1 sales bonus was based on individual sales. To identify the causal impact of the regime shift we compare sickness absence in the customer service unit before and after the reform with the development of sickness absence in other divisions of the firm, not affected by the reform. This gives us a clear cut experimental change in the financial and social incentives associated sickness absence which can shed light on several research and policy questions. Of course, if sickness absence is solely determined by the health of the workers the reform should not cause any change in sickness absence (unless of course one asserts that the reform will influence the health of the workers, which is unlikely). If, however, attendance involves an element of choice - if moral hazard is an issue - we need to examine how the regime shift in dealing with sickness absence changes the incentives for attending work. In the following section we develop a simple conceptual framework capturing the main concerns governing this choice. Expectations We argue that there two reasons for expecting sickness absence to decline after the reform. One is the unpleasantness of letting the team down; not attending work will now reduce the chances of reaching the team‘s sales target. The other reason for expecting reduced absenteeism is standard economic incentives; after the reform an agent will reduce his or her chances of attaining the bonus if absent from work. There is however also an argument that predicts an increase in worker absenteeism. Many lab experiments, often framed as a employer employee relationship, show that strong reciprocity is a forceful human motivation. Humans with strong reciprocity motivation are willing to take actions that lower their own income if it increases the income of someone who have behaved generous and cooperative towards them, and, on the negative side, are willing to forgo income in order to punish someone who have behaved in a negative, disrespectful, controlling way. A one sided abolishment of a generous, trusting, contract that basically insured the workers against bonus losses due to absence, must be characterized as a negative act. Workers may want to reciprocate this change with being more absent from work, even if it means a personal income loss. We believe our study is a nice test of the relevance of reciprocity outside the lab. 2 Results The abolishment of sickness absence compensation lead to a strong drop in absenteeism. For males we estimate (diff in diff) the drop to be as high as 34 %, while the drop for women was 16%. We consider placebo reforms in other years, but cannot detect any significant drop in sickness absence. We conclude that sickness absence are (were) troubled with strong moral hazard problems. We also conclude that if strong reciprocity was a concern for these agents, this motivation was totally swamped by the change in the other incentives for attending work. We struggle to find a clean test to separate the relative force of the two proposed explanations; (i) attendance increased because workers do not want to to let their team down (ii) attendance increased because workers do not want to loose their bonus. One way to untangle this question is to examine if there is a change in workers effort while they are at work (intensive margin). Using part time workers, who are not eligible for a bonus as a control, we find some evidence that the agents exposed to the bonus system work harder to sell insurance after the reform. This observation lends credence to the personal income explanation; agents attend work more often and work harder because they are motivated by the individual sales bonus. But there is also indications that team pressure is an important concern or motivation at this workplace. 3