Zentrum für Entwicklungsforschung, Department of Political and Cultural Change (ZEFa) Coping with Post-Soviet Agriculture Knowledge and Local Governance in Horticultural Production in Tajikistan Andreas Mandler 20 March 2011 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 Inhalt 1. Title .............................................................................................................................................................. 3 2. Relevance and Context of Research ............................................................................................................ 3 3. Problem Definition of the Intended Research............................................................................................. 5 4. Central Research Question .......................................................................................................................... 5 5. Conceptual Framework ............................................................................................................................... 5 Social Order ..................................................................................................................................................... 6 Institutions....................................................................................................................................................... 6 Local Governance ............................................................................................................................................ 7 Knowledge and Agricultural Knowledge Systems ........................................................................................... 8 Innovations ...................................................................................................................................................... 8 Tajik Agricultural Knowledge ........................................................................................................................... 9 Knowledge and Governance.......................................................................................................................... 10 Regimes of Knowledge .................................................................................................................................. 10 6. Intended Research Sites ............................................................................................................................ 12 7. Sub-questions for Research ....................................................................................................................... 12 8. Methodology ............................................................................................................................................. 13 9. Time schedule............................................................................................................................................ 14 10. Budget ................................................................................................................................................... 15 11. Annex ..................................................................................................................................................... 15 12. Bibliography ........................................................................................................................................... 15 2 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 1. Title Making a Livelihood from Post-soviet Agriculture: Knowledge and Local Governance in Horticultural Production in Tajikistan. 2. Relevance and Context of Research Agriculture plays a pivotal role for both, economy and livelihood of people in Tajikistan. At present time, the agricultural sector employs more than 70% of the countries workforce while its revenues count for almost one third of the Tajik GDP. However, the chosen political strategy to cope with transition, suggests that the country sticks to a rather centralized agricultural policy, exercising considerable control over farmer. Since political independence in 1991, Tajikistan is undergoing an economic transition process that is oriented towards a market economy. A series of land reforms (Bliss, 2010a, Bliss, 2010b, DWHH, 2010, Robinson et al., 2008, Spoor, 2007) produced a vast number of new agriculturalists with heterogeneous access to natural resources as e.g. land and water. Great deals of these new farmer possess only limited knowledge about farming (Eshchanov et al., 2007, Wall, 2006a). Due to Soviet ideology that requested specialization and division of labour within the kolkhoz/sovkhoz system, many of today’s farmers are rarely able to run a farm in a private market system. “A consequence is that agricultural extension and other forms of adult education have a more important role to play in [former communist] countries than elsewhere in the world.” (Ban, 1999:121). This points to general upheavals of the agricultural knowledge systems in these countries. Given the significance of agricultural production in Tajikistan, the high attention and influence from state representatives and elite figures – from national to local level – comes as no surprise. Tajikistan’s political culture has been described as authoritarian and neo-patrimonial (Sehring, 2006, Wiegmann, 2009), where patrons use private and public resources to secure the loyalty of