BEFORE THE RÉGIE DE L'ÉNERGIE IN THE MATTER OF: HYDRO QUÉBEC DISTRIBUTION Demande du Distributeur relative à l'établissement des tarifs d'électricité pour l'année tarifaire 2008-2009 DOSSIER R-3677-2008 prepared on behalf of: l'Association québécoise des consommateurs industriels d'électricité (AQCIE) 28 October 2008 Conseil de l'industrie forestière du Québec (CIFQ) prepared evidence of: Robert D. Knecht Industrial Economics, Incorporated 2067 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02140 INTRODUCTION 1 . P O S T- PAT R I M O N I A L G E N E R AT I N G C O S T A L L O C AT I O N 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 My name is Robert D. Knecht. I am a Principal and the Treasurer of Industrial Economics, Incorporated (“IEc”), a consulting firm located at 2067 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA 02140. As part of my consulting practice, I prepare analyses and expert testimony in the field of regulatory economics. In Canada, I have submitted expert evidence in regulatory proceedings in Québec, Ontario, Alberta, New Brunswick, Nova Scotia, Manitoba, and Prince Edward Island. In matters regarding Hydro Québec Distribution (“HQD”), I have submitted evidence or reports before the Régie in dockets R-3477-2001, R-3492-2002 (Phases 1 and 2), R-3541-2004, 35632005, R-3579-2005, R-3610-2006, R-3644-2007, R-3648-2007 and R-3673-2008. I obtained a B.S. degree in Economics from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in 1978, and a M.S. degree in Management from the Sloan School of Management at M.I.T. in 1982, with concentrations in applied economics and finance. My curriculum vitae and a schedule of my expert evidence presented to regulatory tribunals during the past five years are attached as Exhibit RDK-1. 15 16 17 I was retained by l'Association québécoise des consommateurs industriels d'électricité (“AQCIE”) and the Conseil de l'industrie forestière du Québec (“CIFQ”) to evaluate the following aspects of HQD’s filing: 18 19 • Allocation of post-patrimonial generating costs, particularly the treatment of net resale costs; 20 • Revenue allocation, and tracking historical cross-subsidies; 21 • Tariff design for Rate L. PLEASE PROVIDE THE BACKGROUND FOR YOUR EVIDENCE IN RESPECT OF THE 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 In Decision D-2007-12, the Régie directed that HQD implement “the hourly method” for allocating post-patrimonial generating costs in this proceeding. HQD indicates that it has adopted that methodology. In Decision D-2008-024, the Régie affirmed the use of the hourly method, but it directed HQD to conduct additional analysis regarding the methodology for allocating HQD’s supply costs associated with the resale of power. 30 31 32 33 34 35 In this evidence, I review the overall results of HQD’s hourly methodology to demonstrate that they continue to be inconsistent with the economics of electricity generation . However, I address specifically only the issue of the allocation of stranded costs. In the category of stranded costs, I include both the fixed costs associated with not operating the TransCanada Energy (“TCE”) Bécancour generating station and the net costs associated with surplus power resales. 36 37 38 39 H O W D O T H E R E S U LT S O F H Q D ’ S A L L O C AT I O N O F P O S T- PAT R I M O N I A L A L L O C AT I O N O F P O S T- PAT R I M O N I A L G E N E R AT I O N C O S T S . G E N E R AT I N G C O S T S I N T H I S P R O C E E D I N G C O M PA R E W I T H T H E R E S U LT S P R E S E N T E D I N T H E P R E V I O U S T W O P R O C E E D I N G S I N W H I C H T H E “ H O U R LY M E T H O D ” WA S U S E D F O R C O S T A L L O C AT I O N ? Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 1 1 2 3 4 5 A summary of the results of the hourly cost allocation methodology, applied in 2007, 2008 and 2009, are shown in Table IEc-1 below, for the major rate classes. Note that I have made the comparison on a cents-per-kWh of energy generated, as that more accurately reflects the relative costs of generation supply to each rate class, because it is measured before losses. TABLE IEC-1 POST-PATRIMONIAL SUPPLY COSTS HOURLY METHOD CENTS PER KWH OF ENERGY GENERATED 2007 2008 2009 Rate D 8.2 8.3 9.5 Rate G 8.3 8.5 10.5 Rate M 8.0 8.5 10.4 Rate L 8.0 8.8 10.4 Total HQD 8.1 8.6 10.1 6 7 8 9 10 Table IEc-1 gives rise to several observations. First, the per-kWh post-patrimonial generation costs have increased substantially in 2009. This is due at least in part to HQD having retained capacity in excess of its needs, resulting in the need to both resell this excess capacity at a loss and to incur fixed costs associated with keeping the TCE Bécancour generation facility shut down. 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 Second, the table indicates that in both 2008 and 2009 the hourly method produces results that are at odds with generation economics, with traditional generation cost allocation methods and with current market prices. Generation economics dictates that the cost of producing power during off-peak periods is lower than the cost of producing power on-peak. For that reason, both traditional cost allocation methods and modern markets for electric power imply that the unit cost to serve high load factor customers should be below that for lower load factor customers. 18 19 20 HQD’s method produces the reverse result, with the lowest load factor class (the residential class) being assigned the lowest per-kWh generation cost. This result remains unique in my experience. 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 I N T H E E V I D E N C E T H AT Y O U P R E S E N T E D I N L A S T Y E A R ’ S P R O C E E D I N G , Y O U H Y P O T H E S I Z E D T H AT AT L E A S T PA RT O F T H I S U N U S U A L R E S U LT WA S D U E TO H Q D ’ S T R E AT M E N T O F T H E A C C O U N T I N G L O S S E S T H AT I T I N C U R S O N S U R P L U S V O L U M E S . WA S Y O U R H Y P O T H E S I S C O R R E C T ? In part it was. However, as HQD witness Mr. Coté indicated last year, the primary reason why the hourly method produces the very unusual results shown above is the lack of any signal for peak demand or capacity in the method, as well as the lack of any differentiation in energy costs in on-peak and off-peak periods. However, based on the analysis presented by HQD in this proceeding, I conclude that HQD’s treatment of the losses on the resale of surplus volumes contributes to the problem. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 2 1 2 3 4 5 To illustrate this conclusion, Table IEc-2 below compares the results of HQD’s analysis of its 2008 post-patrimonial costs using the approved hourly method and that using a capacity cost signal. Note that this comparison excludes the effects to resold surplus suppliers.1 I start by reviewing the 2008 analysis, because it excludes the effects of the TCE stranded costs. TABLE IEC-2 POST-PATRIMONIAL SUPPLY COSTS EXCLUDING SURPLUS RESALE COSTS HOULY METHOD WITH AND WITHOUT CAPACITY COST 2008 TEST YEAR CENTS PER KWH OF ENERGY DELIVERED Without Capacity Signal With Capacity Signal Percent Difference Residential 8.27 10.76 30.1% Small and Medium General 8.14 9.12 12.0% Large Industrial 7.85 8.02 2.2% Total HQD 8.07 9.24 14.5% Source: HQD-11, Document 4; HQD-16, Document 9, Table R-21.2 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 Table IEc-2 demonstrates that for 2008, the hourly method produces results that are directionally correct, although there is virtually no differentiation among rate classes. Moreover, what little differentiation that appears results primarily from differences in class loss factors and not from any differentiation in actual costs. When a capacity price signal is factored in, however, the results show a more traditional inter-class pattern. Thus, I agree with Mr. Coté’s conclusion that the primary reason for the unusual results is the absence of a capacity price signal, as well as its failure to recognize any differentiation in the time-of-use cost of energy. 14 15 16 Nevertheless, HQD’s treatment of the resold volumes makes the problem worse. Table IEc-3 compares the allocated 2008 unit costs both before and after the effects of surplus resales are considered. 1 Note that the inclusion of a capacity price signal affects the amount of costs that are deemed to be associated with the surplus resale volumes. It appears that HQD’s “with capacity” signal assigns no capacity costs to resold volumes, where the hourly method implicitly includes those costs in the hourly costs assigned to resale volumes. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 3 TABLE IEC-3 POST-PATRIMONIAL SUPPLY COSTS HOULY METHOD WITH AND WITHOUT SURPLUS RESALE EFFECTS 2008 TEST YEAR CENTS PER KWH OF ENERGY DELIVERED Before Resale Including Resale Percent Residential 8.27 9.09 9.9% Small and Medium General 8.14 9.23 13.4% Large Industrial 7.85 9.31 18.6% Total HQD 8.07 9.21 14.1% Source: HQD-11, Document 4 1 2 3 4 5 Thus, it is apparent that something in HQD’s methodology is causing a disproportionate increase in costs allocated to the business classes, particularly the high load factor large industrial class. That is, the effect of surplus resales on the large industrial class is 1.46 cents per kWh or 18.6 percent of allocated cost, compared to an impact on the residential class of 0.82 cents per kWh or 9.9 percent of allocated cost. 6 7 8 9 10 11 Turning to the 2009 analyses, it is apparent that at least one other problem has cropped up. Table IEc-4 below is similar to Table IEc-3, except that it is based on the 2009 test year. Because I had the hourly information for 2009, I segregated the results for the small and medium general service customers, and I presented the results on a perunit of energy generated basis. Additional supporting information for these calculations is shown in Exhibit IEc-2 at the back of this evidence.2 TABLE IEC-4 POST-PATRIMONIAL SUPPLY COSTS HOULY METHOD WITH AND WITHOUT SURPLUS RESALE 2009 TEST YEAR CENTS PER KWH OF ENERGY GENERATED Residential Before Resale Including Resale Percent 9.17 9.48 3.4% Small General 9.83 10.49 6.7% Medium General 9.76 10.42 6.8% Large Industrial 9.73 10.37 6.6% Total HQD 9.54 10.07 5.6% Source: HQD-11, Document 4 2 Supporting hourly information in electronic format is available to parties to this proceeding upon request to AQCIE/CIFQ counsel. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 4 1 2 3 The two major changes between 2008 and 2009 are (a) the per-kWh costs of providing post-patrimonial supply increased sharply from 2008 to 2009 and, (b) the allocation of costs in 2009 before the effect of resale volumes is distorted. 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 While it is impossible to know for certain what causes these changes, it appears that both of these results are influenced by HQD’s treatment of the fixed costs of the TCE Bécancour facility.3 Rather than treating those fixed costs as stranded, HQD apparently decided to include those costs as part of hourly supplies, even though there will be no supplies from that facility. In effect, the hourly costs for the postpatrimonial energy that will actually be supplied from other generators are substantially overstated. Moreover, judging by the inter-class results, it is apparent that the treatment of the TCE stranded costs is further skewing the cost allocation results. As shown in Table IEc-4 above, the introduction of TCE stranded costs in 2009 resulted in more distortion in the “before resale” results than that in 2008 (in Table IEc-3). 15 16 17 18 19 20 B E F O R E A D D R E S S I N G T H E S P E C I F I C S O F H Q D ’ S A L L O C AT I O N M E T H O D O L O G Y In Exhibit IEc- 3, I attach three figures that provide an overview of HQD’s postpatrimonial stranded cost issues. 21 22 23 24 25 26 Figure IEc-1 compares the post-patrimonial load for Rate D and Rate L. Unlike past years in which the load shapes were unusual, the 2009 load patterns are much more consistent with overall HQD loads. In particular, the Rate D load shows the pronounced winter peak that it exhibits overall. The Rate L load is much flatter, though it also exhibits a winter peak. Of course, the winter peak in Rate L postpatrimonial load is not consistent with the overall Rate L load, which is much flatter.4 27 28 29 30 31 Nevertheless, the overall post-patrimonial load shape is beginning to look more like HQD’s overall load. This is an interesting result in that (a) the overall postpatrimonial load remains quite thin relative to the patrimonial load, and (b) the patrimonial load shape was originally designed to be more oriented toward peak hours than HQD’s actual load shape. 32 33 34 It is my understanding that the shift in the patrimonial load shape is due to a number of factors, including reductions in high load factor usage (including both lost industrial load and successful PGEE programs such as reducing the use of inefficient FOR ITS STRANDED TCE AND RESALE COSTS, PLEASE PROVIDE A LITTLE B A C K G R O U N D O N L O A D PAT T E R N S , H O U R LY C O S T S A N D P R I C E S A S S O C I AT E D W I T H H Q D ’ S P O S T- PAT R I M O N I A L L O A D . 3 The actual costs associated with the TCE facility are confidential. As such, I cannot evaluate the exact impact of these stranded costs on the hourly method costs. 4 As I have testified in the past, this counter-intuitive load shape for the large industrial rate class results from the arbitrary allocation method used by HQD to assign the patrimonial load among the rate classes. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 5 1 2 refrigerators) and increases in winter use of electricity by weather-sensitive customers as a result of increases in fossil fuel costs. 3 4 5 6 7 Figure IEc-2 compares the total post-patrimonial consumption with the resale volumes. As shown, the resale volumes are much higher in the summer, due again to the pronounced winter peak in the post-patrimonial load. In essence, HQD is incurring more surpluses in the summer due to both reductions in overall load and increases in winter peak load. 8 9 10 11 12 Figure IEc-3 compares the hourly unit cost of post-patrimonial supplies with the hourly resale unit revenues, for each hour over the year. It is important to recognize that the per-kWh cost reported in this figure is the “hourly method” cost developed by HQD before the resale impacts are considered. However, it includes the effect of the TCE stranded costs. A number of observations apply to this figure: 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 • The resale prices are consistent with generation economics and modern electricity energy markets, in that they are higher on-peak than off-peak, and they are higher in the peak winter and summer seasons (the US export markets have pronounced summer peaks) than in the off-peak seasons. Differentials between on-peak and off-peak prices are about $25 to $30 per MWh. Note that these prices are energy only. Because HQD cannot resell on a firm basis, these prices reflect only hourly energy differentials, and do not reflect capacityrelated values. 21 22 23 24 25 • The hourly method costs show very little on-peak/off-peak differentiation, unlike real electricity markets. The very high hourly costs in the summer almost certainly result from spreading the fixed, stranded TCE costs over a relatively small load in the summer. Thus, the hourly method continues to produce costs that are divorced from reality. 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 • The hourly costs are considerably higher than the resale prices. From an accounting perspective, this suggests that HQD is losing money on each sale, which might imply that HQD should not engage in these sales. However, from an economic perspective, as long as the resale values are higher than the incremental cost of the supply, HQD should continue to resell the power. It is therefore important to recognize that the hourly method costs are not consistent with economic reality. 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 P L E A S E A D D R E S S H O W H Q D ’ S C O S T A L L O C AT I O N M E T H O D F O R B O T H T Y P E S O F S T R A N D E D C O S T S C A U S E S T H E U N U S U A L R E S U LT S S H O W N I N TA B L E I E C - 4 ABOVE. In respect of the TCE stranded costs, it is my understanding that HQD simply takes the fixed costs that it continues to pay to TCE and it spreads those costs over every hour of the year, with no time-of-use variation and no demand component. Because post-patrimonial loads are lower in the summer than in the winter, the per-kWh delivered cost of the TCE stranded costs is higher in the summer than the winter, leading to the cost pattern shown in Figure IEc-3. Because the high load factor Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 6 1 2 customers are disproportionately responsible for summer loads, the high load factor customers are assigned a disproportionate share of the stranded costs. 3 4 5 6 7 8 In respect of the resale volumes, HQD assigns responsibility for the resold volumes in every hour to the actual post-patrimonial consumption in every hour. In essence, the more a class consumes in a particular hour, the more it is deemed to be responsible for the resold power in that hour. Once HQD determines the volumetric responsibility for the resold volumes, it then applies the hourly method unit cost and the resale revenue to each class’s share in each hour. 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 This approach disproportionately assigns costs to the higher load factor rate classes for two reasons. First, because the higher load factor customers represent a larger share of the summer load, they are assigned a larger share of the resale load. For example, as shown in Exhibit IEc-2, the large industrial class is responsible for 39 percent of the post-patrimonial load but it gets assigned 47 percent of the resold volumes. Second, because the per-kWh losses on resold power are higher in the summer than in the winter (the TCE stranded cost effect), the high load factor classes are assigned a disproportionate share. 17 18 19 20 21 22 I S H Q D ’ S M E T H O D F O R T R E AT I N G T H E S E S T R A N D E D C O S T S C O N S I S T E N T W I T H No. HQD’s treatment of both types of stranded costs relies on the assumption that resale volumes are somehow proportional to post-patrimonial consumption. In effect, HQD is saying that, if a class’s post-patrimonial load increases, it should be assigned more of the resold volumes. 