their clients. Informal patron – client relationships are prevalent, possibly reaching from very high up in state structures down to small villages. Tajikistan is perceived as hybrid state, which is not equally present in rural areas (Koehler and Zürcher, 2004, Zürcher, 2005). That does not mean that Tajikistan is a weak state. In selected areas as security, internal politics or economy (e.g. the cotton industry), the state is a considerably strong player. However, in other fields, as education, health or other social services, much of its competencies are delegated to other agencies and actors. It seems that political stability derives at the expenses of social development, concretely the everdecreasing of state benefits. Instead, the state appears even as vehicle to ensure primarily the interests of its own representatives or their clients, that is other elite figures (Christophe, 2005, Schetter, 2006). The deliberate creation of uncertainty belongs to the practices of power in post- 3 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 soviet societies, which provides for the representatives of the state and their clients ways to gain additional income (Christophe, 2005, Christophe, 2006, Trevisani, 2011). In order to profit from this system, it is not necessary that the state is present itself. Since state agencies act often ambiguously, e.g. businessmen are coerced to arrange protection through political actors that are powerful enough to remove ever-imminent administrative obstacles (Christophe, 2006). However, even powerful elites are not outside of a locally established system of social order, which eventually provides legitimacy (Mielke et al., 2010). Against this background, arrangements between state and elites take fundamental influence on local decision-making processes and its enforcement (Trevisani, 2011, Wiegmann, 2009). On local level, a multitude of state and other actors – as representatives of NGO, international organizations, administration or resident elites – steer affairs through institutions as Mahalla, Jamoat and other institutions. The outcomes of such decision-making processes impact on agricultural matters, as they regulate for instance the distribution and use of resources. Unlike Uzbekistan, local decisionmaking in Tajikistan seems less state regulated (Oberkircher, 2010). Nevertheless, decisions are often far away from balancing the interests of various actors. The exorbitant abscondence of Tajik migrants to Russia and elsewhere, totaling to more than 1/6 of the national population, indicates that economic development in Tajikistan faces principle difficulties. In fact, despite officially completed land reform and granted “freedom to farm” (Bliss, 2010a), incentives for farmers to increase production are rather low – a great deal of farmers has either the option nor the desire to strive for private farmland. Instead, the rural population follows a mixed livelihood strategy based on subsistence farming on the household plot. Economic and livelihood reports indicate (UNDP, 2009, WFP, 2005) that farmers from the various districts in Tajikistan manage differently to cope with the above mentioned obstacles. Insights on knowledge in rural areas and its function within local governance processes in Central Asia is rather scarce. Recent works on Uzbekistan displayed structural difficulties farmers encounter when dealing with knowledge to enhance production (Eshchanov et al., 2007, Hornidge, 2010, Oberkircher et al., 2010, Wall, 2006a). Farmer developed at the same time strategies to cope with these impediments (Herbers, 2006a, Trevisani, 2011). Still, very little is known on functional interrelations of local governance and agricultural knowledge management, particularly in Tajikistan. Although the role of state administration is well documented (Bliss, 2010a, Herbers, 2003, Robinson et al., 2008, Rowe, 2010, Šaripov, 2007), many decisions in the agricultural sector are made on local level and abscond from decision making power of the central state (Boboyorov, 2009, Herbers, 2006a, Wiegmann, 2007). In order to support agricultural development in Tajikistan, the task of the present research is to inquire how knowledge and local governance arrangements take influence on agricultural production. For this purpose I take the horticultural sector as example and compare two different 4 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 production sites in Tajikistan. The significance of horticultural production in Tajikistan is rapidly growing (Livinets, 2007). Its products are exempt from taxation and allowed for direct marketing (AVRDC, 2005, Livinets, 2007). Hence, horticultural area under crop is constantly enlarged – a fact that underlines the economic dynamics and incentives for farmers (FAO, 2008, Lerman and Sedik, 2009a). 3. Problem Definition of the Intended Research Although Tajikistan is primarily an agrarian country, benefits of local farmers from agricultural production vary strongly throughout the different districts. Focusing on the handling of knowledge in horticultural production, it is unknown why, for example, agrarian innovation (e.g. post harvest procedures, international export schemes) is in use in one place (Pendžikent), while being virtually absent in other areas (Šachrtuz). It is assumed that deviant sub-regional developments emanate from specific arrangements of agricultural-relevant knowledge and the enabling or constraining role local governance plays. The present research inquires into this interdependent relationship taking the example of Tajik horticulture production. 4. Central Research Question How do local governance arrangements enable and constrain farmers handling (access, usage, creation and amplification, dissemination) of knowledge in horticultural production in two distinct agricultural districts of Tajikistan since 1991? 5. Conceptual Framework Tajik farmers everyday life and working environment are shaped by worldviews (North, 1994, North et al., 2009) that stem from regional cultural traditions, late soviet politics, a civil war in the 90´s and the ongoing transition process since then. During post-soviet transition many – not all – arrangements of how people steer every days life were changed. This research is therefore based on a set of closely interrelated key terms, which form together the conceptual framework for the present study: Social Order Innovations Institutions Tajik Agricultural Knowledge Local Governance Knowledge and Governance Knowledge and Agricultural Knowledge Systems Regimes of Knowledge 5 Taking into account the hybrid condition of the Tajik state, aspects and outcomes of governance and administration vary strongly among sub-regions. Social Order The term social order encompasses the particular constellation of institutions and agencies or actors, not necessarily at state level (North et al., 2009), that can be found in one locality in a certain moment of time (Mielke et al., 2010). It describes an underlying system of flexible norms that is obligatory to all members of the community and which has been relevant even in times of the complete absence of state (Mielke et al., 2007, Schetter, 2009). Institutions Institutions, famously described by North (1990) as “rules of the game”, are framing not only political processes (governance), but enable or constrain social live and activities in general. Institutions are related to certain ideas of values and norms, which reflect dominant identities, legitimacies and worldviews (Boboyorov, 2009, Mielke and Schetter, 2007, North, 1994). Being intrinsically interlinked, its status varies with regard to power or visibility, as, for example legal laws, codified rules, informal rules (Hodgson, 2006). A few examples of institutions that influence agricultural production in Tajikistan, illustrate this: Behaviour structured by patron–client relations Farmers hardly ever pose own decisions or statements against elite or experts´ opinions. Due to the lack of rule of law, the support of authorities (e.g. former Kolkhoz nomenclature) is needed to solve any farming issue (Herbers, 2006b). Regulations regarding access to arable land and water The distribution of land plots to private owners or leaseholder represents a hierarchical ranking within the village (Herbers, 2006a). Conditions for the access to networks Networks are key sources of knowledge, therefore its access is regulated. For the process of decision making, relevant networks exist around kinship, migrants, neighbors or classmates (Roy, 1999). Regulations regarding the access to markets Although farmer might possess knowledge about markets and business opportunities, administrative barriers are imposed that regulate any regional exchange (Wiegmann 2009). On the basis of a mix of outdated Soviet laws and newly invented institutions, agriculturalists have to stick to soviet economic procedures, face difficulties to direct-market own produce, buy technical input, request machineries or to use transport capacities (Boboyorov, 2009). Economic opportunities depend therefore very much on linkages to elite figures (ICG, 2005, ICG, 2011). In Tajik rural areas however, institutions are modified according contextual requirements, providing ad hoc interpretative models and determinations – just in order to avoid clearness and unambiguousness (Christophe, 2006). Due to `functional overlapping´ of different institutions (institutional bricolage) their area of application is flexibly used – according to actual needs in a given decision-making process (Cleaver, 2002, Sehring, 2006). The same way, parallel decision- Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 making processes occur, as official rules may contain contradictions, or being thwarted by statedirectives or more “powerful” institutions. The flexibility how institutions are applied, signals the potential to what extend powerful actors exercise influence (Lauth and Liebert, 1999). Their outreach expands often times on more than one institution. Moreover, actors often hide the logic of their operations, instead relying on the efficiency of informal arrangements (Koehler and Zürcher, 2004, Wiegmann, 2007). It is social order that forms the overarching framework for institutional arrangements in which rural organizations as Mahallas (neighborhood associations), Jamoats (administrative divisions, similar to communes or municipalities), professional associations and kinship groups are included. Also collective communal decision-making and activities are being mobilized through this network.1 Based on its „long duré“ and embeddedness in social order, institutions create reliability of expectations. Between institutions and local moral concepts exist dynamic bonds that are incorporated into the process of decision-making