23 24 25 26 27 28 This approach makes little sense. Resales of power are necessary because there is not enough consumption to fill up the contracts, not because there is too much consumption. To the extent that there is any causative relationship between postpatrimonial consumption and resale volumes, HQD’s method has it exactly backwards. When demand from a particular class in a particular hour increases, the need to resell power in that hour goes down. 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 In addition, it may be that the need to resell power is not related to any unexpected shortfall in consumption at all. For example, it is not clear that HQD’s planning did not actually anticipate the need to resell power, particularly in the summer months when local demand is low and export prices are more attractive. To the extent that HQD ever made a planning decision based on the expectation that it would resell power, there is surely no reason to charge the net accounting loss on those exports to summer loads. 36 37 Under those conditions, there is no conceivable cost causation basis for such a cost assignment. 38 39 40 41 C A N I T B E C R E D I B LY A R G U E D T H AT L O S S E S I N H I G H L O A D FA C TO R I N D U S T R I A L C O S T C A U S AT I O N ? L O A D S A R E C A U S I N G H Q D TO I N C U R R E S A L E L O S S E S , A N D T H E R E F O R E H Q D S H O U L D A S S I G N T H E C O S T S F O R T H E S U M M E R L O S S E S TO L A R G E I N D U S T R I A L C U S TO M E R S ? Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 7 1 No. Such an argument fundamentally misunderstands the economics of resold power. 2 3 4 5 If viewed from the narrow perspective of looking only at accounting costs and only for resold volumes, the argument may appear at first blush to have some merit. Relative to a base case situation, across-the-board reductions in industrial load will result in the need to resell more power in the summer. 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 However, lost industrial load is not the only change that will cause these results. For example, an across-the-board reduction in any baseload use (e.g., due to replacement of inefficient refrigerators and installation of compact fluorescent lighting) will also cause this kind of result. Similarly, increases in peak season load (e.g., increases in electric heat due to high fossil fuel prices) will cause this effect. Based on my conversations with AQCIE/CIFQ analyst M. Trahan, I understand that all of these effects are occurring.6 13 14 15 16 17 In addition, the argument fails on cost causation. If losses on resale were actually caused by customers leaving the system, then it would be appropriate to charge the customers who have left the system for those costs. It makes little sense to assign the costs for customer shutdowns to only one class of customer. The remaining customers in that class are not the ones who are responsible for the shutdown. 18 19 20 However, most importantly, this argument is specious on economic grounds, because it assumes that lost industrial load is actually a net cost to the system. This assumption is incorrect. 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 Average large industrial revenues are about 4.6 cents per kWh, and the high load factor customers within the class (particularly those taking service at high voltage) pay a lower rate than that. When one of those customers shuts down, the worst case for HQD is that it loses 4.6 cents per kWh in revenues and it is able to resell that power for an average of 6.3 cents per kWh (ranging anywhere from 5 to 9 cents per kWh, as shown in Figure IEc-3). Thus, in total, HQD will earn more revenues than it loses if a large industrial customer closes, and that benefit will necessarily be passed back to ratepayers in all classes. 29 30 31 The problem with the “blame-the-large-industrials” argument is that it focuses only on the accounting cost of the resale volumes, and it ignores the overall economic (and accounting) impact on HQD as a whole. 32 33 34 35 To understand this, consider what happens to overall cost allocation when large industrial load declines. Because the government of Québec in its annual decrees has adopted a proportional allocation for patrimonial load, when large industrial load declines, the other rate classes’ share of patrimonial load increases. This, of course, 5 I developed a simple two-period, two-class model to demonstrate that this and the rest of the analyses presented in this section of my evidence are correct, even recognizing the proportional allocation of patrimonial load. Electronic copies of this simple model are available upon request to AQCIE/CIFQ counsel. 6 See also HQD-16, Document 8, page 7, and HQD-14, Document 1, page 21. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 8 1 2 3 benefits those rate classes. However, if the focus of attention is only on the accounting losses of resale, the beneficial effects of the reallocation of patrimonial load will be ignored. 4 5 6 7 8 Thus, it would be extremely disingenuous, for example, for an analyst to argue that residential customers should get the benefits associated with lost industrial load in the form of a greater entitlement to low-cost patrimonial load, while forcing the remaining large industrial customers to bear the accounting losses associated with resold power supplies. O V E R A L L , W H AT A R E Y O U R C O N C L U S I O N S A N D R E C O M M E N D AT I O N S I N T H I S 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 As I have in the past, I conclude that the hourly method is not consistent with generation economics, cost causation, or electricity markets. Because it is not an issue in this proceeding, I make no recommendation regarding the allocation of nonstranded costs. Nevertheless, in light of the increasing winter peak demands of the post-patrimonial load, I encourage the Régie to monitor whether incorporating a demand component into post-patrimonial cost allocation may merit future attention. 17 18 19 20 In this proceeding, HQD’s stranded costs include all of the fixed costs paid to TCE for the Bécancour facility that supplies no power, as well as the accounting losses on resold power. I conclude that both of these stranded costs should be excluded from the hourly method and allocated separately. 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 In my view, the most equitable way to allocate these costs is in proportion to total generation costs. As I mentioned, the stranded costs are generated as a result of consumed volumes being lower than purchased volumes. Reductions in volumes for a particular class create benefits for other classes in the form of higher patrimonial loads. Because the classes whose loads have not decreased benefit from the lost volumes in the form of more patrimonial load, it would seem fair to assign those costs proportionately. 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 W H AT I S T H E I M PA C T O F Y O U R P R O P O S A L O N O V E R A L L A L L O C AT E D Because the TCE stranded costs are confidential, I cannot evaluate the overall impact. However, for illustrative purposes, I prepared an example based on the assumption that the TCE stranded costs for 2009 are $120 million. (The buyout costs for TCE were reported as $73 million at Docket No. R-3673-2008, and the regular TCE demand charges must be added to that.) I also assumed that HQD’s hourly method assigns the TCE stranded costs equally over the 8760 hours of 2009. 36 37 38 Based on those assumptions, Table IEc-5 below compares the total unit generation costs based on HQD’s filing and my proposed modification to stranded cost allocation. P R O C E E D I N G R E G A R D I N G P O S T- PAT R I M O N I A L G E N E R AT I O N C O S T A L L O C AT I O N ? G E N E R AT I O N C O S T S ? Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 9 TABLE IEC-5 ALLOCATED 2009 TEST YEAR GENERATION COSTS HQD FILED VERSUS ALTERNATIVE STRANDED COST EXAMPLE CENTS PER KWH OF ENERGY DELIVERED HQD Filed Alternative Example Percent Residential 3.34 3.36 0.7% Small General 3.08 3.07 -0.3% Medium General 2.88 2.87 -0.4% Large Industrial 2.67 2.65 -0.5% Total HQD 2.97 2.97 0.0% Source: Exhibit IEc-4, IEc Workpapers 2. ALLOC 2 .AT R I OEN V EONFU E ATLRLAONCSAT M I SOSNI OANN D CCORSO TSSS U B S I D I Z AT I O N 1 2 3 4 5 6 P L E A S E P R O V I D E A B R I E F B A C K G R O U N D O F T H E R E G U L ATO RY I S S U E S S U R R O U N D I N G R E V E N U E A L L O C AT I O N F O R T H I S P R O C E E D I N G . As the parties to these proceedings are well-aware, the regulation of HQD is subject to the unusual (and quite possibly unique) requirement that rates may not be adjusted in order to cause changes in historical levels of cross-subsidization. How that crosssubsidization is measured was a matter of some debate over several rate proceedings. 