and which, thus, co-author the social order in place. Local Governance Governance describes a rational social situation, embedded in a territorial, temporal, political or ideological context2. General conceptions of governance indicate that the term comprises various aspects and dimensions. It may be understood as structure or process (Pierre and Peter, 2000), whereat it refers to detectable structures (as institutions, partnerships, networks, hierarchies etc.) or it deals with processes of interaction among the various structures, which eventually lead to decisions. Michael Chibba (2009:79) captures governance as two dimensional: “The first refers to all aspects of the way a nation is governed, including its institutions, policies, laws, regulations, processes and oversight mechanisms. The second dimension is its cultural and ideological setting, for governance is perceived and shaped by values, culture, traditions and ideology.” Such a definition of governance attempts to overcome a long dominant focus on the state and administrative units (cf. various definitions by WB, USAID, IMF, DFID in Grindle (2007). Recognizing failures and shortcomings of state-centered governance concepts, especially in the context of serial state crises after the collapse of the eastern bloc in 1989; broader research interest was shifted to forms of governance, which are not or not exclusively attached to the state. One of the new perspectives developed was a broader understanding of local governance. In this sense, here with special regard to recent EU politics of decentralization, “[the term] `local governance is what the council does´ has to be replaced by a conception in which it is conceded that public decision-making concerning local issues increasingly involves multi-agency working, partnerships and policy networks, which cut across organizational boundaries – in essence governance.” (Leach and Percy-Smith, 2001). Accordingly, it appears that governance is driven by 1 Institutions, that are possibly mobilized for collective action are: hashar – common harvesting; sadaqa – collection of charity; qars – tax to support marriages, sickness, travel expenses; uschr, hums – tax to finance common goods. Conclusion of such collective efforts is not per se assured, it depends on the local context. 2 Leaning on Bailey´s semi-syllogism “Politics is a competitive game: Games are orderly ” see: VINCENT, J. (2002) The anthropology of politics : a reader in ethnography, theory, and critique, Malden, Mass., Blackwell Publishers. 7 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 a multitude of actors, thus captured as collective arrangement of social issues (Risse, 2007). Local governance in Tajikistan, given the hybrid character of the state, takes place with the state as only one actor among others (Bliss, 2010a, Wiegmann, 2009). Here, local governance stems basically from the social order in place, it appears as negotiation of overlapping institutions, mechanisms and processes, through which actors and agencies formulate their interests, settle conflicts or comply with rights and duties (Mielke et al., 2010, Boboyorov, 2009). At the same time, it is very much influenced by powerful actors that not only interfere in decision-making processes, but enable or avert enforcement of decisions. Knowledge and Agricultural Knowledge Systems Knowledge has been defined as capacity for social action, based on cognitive digestion of data and information (Gerke and Evers, 2006). In a more applied sense it appears as "the sum total of 'what everybody knows' about a social world" (Berger and Luckmann, 1984:16). Often knowledge is categorized by its application to thematic sectors or groups (e.g. horticultural knowledge, women knowledge), by its qualities (e.g. theoretical or expert knowledge) or it is grouped into systems. Wall (2006a), for example, refers in his study on knowledge management in rural Uzbekistan on three different knowledge systems (peasant KS, expert KS and post-Socialist KS). Similarly, the agricultural knowledge system – also called Agriculture Knowledge and Information System (AKIS) – incorporates all knowledge and experiences about agricultural production, post harvesting, storage, marketing and so forth. It also captures knowledge on agricultural resources, foodstuff and alimentation, as well as influences of nature on agriculture and vice versa (BLW, 2008). All knowledge that is made relevant to agricultural topics is eligible, as there is no formal steering in place (Aenis, 1997, Lemma, 2007). However, agricultural actors rely heavily on interlinked networks and channels that provide access to knowledge. A powerful agriculture is considered to be well connected with many different sources: Experts, fellow practitioners, agricultural advisory services, research institutes and others (Hoffmann et al., 2009). At the same time local knowledge has an important complementary role of linking local agriculturalists through manifold adaptation processes to global knowledge and thus new practices (Evers et al., 2006a, Gerke and Evers, 2006, Wall, 2006b). The knowledge systems perspective is useful to describe the landscape of knowledge and to group certain assets of knowledge from a particular perspective, as e.g. postsoviet knowledge. However, the conceptualization of knowledge systems tends to be additive and difficult to delimit. Despite