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 Nevertheless, in the 2006 HQD proceeding (R-3610-2006), the Régie approved a methodology proposed by HQD which measures the increase in allocated per-kWh cost from proceeding to proceeding, based on a consistent cost allocation methodology. That is, HQD simulates its cost allocation methodology for the prior test year and for the proposed test year with the same cost allocation methodology. The difference in the per-kWh allocated costs between those two simulations is deemed, under this methodology, to be the necessary difference in rates that would result in no change in cross-subsidies. 15 16 Thus, in Docket R-3610-2006, the Régie implicitly adopted a new base level of crosssubsidies. 17 18 19 However, in neither of the last two proceedings has the Régie applied its cross-subsidy approach for revenue allocation.7 Instead, it approved across-the-board rate increases for all rate classes in both cases. 20 21 22 In the current proceeding, HQD has again prepared its cross-subsidization analysis, which implies differential rate increases are necessary to prevent cross-subsidies from expanding. However, HQD has again proposed to apply an across-the-board rate 7 I use the term “revenue allocation” to apply to how much of the overall increase in HQD’s revenue requirement is applied to each rate class. I use the term “rate design” to apply to how rates are structured to recover the revenue requirement assigned to each class in the revenue allocation process. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 10 1 2 increase of 2.2 percent. At the direction of the Régie, however, HQD has offered several alternative approaches for differential rate increases. 3 4 5 6 7 8 W H AT A R E T H E P R I M A RY C O N S I D E R AT I O N S O F R E G U L ATO R S F O R E VA L U AT I N G R E V E N U E A L L O C AT I O N D E C I S I O N S ? As a general rule, regulators consider three primary factors when determining how a rate increase is shared among the various rate classes. First, most regulators consider cost to be the primary consideration, and that the objective of revenue allocation is to move rates more into line with allocated costs under future rates than under prior rates. 9 10 11 This objective of “moving toward cost-based rates” is tempered by two other considerations. These are the principle of “rate gradualism” (often referred to as avoiding “rate shock”) and the principle of “value of service.” 12 13 14 15 16 17 While it is difficult to pin down exactly what the principle of gradualism requires, many regulators rely on a “rule of thumb” that the rate increase for a particular class be no more than 1.5 or 2.0 times the system average increase. (Generally, for smaller overall increases, regulators are more comfortable with a higher multiple.) Thus, for example, under a “two-times” rule, if the system average rate increase is 2.2 percent, no class is assigned more than a 4.4 percent increase. 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 The principle of “value of service” is that classes who place a higher value on the utility service may be assigned a larger increase than those classes that value the service less highly. This criterion is generally interpreted to mean that customers whose demand will be less affected by a rate increase (i.e., the demand is less price elastic) may be assigned a larger increase. In practice, this criterion is often used to justify lower rate increases for customers or customer classes who are likely to lose load (e.g., bypass rates). 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 W H AT A LT E R N AT I V E A P P R O A C H E S H A S H Q D O F F E R E D F O R R E V E N U E The cross-subsidy analysis indicates that, to maintain constant cross-subsidies, it would be necessary to apply a rate increase of above average increases of 3.6 percent and 2.6 percent to the residential and small general service classes respectively, and below average increases of 0.2 percent and 0.7 percent to the medium general and large industrial rate classes. 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 However, HQD is unwilling to suggest differentiated rate increases of that magnitude. It offers several alternatives based on considerations that are consistent with the “rules of thumb” that I discuss above. However, HQD is willing only to suggest maximum rate increases that are 1.2 times, 1.3 times and 1.4 times the system average. Such constraints are somewhat cautious compared to my experience in other jurisdictions, although they presumably reflect both historical rate increase patterns and political considerations in Québec. 39 40 D O Y O U H AV E S P E C I F I C R E C O M M E N D AT I O N S R E G A R D I N G R E V E N U E A L L O C AT I O N A L L O C AT I O N I N T H I S P R O C E E D I N G ? IN THIS PROCEEDING? Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 11 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 While I encourage the Régie to differentiate rate increases among the various rate classes to restrict or eliminate the growth in cross-subsidies, I do not have a specific proposal in this proceeding. The choice of how much to temper the results of the cost allocation analysis with the principle of “gradualism” is essentially one of judgement. However, I do offer factors for the Régie to consider, and I evaluate whether the Régie’s arguments in Decision 2008-024 justify an across-the-board rate increase in this proceeding. 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 First, if HQD’s across-the-board increase is granted in this proceeding, the total accumulated changes in cross-subsidies would be quite significant. in Exhibit IEc-5, I have compiled the annual increases in cross-subsidies for each major rate class group since the Régie’s adoption of a cross-subsidization metric in R-3610-2006. Under HQD’s proposal, subsidies to the residential class will have increased by over $300 million (some 7.1 percent of current revenues), while the subsidies from the large industrial class have increased by over $150 million (some 8.5 percent of current revenues). 16 17 18 19 20 Second, all of HQD’s business classes already provide quite substantial crosssubsidies to the residential class, particularly the medium commercial rate class in which cross-subsidies amount to more than 30 percent of allocated costs. Allowing these subsidies to continue to increase would be considered inequitable in most jurisdictions in my experience. 21 22 23 24 In addition, allowing the cross-subsidies to increase is creating rate design problems. The higher cross-subsidy level for the Rate M customers is creating uneconomic incentives for some customers to want to switch to Rate L, simply to get access to a rate class that is subject to a lower cross-subsidy level. 25 26 27 28 29 P L E A S E R E V I E W T H E R É G I E ’ S R AT I O N A L E I N D - 2 0 0 8 - 0 2 4 R E G A R D I N G In that decision, the Régie identified a number of reasons for adopting an across-theboard increase in that proceeding. With respect, I do not agree that these reasons support an across-the-board increase in this proceeding. 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 1) In R-3644-2007, there were unresolved issues regarding transmission and PGEÉ cost allocation that reduced the reliability of the cost analysis. While cost allocation issues may contribute some small uncertainty to HQD’s estimates of impacts, it is important to recognize that HQD’s calculation of before and after cross-subsidies are made using the same cost allocation methodology. Thus, changing a methodology in a particular proceeding does not have a significant effect on the cross-subsidy calculation. Moreover, I believe that the transmission and PGEÉ cost allocation procedures have been resolved, and are therefore not an issue in this proceeding. 39 40 41 42 2. Large industrial load reductions will have an impact on the overall costs to consumers, and the allocation of stranded costs may cause inequities. As I explained earlier, reductions in large industrial load tend to benefit the other customer classes. To the extent that there are any inequities in HQD’s allocation D I F F E R E N T I AT E D R AT E I N C R E A S E S . Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 12 3 . TA R I F F D E S I G N F O R R AT E L 1 2 3 of stranded costs, it is in favor of the residential class and at the expense of the business classes. For that reason, considerations of equity should doubly favor the differentiated rate increases implied by HQD’s cross-subsidy analysis. 4 5 6 7 8 3. The treatment of the deferred transmission expense militates against a differentiated increase. As shown in HQD-16, Document 9, Table 16.1, all of the Régie’s changes in last year’s proceeding had only a small net effect on allocated costs. Moreover, it is my understanding that deferred transmission expense is not a significant factor in this proceeding. 9 10 Therefore, I do not believe that the reasons presented by the Régie in its last decision are applicable to this proceeding. 