its descriptive advantages, it is hardly possible deducing explicit rules or actions. Only by external factors (public demand, knowledge governance, cf. Wall, 2006a) the knowledge captured in a system is evaluated. Innovations Availability of knowledge and possibility to freely deal with it, is considered a precondition for innovation. “Innovation depends on many processes of knowledge production that are distributed over various institutional settings.” (Rammert, 2004:1). More specifically, agricultural innovation systems are considered as networks of different players that are transient and emerge around specific challenges and tasks at particular points in time (cf. Klerkx et al., 2009). Since innovations 8 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 are closely linked to the access, usage, creation, amplification and dissemination of knowledge; a clear understanding is necessary to identify them. With reference to Klerkx et al. (2009) innovation in the agricultural sector is roughly conceptualized as “a successful combination of ‘hardware’ (i.e., new technical devices and practices), ‘software’ (i.e., new knowledge and modes of thinking) and ‘orgware’ (i.e., new social institutions and forms of organisation)”. Knowledge and practises that enable action are highly relevant when unfolding such features of innovations, allowing rural communities e.g. to learn to cope with change and uncertainty. In this regard, innovations form the interface between knowledge and local governance, indicating previous negotiations and interaction. Tajik Agricultural Knowledge Currently, agriculture specific knowledge creation in Tajikistan, is to a great deal neglected. Prior to transition, agricultural expert knowledge was integrated in Soviet research structures, however, these resources are partly lost or became outdated (Evers and Wall, 2006b, Morgounov and Zuidema, 2001). The remains of this knowledge form the basis of current cultivation praxis that often times did not change much. That is especially true for the cotton industry, where Soviet praxis and the respective knowledge was until recently deliberately preserved (Atta, 2008, Bliss, 2010a, ICG, 2005). In general, conditions to exchange agricultural knowledge in Tajikistan are rather low.3 Nevertheless, the horticultural sector is quite excluded from this, as it appears as `emerging market´ with exclusive business rights and expanding knowledge (CACAARI, 2009) + (CACAARI 2007, 2009). That is also due to a broad variety of actors involved, as former Kolkhoz nomenclature, newcomer like NGO and Jamoat, women farmer or returning labor migrants that insert new knowledge. Horticultural production is deeply rooted in Tajik agriculture, both as subsistence crop or as export produce, thus making a very substantial contribution to peoples livelihood. 3 There are several impediments to further spread of agricultural knowledge: 1. Lack of farmers economic self-determination. 2. Problems to adapt to traditional agricultural knowledge due to soviet ideology and industrial division of labour DWHH (2010) Landreform in Tadschikistan- Eine Übersicht [Internal Report]. Bonn, Deutsche Welthungerhilfe e.V. 3. Deterioration of infrastructure since 1991 brought information flow between the regions to halt. Currently there is no common informational space in the country. 4. Media has limited freedom to report and is hardly present in rural areas BENSMANN, M. (2007) Viel Zensur, Wenig Freiheit. Medien in Zentralasien. Osteuropa, 57, 517-531, LOERSCH, A. & GRIGORIAN, M. (2000) Report on the Media Situation in Tajikistan. Geneva, Switzerland, CIMERA, NANSMIT (2009) Media Monitoring. Dushanbe, Tajikistan, NANSMIT, National Association of Independent Media in Tajikistan. 5. The very few and thematically limited agricultural research and advisory services have little outreach to rural areas. CACAARI (2009) Current Agricultural Information System in Tajikistan. IN KARIMOVA, G. (Ed.), Central Asia and the Caucasus Association of Agricultural Research Institutions CACAARI, MANDLER, A. (2010) Social and political context of agriculture advisory services in the Republic of Tajikistan. IN LABAR, K., PETRICK, M. & BUCHENRIEDER, G. (Eds.) Challenges of Education and Innovation for Agricultural Development. Studies on the Agricultural and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe. Proceedings of the 4th MACE Green Week Scientific Conference 2010. Halle (Saale), Leibniz Institute of Agricultural Development in Central and Eastern Europe, IAMO, WASON, A. (2002) Az Dekhon ba Dekhon (Farmer to Farmer): A Participatory Radio Series for Private Farmers in Tajikistan. Communication for Development Case Study 18. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations FAO. 6. Cooption of farmer lobby groups and associations (Herbers, 2006a). However, mobile telephones are increasingly in use in rural areas. 9 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 Knowledge and Governance Rural actors commune through the agricultural knowledge system in order to release innovation or solve problems (Leeuwis and Ban, 2004) what eventually serves to boost business. There is much evidence for the delicacy of agricultural production regarding limitations of communication and information (Foss, 2007, Lemma, 2007, Wall, 2006a); at the same time production is stimulated by incentives for education and knowledge exchange (Evers, 2008, Evers et al., 2006a, Roeling and Wagemakers, 1998, Röling, 1994). A growing number of scientific research deals with function and impact of knowledge management in rural areas by addressing cross-cutting problems as livelihoods (Allison and Badjeck, 2004), knowledge and gender (Inhetveen et al., 2004, TeheraniKrönner et al., 2000) or the distribution and use of knowledge (El-Berr, 2009, Neef, 2001). Knowledge appears as determinant of both, power and economic growth. Hoang et al. (2006) shows how – by means of local networks and traditional hierarchies – agricultural advisory services in Vietnam serve exclusively interests and prosperity of a small elite. In the Tajik context of scarce agricultural resources and intransparent governance, knowledge forms a strategic asset, useful to achieve benefits and competitive advantages (Gerke and Ehlert, 2009, Nissen, 2004). Not surprisingly, there is manifold interference in the relation between actors and knowledge. In order to ensure governance domains, exponents of local power structures regulate access and use of information and knowledge through physical or legal barriers. In contrast to the collective approach established during Soviet agriculture, today one´s individual relationship to power structures, as administration or local elites, defines the relationship to knowledge (Herbers, 2006a, Wall, 2006a). Regimes of Knowledge From the perspective of agricultural actors, the handling of knowledge in rural areas can be described through regimes, reflecting the flexibility of actors towards assets of knowledge or knowledge systems. Regimes may be imposed by the state, may be used by groups to include or exclude others, but describe also the way how knowledge is generally dealt with. Rural communities in Central Asia find various regimes of knowledge in place, crosscutting the knowledge systems. Partly stemming from Soviet ideological practice, regimes of truth (a term borrowed from Foucault, 1978) exercise a great influence on farmers. Taking examples from farmers in Uzbekistan, the governmental knowledge system (Trevisani, 2011, Wall, 2006a) enforces not only agricultural production (e.g. cotton, wheat), but it dictates also the discourse of how farmers speak about business. This refers also on limited vocabulary or no public space available for certain agricultural discourses. For instance insist Uzbek power structures on national-independence-wealthrhetoric’s, which make it for farmers impossible to even express needs abstaining from cotton production (Veldwisch, 2008, Trevisani, 2007). This kind of limitations originate from local arrangements, e.g. described by Lachemann (1994) as `Systeme des Nichtwissens´ or Wall (2006a) `Knowledge governance´, that neglect certain domains of knowledge by denying validity and application within the community. Such negative 10 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 regimes clearly derive from the political set up and constellations of power. In this regard, the concept of knowledge regime refers to a “constellation of political power, legal normativity, and scientific knowledge. The latter gives such a regime supplementary institutional characteristics beyond the political and the legal: its identity is also determined by the forms of knowledge predominant in the political institution.” (Rammert, 2004). In this perspective the term knowledge regime is exclusively attached to the predominant ideology and worldview. Parting from the above definition of knowledge as socially constructed (Berger and Luckmann, 1984) it becomes clear that value and significance of knowledge are `localized´ (Jasanoff, 2004, Jasanoff and Wynne, 1998) and thus subject to local power structures and the social order in place. At this point, the concept of knowledge regimes seems particularly helpful to describe local rules, that refer e.g. to the way how knowledge in various systems is handled among groups of actors. In her important study on exchange of favors in Russia, Lebedeva uses “the idea of `regimes´ for the analysis of reciprocity to avoid the assumptions implied in the usage of the terms `kinship´, `friendship´, `acquaintance´.” (1998:143). A knowledge regime describes the dynamics of how actors approach knowledge, as well as the purposes attached to such efforts. In Tajikistan, privatization of agricultural land took place mostly in favor of state representatives or other elites, as kolkhoz staff or religious dignitaries. Due to proximity to local power structures these actors were able to generate more knowledge on future developments, prepare themselves earlier on upcoming policies, what consequentially allowed this group to have more options open (“Handlungsmacht” Herbers, 2006a, 2006b). As Herbers (2006a) showed, advantage in options, not necessarily access to power or financial resources, enhanced the standing certain actors in local governance processes. Given the above mentioned scarcity of knowledge and information in rural areas, all opportunities to exchange knowledge are important to farmers, as knowledge has actively to be “procured”. This requests from Tajik farmers „cleverness“ and „viel Lauferei“ [much running about] (Herbers, 2006a: 172), in order to obtain the necessary insights. Especially Dehkon farmer (Tajik private farmer) need to dedicate themselves to endless personal conversations and