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 W H AT A R E T H E I M P O RTA N T F E AT U R E S O F T H E R AT E L TA R I F F D E S I G N F O R T H I S PROCEEDING?8 The Rate L tariff consists of demand and energy charges. In considering tariff design for large industrial customers, it is reasonable for the regulator to consider both embedded cost effects and marginal cost effects. As the Régie correctly recognized in Decision D-2008-024, because the vast majority of generation costs assigned to the Rate L class (or all rate classes for that matter) are related to the below-market patrimonial pool, it will be extremely difficult to set rates for Rate L at or near marginal costs. W H AT A R E T H E I M P L I C AT I O N S O F A N E M B E D D E D C O S T A L L O C AT I O N S T U D Y F O R 20 21 22 23 24 25 As a general rule, demand charges are designed to recover costs that are classified as demand-related, and energy charges are designed to recover costs that are classified as energy-related.9 It is important to recognize that, if rates are not designed in this way, the tariff design will result in intra-class cross-subsidization. 26 27 28 29 For example, suppose HQD decided to eliminate the Rate L demand charge entirely, and collect all revenue from an energy charge. Because HQD’s cost allocation methodology classifies costs into demand components and energy components, the cost of service per kWh is different from customer to customer. Under HQD’s D E S I G N I N G R AT E S F O R L A R G E I N D U S T R I A L C U S TO M E R S ? 8 Much of this section of my testimony presents the same material that I presented in last year’s proceeding on this subject. It is included again because much of the focus of last year’s proceeding was in respect of the “stepped rate” concept for Rate L tariff design, and the issues I raised may not have been fully explored. I have updated the figures for the 2009 filing, and retained much of the text. However, I have added a discussion relating to the implications of the shifts in post-patrimonial load patterns for peak demand and off-peak price signals. 9 Some utilities will set demand charges modestly below allocated demand costs, in recognition that the individual customer peak demands do not always match up with the coincident peak measures used in the cost allocation study. The need for this adjustment is less appropriate for HQD, because it already uses a broad peak for allocating the demand-related portion of generation costs in the load factor method. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 13 1 2 3 4 methodology (as filed in this proceeding), a customer with a 100 percent load factor would cost approximate 3.7 cents per kWh to serve, while a customer with a 60 percent load factor would cost about 4.5 cents per kWh to serve, a 21 percent difference. 5 6 7 8 If rates for both types of customer were set at the same average per-kWh rate, the high load factor customer would cross-subsidize the low load factor customer. While this is obviously an extreme example, a similar but less extreme pattern would result if HQD simply over-recovered the energy-related costs in its energy charge. 9 10 11 12 However, over the last several rate proceedings, HQD has been following a pattern of assigning disproportionate increases to the Rate L energy charges and lower increases to the demand charges. This policy will necessarily result in larger rate increases for high load factor rate customers than for lower load factor customers. 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 I S H Q D ’ S R AT E D E S I G N P R O P O S A L I N T H I S P R O C E E D I N G C O N S I S T E N T W I T H I T S No, it is not. Exhibit IEc-6 shows the energy component of costs allocated to the Rate L class in HQD’s cost allocation studies from 2007 through 2009. In that table, I use generous assumptions about the energy component of costs, including the assumptions that all post-patrimonial energy and all PGEÉ costs are energy-related. In actuality, both of those cost items should have a demand-related component. 20 21 22 23 24 As shown in Exhibit IEc-6, the upper bound for energy-related costs for Rate L, even including a substantial provision for cross-subsidization, is 2.95 cents per kWh. The cost basis is therefore about 1.3 percent above the current Rate L energy charge of 2.99 cents per kWh, and about 2.1 percent below HQD’s 3.01 cents per kWh proposed energy charge in this proceeding. 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 I recognize that it is HQD’s view that, for Rate L rate design purposes, all generation costs are energy-related and all transmission and distribution costs are demand-related. Regarding most transmission and distribution costs, as a theoretical matter, I tend to agree with HQD’s all-demand approach. However, the Régie most clearly does not, in that it has directed that a substantial percentage of transmission costs be classified as energy-related. Thus, in HQD’s cost allocation methodology, if a rate class experiences an increase in energy consumption but no increase in peak demand, its allocated transmission costs will increase. Therefore, it is appropriate for rates to reflect that methodology. 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 For similar reasons, I respectfully (and quite strongly) disagree with HQD that all generation costs are energy-related. The patrimonial generation cost allocation scheme put forward by HQD and mandated by government decree allocates patrimonial generation costs using both energy and demand allocators, with a system load factor weighting. Thus, if a Rate L customer can reduce its peak demand with no reduction in energy consumption (i.e., leveling its load), the patrimonial costs allocated to Rate L will go down. Again, this cost allocation method should be reflected in the rate design. E M B E D D E D C O S T A N A LY S I S ? Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 14 1 2 3 4 W H AT O F M A R G I N A L C O S T C O N S I D E R AT I O N S I N TA R I F F L R AT E D E S I G N ? 5 6 7 8 First, it relies on the premise that the only price signal that industrial customers consider is the short-term energy price signal. While this may be true for short-term decisions, it is not correct for most serious decisions regarding longer-term investment and operational planning decisions. It is my understanding that HQD believes that its approach will encourage conservation, by increasing the energy charge to get it closer to the marginal energy supply costs. However, this argument relies on two dubious premises. 9 10 11 12 At large industrial operations, energy efficiency programs generally target loads during all hours of the year, including both peak and off-peak consumption levels. Shifting costs from demand charges to energy charges will likely not create any meaningful additional incentives to conserve. 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 What reducing the relative demand charges will do, however, is reduce the incentive for large industrial customers from maintaining a level load. That is, customers will have less incentive to use energy efficiently. Under HQD’s tariff, the energy charge is the same regardless of whether it is a peak period or an off-peak period, or whether it applies to a customer with a very high load factor or to a customer with a more temperature sensitive peak demand. The demand charge, by contrast, applies only to the customer’s peak demand. Thus, by proposing disproportionate increases to the energy charge, HQD encourages less efficient behavior by Rate L customers. 21 22 23 24 25 Second, the conservation premise relies on the assumption the relevant marginal cost signal is energy-related. However, the shifting load pattern for post-patrimonial load suggests that the need to meet winter peak demands is becoming an increasingly important supply consideration. Thus, marginal supply costs will increasingly need to recognize the need for capacity as well as energy. 26 27 28 29 W H AT I S Y O U R R E C O M M E N D AT I O N I N T H I S P R O C E E D I N G ? Based on the foregoing, I recommend that the energy charge for Rate L be set at 2.95 cents per kWh if HQD’s across-the-board rate increase is approved, with the balance of the rate increase applied to demand charges. 30 31 32 33 34 35 To the extent that the Régie modifies the rate increase proposed for Rate L, I suggest that the energy cost increase be adjusted proportionally. For example, an increase to 2.95 cents per kWh is a 1.3 percent increase, compared to HQD’s overall proposed Rate L increase of 2.2 percent. If the Régie approves an overall increase for Rate L of 0.7 percent, the energy charge increase should be scaled back by 0.7%/2.2% * 1.3% = 0.4%, thereby resulting in an energy charge of 2.92 cents per kWh. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 15 CONCLUSIONS AND 1 Based on my analysis completed to date, my recommendations are as follows: R E C O M M E N D AT I O N S 2 3 • Correct the HQD hourly cost allocation methodology for a mis-allocation of stranded costs. 4 5 6 • Assign different rate increases to the various classes to reduce the increases in cross-subsidies, consistent with the Régie’s interpretation of the principles of gradualism and equity. 7 8 • Set the energy charge for Rate L at 2.95 cents per kWh, with proportional adjustments for any change in the overall Rate L class increase. Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 16 EXHIBIT IEc-1 CURRICULUM VITAE AND EXPERT TESTIMONY SCHEDULE OF ROBERT D. KNECHT Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 ROBERT D. KNECHT Robert D. Knecht specializes in the practical application of economics, finance and management theory to issues facing public and private sector clients. Mr. Knecht has more than twenty years of consulting experience, focusing primarily on the energy, metals, and mining industries. He has consulted to industry, law firms, and government clients, both in the U.S. and internationally. He has participated in strategic and business planning studies, project evaluations, litigation and regulatory proceedings and policy analyses. His practice currently focuses primarily on utility regulation, and he has provided analysis and expert testimony in numerous U.S. and Canadian jurisdictions. In addition, as Treasurer of IEc since 1995, Mr. Knecht is responsible for the firm's accounting, finance and tax planning, as well as administration of the firm's retirement plans. Mr. Knecht's consulting assignments include the following projects: C For the Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate, Mr. Knecht provides analysis and expert testimony in industry restructuring, base rates and purchased energy cost proceedings involving electric, steam and natural gas distribution utilities. Mr. Knecht has analyzed the economics and financial issues of electric industry restructuring, stranded cost determination, fair rate of return, claimed utility expenses, cost allocation methods and rate design issues. C For independent power producers and industrial customers in Alberta, Mr. Knecht has provided analysis and expert testimony in a variety of electric industry proceedings, including industry restructuring, cost unbundling, stranded cost recovery, transmission rate design, cost allocation and rate design. C For industrial customers in Québec, Mr. Knecht has prepared economic analysis and expert testimony in regulatory proceedings regarding cost allocation, compliance with legislative requirements for crosssubsidization, and rate design. C As part of international teams of experts, Mr. Knecht has prepared the economic and financial analysis for industry restructuring studies involving the steel and iron ore industries in Venezuela, Poland, and Nigeria. C For the U.S. Department of Justice and for several private sector clients, Mr. Knecht has prepared analyses of economic damages in a variety of litigation matters, including ERISA discrimination, breach of contract, fraudulent conveyance, natural resource damages and anti-trust cases. C Mr. Knecht participates in numerous projects with colleagues at IEc preparing economic and environmental analyses associated with energy and utility industries for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Mr. Knecht holds a M.S. in Management from the Sloan School of Management at M.I.T., with concentrations in applied economics and finance. He also holds a B.S. in Economics from M.I.T. Prior to joining Industrial Economics as a principal in 1989, Mr. Knecht worked for seven years as an economic and management consultant at Marshall Bartlett, Incorporated. He also worked for two years as an economist in the Energy Group of Data Resources, Incorporated. Industrial Economics, Incorporated 2067 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02140 USA 617.354.0074 | 617.354.0463 fax August, 2006 www.indecon.com ROBERT D. KNECHT EXPERT TESTIMONY SUBMITTED IN REGULATORY PROCEEDINGS: 2004 TO 2008 DOCKET # REGULATOR UTILITY DATE CLIENT TOPICS P-20082044561 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Pike County Light & Power October 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Electric default service procurement R-3673-2008 Régie de l’Énergie, Québec Hydro Québec Distribution August 2008 AQCIE/CIFQ Electric supply contract modifications. 1550487 Alberta Utilities Commission ENMAX Power Corporation July 2008 D410 Group Formula-based (performance-based) ratemaking; ratepayer-supplied equity contributions. R-20082039417 et al. Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission UGI Utilities (Gas Division) July 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Design day demand forecast. R-20082039284 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission UGI Penn Natural Gas July 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Revenue sharing, gas supply costs. R-20082039634 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Gas Utilities July 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Lost and unaccounted-for gas, gas supply costs. A-20082034045 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission UGI Utilities, PPL Gas Utilities June 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Public benefits of proposed sale. R-20082011621 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Columbia Gas of Pennsylvania May 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Cost allocation, revenue allocation, rate design. R-20082028039 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Columbia Gas of Pennsylvania May 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas supply cost functionalization; cost reconciliation method, sharing mechanisms. R-3648-2007 Régie de l’Énergie, Québec Hydro Québec Distribution April 2008 AQCIE/CIFQ Electric supply contract modifications. R-20082021348 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Philadelphia Gas Works April 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Sharing mechanisms, gas supply contracts. R-20082012502 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission National Fuel Gas Distribution Company March 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Transportation and sales customer rate design, design day forecasts. 1 ROBERT D. KNECHT EXPERT TESTIMONY SUBMITTED IN REGULATORY PROCEEDINGS: 2004 TO 2008 DOCKET # REGULATOR UTILITY R-20082013026 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission T.W. Phillips Gas and Oil Company P-00072342 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission 2007-004 DATE CLIENT TOPICS March 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Rate design treatment of capacity release revenues. West Penn Power d/b/a Allegheny Power February 2008 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Default service electricity procurement, rate design, reconciliation. New Brunswick Board of Commissioners of Public Utilities New Brunswick Power Distribution and Customer Service Corporation November 2007 New Brunswick Public Intervenor Cost allocation, revenue allocation, rate design. R-3644-2007 Régie de l'Énergie, Québec Hydro Québec Distribution October 2007 AQCIE/CIFQ Cost allocation, revenue allocation, rate design. P-00072305 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Pennsylvania Power Corporation July 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Default electric service procurement. R-00072334 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission UGI Penn Natural Gas, Inc. July 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Asset management arrangement, gas procurement. R-00072333 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Gas Utilities Corporation July 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Design day forecasting, gas procurement. R-00072155 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Electric Utilities Corporation July 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Cost allocation, revenue allocation, rate design, energy efficiency. R-00049255 (Remand) Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Electric Utilities Corporation May 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Revenue allocation. R-00072175 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Columbia Gas of Pennsylvania, Inc. May 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement. R-00072110 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Philadelphia Gas Works April 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement, margin sharing mechanisms. R-00061931 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Philadelphia Gas Works April 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Cost allocation, revenue allocation, retail gas competition. P-00072245 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Pike County Light & Power Company March 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Default service procurement, rate design. 