visits of administration, which are vital for running private farms (Herbers, 2006a: 172f.). Similarly, another potential regime in use to cope with restrictions to farming has been described as discursive practices (Oberkircher et al., 2010). It referes to verbal strategies that camouflage deviant or illegal behavior. Farmers denial of illegal practices may also stem from the lack of adequate language and discourses (e.g. as explained above) – in a sense that there are no adequate expressions for potential confession. It seems that such practices derive from common soviet history, they are, beside Uzbekistan, also in place in Tajikistan. However, for the later, it remains to be seen to what extend such practices are meant to bypass strategically (local) governance decisions or if they are more used as ad hoc excuse. The present conceptualization of knowledge and local governance in Tajikistan is trying to capture roughly the environment and mechanisms in which decision-making takes place. It helps to 11 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 understand specific local arrangements, and thus, motivations and limitations of agricultural actors in their everyday activities. 6. Intended Research Sites Throughout Tajikistan farmers achieve different benefits from horticulture. From a general perspective, horticulture production appears to be a major source of income in Pendžikent district (Sughd province), while it contributes only little to that in Šachrtuz district (Khatlon province). Different horticultural production and marketing schemes are in place in the two sub regions. It has been noted that horticulture farmers in Pendžikent apply other approaches towards knowledge and innovations (e.g. in commercialization, cultivation practices) than their colleagues in Šachrtuz do (GAA, 2006, MEDA, 2006). This different set up is underpinned by deviant experiences of agricultural advisory services in both provinces (Livinets, 2007, Mašrabovič, 2008). For instance, farmers in the south reported frequent interferences in cropping decisions by the authorities (WFP, 2005), while experiences in the northern province Sughd display a positive ground for advisory services (WHH, 2010). Throughout the district of Šachrtuz (Khatlon) cotton has been the dominating crop for the last decades. Assumably, this cultivation practice had through various channels a strong influence on local farmers (Wall, 2006). Constraints to advisory services in Khatlon province derived from state interferences in media, advisory services or farmers associations (Mandler, 2010). Similarly, cases are reported of farmers prohibited to apply new production practises, difficulties to commercialize produce or delayed land reform (ICG, 2005, Porteous, 2005, Robinson et al., 2008, Wason, 2002). 7. Sub-questions for Research 1st research hypothesis regarding local governance in Tajikistan: Rural actors are influenced by both, local and national governance. However, specific decisions as e.g. the distribution of natural resources may only be explained by the local context. Decision making processes are embedded in a system of local social order, with often times more bounding force than orders coming from national political level. Therefore farmers in the Tajik sub-regions manage differently to enforce their interests. Guiding question: From the perspective of farmers, to what extend differ processes of local governance in Tajik sub-regions? Sub-questions: What are indicators for different impact of central and local governance in Pendžikent and Šachrtuz? Who are the drivers of local governance processes? How is social order and local governance interrelated? 12 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 Which possibilities to participate in local governance do exist for smallholder farmers, especially women-farmer? 2nd research hypothesis regarding the relation of knowledge and local government: Within the realm of local governance processes, local farming knowledge and expertise converges with e.g. industrial concepts of farming. The pluralistic, horizontal approach to knowledge of individual farmers contradicts the unidirectional implementation of knowledge in large-scale production. Especially in cotton growing regions (Šachrtuz) agricultural knowledge is focused towards the mainstream of cotton production. This industrialized logic takes effect on small-scale horticultural production. Indices for such a situation are the sluggish privatization of land or continued control of land use. In contrast, it seems that a more individual approach to knowledge is characteristic for traditional horticultural areas along the Zarafšon River in Pendžikent (Sogd). Local governance appears to be the arena where the discrepancy between formal or informal assumptions, with regard to agricultural production, is negotiated. Guiding question: To what extend is the handling of horticultural knowledge enabled or constrained by local governance arrangements in Tajikistan? Sub-questions: Through which channels (e.g. ICT, media, agricultural advisory systems, farmers associations) do local (women-)farmers approach and exchange knowledge? Which knowledge regimes exist and what are they used for? Which path-dependencies appear in handling knowledge? To what extend can generalized patterns of the relation between local governance and knowledge management be drawn from the two case studies? 