2 ROBERT D. KNECHT EXPERT TESTIMONY SUBMITTED IN REGULATORY PROCEEDINGS: 2004 TO 2008 DOCKET # REGULATOR UTILITY R-00072043 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission National Fuel Gas Distribution Company C-20065942 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission R-3610-2006 DATE CLIENT TOPICS March 2007 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Design day requirements. Pike County Light & Power Company November 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Wholesale power procurement by provider of last resort. Régie de l'Énergie, Québec Hydro Québec Distribution November 2006 AQCIE/CIFQ Post-patrimonial generation cost allocation; cross-subsidization; rate design. P-00052188 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Pennsylvania Power Company September 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Affidavit: POLR rates, wholesale to retail. R-00061493 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission National Fuel Gas Distribution Corporation September 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Rate of return, load forecasting, cost allocation, revenue allocation, rate design, revenue decoupling. R-00061398 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Gas Utilities Corporation August 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Cost allocation, revenue allocation, rate design. R-00061365 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PG Energy/Southern Union Company July 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Merger savings, cost allocation, revenue allocation, rate design. R-00061519 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Gas Utilities Corporation July 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Design day weather and throughput forecasts; gas supply hedging. R-00061518 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PG Energy/Southern Union Company July 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Design day weather and throughput forecasts; gas supply hedging. A-125146 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission UGI Utilities, Inc., Southern Union Company June 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Public benefits of proposed sale of PG Energy to UGI; asset management agreement. R-00061355 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Columbia Gas of Pennsylvania May 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas supply and hedging plan; procedural issues R-00061296 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Philadelphia Gas Works April 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement and procedural issues. R-00061246 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission National Fuel Gas Distribution March 2006 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement; unaccounted for gas retention rates. 2005-002 Refiling New Brunswick Board of Commissioners of Public Utilities New Brunswick Power Distribution and Customer Service Company New Brunswick Public Intervenor Cost allocation, rate design. February 2006 3 ROBERT D. KNECHT EXPERT TESTIMONY SUBMITTED IN REGULATORY PROCEEDINGS: 2004 TO 2008 DOCKET # REGULATOR UTILITY P-00052188 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Pennsylvania Power Company R-3579-2005 Régie de l'Énergie, Québec 2005-002 DATE CLIENT TOPICS December 2005 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Cost allocation and rate design for POLR supplies. Hydro Québec Distribution November 2005 AQCIE/CIFQ Generation cost allocation; crosssubsidization; revenue allocation. New Brunswick Board of Commissioners of Public Utilities New Brunswick Power Distribution and Customer Service Company August 2005 New Brunswick Public Intervenor Cost allocation, rate design. R-00050538 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PG Energy July 2005 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement diversification. R-00050540 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Gas Utilities Corporation July 2005 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement, hedging, retention rates, sharing mechanism. R-00050340 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Columbia Gas of Pennsylvania May 2005 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement, hedging and diversification. R-3563-2005 Régie de l'Énergie, Québec Hydro Québec Distribution April 2005 AQCIE/CIFQ Generation cost allocation; industrial demand response. R-00050264 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Philadelphia Gas Works April 2005 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas procurement, risk hedging, financing costs in the gas cost rate. R-00050216 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission National Fuel Gas Distribution March 2005 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Gas supply procurement and forward pricing policies. EB-2004-0542 Ontario Energy Board Union Gas Limited March 2005 Tribute Resources Inc. Cost allocation and rate design for service to embedded storage pools. R-00049884 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Pike County Light and Power (Gas Service) January 2005 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Fair rate of return, cost allocation, class revenue assignment. R-00049656 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission National Fuel Gas Distribution December 2004 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Fair rate of return, uncollectibles costs, automatic rate adjustments, cost allocation, rate design. R-3541-2004 Régie de l'Énergie, Québec Hydro Québec Distribution November 2004 AQCIE, CIFQ Allocation of post-patrimonial generation costs. C-20031302 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Columbia Gas of Pennsylvania July 2004 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Customer assistance program funding and cost allocation. R-049255 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission PPL Electric Utilities Corporation June 2004 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Transmission and distribution cost allocation, rate design, automatic distribution increases. 4 ROBERT D. KNECHT EXPERT TESTIMONY SUBMITTED IN REGULATORY PROCEEDINGS: 2004 TO 2008 DOCKET # REGULATOR UTILITY P-042090 et al. Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Philadelphia Gas Works RP-2003-0203 Ontario Energy Board R-049157 P-042090 DATE CLIENT TOPICS June 2004 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Collections and universal service cost issues. Enbridge Gas Distribution May 2004 Vulnerable Energy Consumers Coalition et al. Cost allocation, rate design for pipeline and storage costs. Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission Philadelphia Gas Works April 2004 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Cash receipts reconciliation clause. R-049108 Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission National Fuel Gas Distribution March 2004 Pennsylvania Office of Small Business Advocate Uncollectible cost responsibility for standby charges. Application 1306819 Alberta Energy and Utilities Board ENMAX Power Corporation January 2004 Calgary Industrial Group Calgary Building Owners T&D cost allocation, rate design, ratepayer equity funding. October 2008 Industrial Economics, Incorporated 2067 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02140 USA 617.354.0074 | 617.354.0463 fax www.indecon.com 5 EXHIBIT IEc-2 EFFECTS OF RESALE COSTS AND REVENUES ON 2009 POST-PATRIMONIAL ALLOCATED COSTS Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Workpapers of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Exhibit IEc-2 Impact of Power Resales on Post-Patrimonial Generation Cost Alloca Unit Cost (cts/kWh) Energy at Generator (GWh) Energy Share Cost ($mm) 9.17 9.83 9.76 9.73 9.54 1,731 426 775 1,908 4,839 35.8% 8.8% 16.0% 39.4% 100.0% 158.7 41.9 75.7 185.7 461.9 Costs of Surplus Supplies Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total 11.33 12.01 11.96 11.81 11.75 107 50 91 220 468 22.9% 10.6% 19.4% 47.0% 100.0% 12.2 6.0 10.9 26.0 55.0 Total Supply Cost Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total 9.29 10.06 9.99 9.95 9.74 1,838 476 866 2,128 5,307 34.6% 9.0% 16.3% 40.1% 100.0% 170.8 47.9 86.6 211.6 516.9 Resale Revenues Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total 6.93 6.91 6.91 6.58 6.29 22.9% 10.6% 19.4% 47.0% 100.0% (6.8) (3.2) (5.8) (13.7) (29.4) 35.8% 8.8% 16.0% 39.4% 100.0% 164.1 44.7 80.8 197.9 487.4 Costs Excluding Surplus Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total Post-Patrimonial Supply Cost Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total Net Effect of the Resale of Surplus Supplies Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total 9.48 10.49 10.42 10.37 10.07 Cost Markup (cts/kWh) 0.31 0.66 0.66 0.64 0.53 (107) (50) (91) (220) (468) 1,731 426 775 1,908 4,839 Percent Markup 3.4% 6.7% 6.7% 6.6% 5.5% Cost ($mm) 5.4 2.8 5.1 12.3 25.6 Source: HQD-16, Document 9, Table R-2.1 Exhibits 3677.xls; Exhibit IEc-2 10/27/2008 EXHIBIT IEc-3 POST-PATRIMONIAL AND RESALE LOAD, COST AND PRICE FIGURES Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 1Ja n 16 -J an 31 -J an 15 -F eb 2M ar 17 -M ar 1Ap r 16 -A pr 1M ay 16 -M ay 31 -M ay 15 -J un 30 -J un 15 -J ul 30 -J u 14 l -A ug 29 -A ug 13 -S ep 28 -S ep 13 -O ct 28 -O c 12 t -N ov 27 -N ov 12 -D ec 27 -D ec MWh/hour Figure IEc-1 HQD 2009 Post-Patrimonial Loads 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 - Residential Rate L Industrial 1Ja n 16 -J an 31 -J an 15 -F eb 2M a 17 r -M ar 1Ap r 16 -A pr 1M a 16 y -M a 31 y -M ay 15 -J un 30 -J un 15 -J ul 30 -J u 14 l -A ug 29 -A ug 13 -S ep 28 -S ep 13 -O ct 28 -O c 12 t -N ov 27 -N ov 12 -D ec 27 -D ec MWh/hour Figure IEc-2 HQD 2009 Post-Patrimonial Load and Resale Volumes 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 - (500) Post-Patrimonial Load Resale Volumes -A pr 1M a 16 y -M a 31 y -M ay 15 -J un 30 -J un 15 -J ul 30 -J u 14 l -A u 29 g -A u 13 g -S e 28 p -S ep 13 -O c 28 t -O c 12 t -N o 27 v -N o 12 v -D e 27 c -D ec 16 ar ar Ap r -M M 1- 17 eb an -F -J n an Ja -J 2- 15 31 16 1- $/MWh Figure IEc-3 HQD Post-Patrimonial Hourly Costs and Resale Revenues 150.00 130.00 110.00 90.00 70.00 50.00 30.00 "Hourly Method" Cost Resale Revenue EXHIBIT IEc-4 EXAMPLE OF ALTERNATIVE STRANDED COST ALLOCATION Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Workpapers of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Exhibit IEc-4 Example of Alternative Method for Stranded Cost Allocation HQD Method Patrimonial Consumption Volumes Costs Unit Costs Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total 58,643 14,430 26,423 66,885 166,381 Alternative Example Residential Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total Patrimonial Cost 1,850.6 412.9 702.5 1,637.5 4,603.5 1,850.6 412.9 702.5 1,637.5 4,603.5 3.16 2.86 2.66 2.45 2.77 Post-Patrimonial Consumption Volumes Costs Unit Costs 1,731 426 775 1,908 4,839 Post-Patrimonial Consumption Volumes Costs Unit Costs 1,730.6 127.6 7.38 425.7 32.0 7.51 775.1 58.0 7.48 1,907.9 142.0 7.44 4,839.2 359.6 7.43 164.1 44.7 80.8 197.9 487.4 Sub-Total Costs 1,978.2 444.9 760.5 1,779.5 4,963.1 9.48 10.49 10.42 10.37 10.07 Stranded Cost 51.0 11.5 19.6 45.8 127.8 Total Consumption Volumes Costs Unit Costs 60,374 14,856 27,198 68,793 171,220 2,014.7 457.6 783.3 1,835.4 5,090.9 Volumes 60,374 14,856 27,198 68,793 171,220 Total Costs 2,029.2 456.3 780.1 1,825.4 5,090.9 3.34 3.08 2.88 2.67 2.97 Unit Costs 3.36 3.07 2.87 2.65 2.97 Source: HQD-11, Document 3, Table 9A; IEc Workpapers. Exhibits 3677.xls; Exhibit IEc-4 10/27/2008 EXHIBIT IEc-5 ANALYSIS OF CUMULATIVE CHANGES IN CROSS-SUBSIDIES AMONG RATE CLASSES Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Workpapers of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 EXHIBIT IEc-5 ANALYSIS OF CUMULATIVE CHANGES IN CROSS-SUBSIDIES Increase with No Change in Cross-Subsidy Approved/ Increase in Proposed Cross-Subsidy Increase (Percent) Cumulative Base Increase in Increase with Revenues Cross-Subsidy No Change in ($mm) ($mm) Cross-Subsidy Cumulative Approved/ Proposed Increase Single Year Cumulative Increase in Subsidy 2007 Test Year Domestique Petite Puissance Moyenne Puissance Grande Puissance Total 2.83% 1.73% 1.03% 0.97% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% -0.91% 0.19% 0.89% 0.95% 0.00% 4,050 1,275 1,830 1,971 9,126 (36.7) 2.5 16.2 18.7 0.7 2.83% 1.73% 1.03% 0.97% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% 1.92% (36.67) 2.45 16.23 18.71 0.72 2008 Test Year Domestique Petite Puissance Moyenne Puissance Grande Puissance Total 4.31% 1.32% 2.75% 1.06% 2.90% 2.91% 2.94% 2.87% 2.90% 2.90% -1.40% 1.61% 0.12% 1.84% 0.00% 4,165 1,294 1,879 1,929 9,267 (58.5) 20.9 2.3 35.5 0.2 7.26% 3.07% 3.81% 2.04% 4.88% 4.88% 4.91% 4.85% 4.88% 4.88% (98.93) 23.80 19.44 54.72 (0.95) 2009 Test Year Proposed Domestique Petite Puissance Moyenne Puissance Grande Puissance Total 3.60% 2.57% 0.20% 0.69% 2.20% 2.20% 2.20% 2.20% 2.20% 2.20% -1.40% -0.37% 2.01% 1.50% 0.00% 4,317 1,362 1,905 1,820 9,404 (60.5) (5.0) 38.2 27.4 0.1 11.12% 5.72% 4.02% 2.75% 7.19% 7.19% 7.22% 7.16% 7.18% 7.19% (169.70) 20.47 59.81 80.68 (8.74) Cumulative Three-Year Cross-Subsidy (excluding interest) Domestique Petite Puissance Moyenne Puissance Grande Puissance Total Exhibits 3677.xls; Exhibit IEc-5 (305.30) 46.72 95.49 154.11 (8.98) 10/27/2008 Workpapers of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Exhibit IEc-5 (Continued) Supporting Workpapers for Historical Cross-Subsidy Calculations R-3677-2008 Filing Cost of Service Sales Volume 2008 2009 2008 2009 5,133.4 5,311.9 59,760 60,440 1,063.5 1,110.1 14,600 14,896 1,505.2 1,466.3 27,331 26,811 1,736.3 1,591.7 43,569 39,948 9,438.4 9,480.0 145,261 142,095 HQD-11, Doc 1 Table 2 Domestic Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total Sources: Revenues Before After $mm $mm 4,317 4,412 1,362 1,392 1,905 1,947 1,820 1,860 9,404 9,611 HQD-12, Doc. 3, page 3 % 2.20% 2.20% 2.20% 2.20% 2.20% Unit Revenue Req'mt 2008 2009 Change cts/kWh cts/kWh 8.59 8.79 0.20 7.28 7.45 0.17 5.51 5.47 (0.04) 3.99 3.98 (0.00) 6.50 6.67 0.17 HQD-16, Document 4, Table R-6A Cost Regul. Growth Provision $mm 2007-08 120.10 16.10 25.07 3.83 (10.27) 5.54 (0.28) 4.79 134.62 30.26 Unit Revenue Req'mt 2007 2008 Change cts/kWh cts/kWh 8.18 8.59 0.41 7.05 7.28 0.24 5.23 5.51 0.28 3.88 3.99 0.11 6.18 6.50 0.31 Filing Cost Regul. Growth Provision $mm 2006-07 244.39 (43.87) 34.78 (11.12) 75.84 (14.62) 46.67 (16.45) 401.68 (86.06) 19.31 6.09 8.52 8.14 42.06 Total $mm 155.51 34.99 3.79 12.65 206.94 (21.06) (6.54) (9.50) (9.75) (46.85) Total $mm 179.46 17.12 51.72 20.46 268.77 (18.04) (5.61) (8.14) (8.36) (40.15) Total $mm 181.78 11.86 48.98 26.16 268.77 6.43 2.03 2.91 3.13 14.50 Total $mm 114.43 22.03 18.91 19.13 175.50 Change in Cross Subsidies Subsidy Unit Revenues Before Proposed Cost-Based Percent Ch. $mm 7.14 7.30 7.40 3.60% 60.5 9.14 9.34 9.38 2.57% 5.0 7.11 7.26 7.12 0.20% (38.2) 4.56 4.66 4.59 0.69% (27.4) 6.62 6.76 6.76 2.20% (0.1) Calculations Decision 2008-024 (Compliance for R-3644-2007) Domestic Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total Sources: Cost of Service Sales Volume 2007 2008 2007 2008 4,845.8 5,133.4 59,232 59,760 1,030.1 1,063.5 14,620 14,600 1,418.8 1,505.2 27,129 27,331 1,767.1 1,736.3 45,567 43,569 9,061.8 9,438.4 146,548 145,261 Filing; HQD-11, Doc 1 Table 2, R-3677-2008 Before $mm 4,165 1,294 1,879 1,929 9,267 Filing Revenues After $mm 4,286 1,332 1,933 1,985 9,536 % 2.91% 2.94% 2.87% 2.90% 2.90% Before 6.97 8.86 6.87 4.43 6.38 Change in Cross Subsidies Unit Revenues Subsidy Proposed Cost-Based Percent Ch. $mm 7.17 7.27 4.31% 58.5 9.12 8.98 1.32% (20.9) 7.07 7.06 2.75% (2.3) 4.56 4.47 1.06% (35.5) 6.56 6.56 2.90% (0.2) Before 6.97 8.86 6.87 4.43 6.38 Change in Cross Subsidies Subsidy Unit Revenues Proposed Cost-Based Percent Ch. $mm 7.17 7.27 4.36% 60.8 9.12 8.94 0.92% (26.1) 7.07 7.05 2.61% (5.0) 4.56 4.49 1.36% (29.8) 6.56 6.56 2.90% (0.2) Before 6.84 8.72 6.75 4.33 6.23 Change in Cross Subsidies Subsidy Unit Revenues Proposed Cost-Based Percent Ch. $mm 6.97 7.03 2.83% 36.7 8.89 8.87 1.73% (2.5) 6.88 6.82 1.03% (16.2) 4.41 4.37 0.97% (18.7) 6.35 6.35 1.92% (0.7) R-3644-2007 Filing Domestic Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total Sources: Cost of Service Sales Volume 2007 2008 2007 2008 4,845.8 5,132.7 59,232 59,760 1,030.1 1,057.3 14,620 14,600 1,418.8 1,501.1 27,129 27,331 1,767.1 1,740.6 45,567 43,569 9,061.8 9,431.7 146,548 145,261 HQD-11, Doc 1 Table 2 Revenues Before After $mm $mm 4,165 4,286 1,294 1,332 1,879 1,933 1,929 1,985 9,267 9,536 HQD-12, Doc. 3, page 3 % 2.91% 2.94% 2.87% 2.90% 2.90% Cost Regul. Unit Revenue Req'mt 2007 2008 Change Growth Provision cts/kWh cts/kWh $mm 2006-07 8.18 8.59 0.41 243.69 (43.87) 7.05 7.24 0.20 28.58 (11.12) 5.23 5.49 0.26 71.74 (14.62) 3.88 4.00 0.12 50.97 (16.45) 6.18 6.49 0.31 394.98 (86.06) HQD-15, Document 4, Table R-22(c) D-2007-12 (Compliance R-3610-2006) Cost of Service 2006 2007 Domestic Small General Medium General Large Industrial Total Sources: - - Sales Volume 2006 2007 59,232 14,620 27,129 45,567 146,548 Cost Regul. Revenues Unit Revenue Req'mt Before After 2006 2007 Change Growth Provision $mm $mm % cts/kWh cts/kWh $mm 2006-07 4,050 4,128 1.92% 8.40 0.06 37.00 71.00 1,275 1,299 1.92% 7.00 0.01 2.00 18.00 1,830 1,865 1.92% 5.10 (0.03) (8.00) 24.00 1,971 2,009 1.92% 3.80 (0.02) (10.00) 26.00 9,126 9,301 1.92% 6.20 0.01 21.00 139.00 HQD-12, Document 1, Table 28. HQD-15, Document 4, Table R-22(d), R-3644-2007 Shaded cells represent input values Exhibits 3677.xls; Exhibit IEc-5ii 10/27/2008 EXHIBIT IEc-6 DEMAND AND ENERGY CLASSIFICATION OF RATE L COSTS 2007 TO 2009 Evidence of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Workpapers of Robert D. Knecht Docket No. R-3677-2008 Exhibit IEc-6 Rate L Energy Component of Generation: 2007 to 2009 Load Factor Method Generation Costs Energy Component of Generation (300 CP) Energy-Related Patrimonial Costs ($mm) Rate L Share of LF Method Energy Rate L LF Method Energy Cost 2007 4,971.2 67.2% 3,340.6 2008 4,603.5 67.1% 3,088.9 2009 4,603.5 67.2% 3,093.6 25.8% 861.6 24.8% 767.5 23.0% 712.6 Table 53 141.8 115.5 Table 9A 909.3 828.1 469.5 42.9% 201.3 450.1 41.4% 186.3 Rate L Hourly Method Energy Total Generation Energy Costs 861.6 Rate L Transmission Costs Rate L Energy Share of Transmission Rate L Transmission Energy Costs 0.0% - Total Rate L PGEÉ Costs 10.7 8.9 9.7 Total Rate L Energy Costs 872.3 1,119.4 1,024.1 43,623.0 2.57 110.0% 2.82 2.91 40,074.0 2.56 115.3% 2.95 3.01 Rate L Consumption (GWh) Rate L Unit Energy Cost (cts/kWh) Rate L Revenue/Cost Ratio Cost-Based Rate L Energy Charge (cents/kWh) HQD Proposed Energy Charge (cents/kWh) Exhibits 3677.xls; Exhibit IEc-6 45,708.0 1.91 115.6% 2.21 2.84 2009 Source Table 9A Table 53 Table 9D Table 9C Table 25B Table 11 HQD-12, D1, Table 1 10/27/2008