8. Methodology The present research project follows an interdisciplinary, actors centered approach, which entails sociological, political, ethnological and agro-economic methods of collection, analyzing and evaluating of data. The following methodological setting has been developed: Study of literature and critical assessment of sources: Besides an in depth analysis of scientific literature and governmental publications the corpus of “grey literature”, e.g. documents of national and international NGO, are of high relevance for the present research, as they provide timely information from sub regions or governmental activities. Participant observation: By participating in everyday life it is intended to observe and document social networks, decision making processes and important other procedures. Therefore a period of 9 months of fieldwork is scheduled, in order to capture the full circle of agricultural labor. 13 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 Semi-structured interviews/ Questionnaire: Semi-structured interviews and a basic questionnaire will reveal information from the two selected sub regions that is also statistically comparable. The questionnaire is discussed with other research groups at ZEF and will be evaluated statistically (SPSS). It is aimed to develop a basic set of statistically relevant data of the population in the area of research. As interview partners especially representatives from the various groups of actors (heads of Dehkon farms, male and female heads of households, representatives of collective farms) are scheduled. The interviews will be held beforehand the questionnaire. Background-interviews: In order to gain knowledge about the general context and specific correlations, background-interviews (along guidelines) will be conducted. These talks are aiming at local experts and representatives of elites. Both interviews, background and semi-structured interviews may be carried out with the help of a female research assistant, due to the fact that many households in rural areas are headed by women farmers. Social Network Analysis: to map out some findings and underpin the results in 2 research areas, a basic SNA will be conducted. Data is collected on the basis of information gathered through the questionnaire and the interviews. That will also reveal concentrations of power and adjacent relations. Obviously the design of the methodology is flexible and will be adjusted to possible changes that occur during the research. 9. Time schedule Activity Conceptual phase, Literature Time Results Until 03/2011 Finished research proposal 1. Field research (4 months) 04 – 07/2011 Collection of field data Analysis of field data, further 11/ 2011 – 01/2012 Analysis of field research data review conceptualization of research Literature review 2. Field research (5 months) 03 – 07/ 2012 Collection of field data Writing of thesis 08/ 2012 - 05/2013 Finish thesis 14 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 10. Budget tbc 11. Annex Structure of Questionnaire [ SPSS] personal background/ household features (personal education, how became a horticulturalist?) horticultural knowledge (access, media, knots, barriers, etc) application of knowledge/ innovations (what did you learn, how you make use of it? who to ask ? SNA mapping) Preliminary starting or narrative question to ask in background interview How did you learn to be a horticulturalist/ being a private farmer/ cope with market economy? Please share with me all your experiences that you encountered as a farmer since 1991? 12. Bibliography AENIS, T. (1997) Das Wissenssystem der Schafhaltung in Brandenburg: Eine Analyse von Kommunikationsbeziehungen der beteiligten Institutionen und Organisationen aus Produktion, Forschung und Beratung, Weikersheim, Margraf Publishers. ALLISON, E. & BADJECK, M.-C. (2004) Livelihoods, Local Knowledge and the Integration of Economic Development and Conservation Concerns in the Lower Tana River Basin. Hydrobiologia, 527, 19-23. ATTA, D. V. (2008) King Cotton Freezes Tajikistan. Central Asia - Caucasus Institute Analyst, 10, 3-5. AVRDC (2005) Vegetable Production in Central Asia: Status and Perspectives. IN KALB, T. J. & MAVLYANOVA, R. F. (Eds.) Proceedings of the Workshop 13–14 June 2003, Almaty, Kazakhstan. Shanhua, Taiwan, The World Vegetable Centre AVRDC. BAN, A. V. D. (1999) Problems of Agricultural Extension in Developing and former Communist Countries. IN HANSRA, B. S. (Ed.) Globalising Indian Agriculture: Policies and Strategies. New Delhi, Classical Publishing Company. BENSMANN, M. (2007) Viel Zensur, Wenig Freiheit. Medien in Zentralasien. Osteuropa, 57, 517-531. BERGER, P. L. & LUCKMANN, T. (1984) The social construction of reality : a treatise in the sociology of knowledge, London, Penguin Books. BLISS, F. (2010a) Poverty, Governance and Participation: The Example of Tajikistan. Projekt Working Paper Nr. 1 (”Participation and Development in Central Asia”). Duisburg, Institute for Development and Peace. BLISS, F. (2010b) Partizipation in der nationalen Entwicklungsplanung und -implementierung in Tadschikistan. Projekt Working Paper Nr. 2 (”Participation and Development in Central Asia”). Duisburg, Institute for Development and Peace. BLW (2008) Strategische Weiterentwicklung des Landwirtschaftlichen Wissenssystem. Bern, Schweizerisches Bundesamt für Landwirtschaft BLW. BOBOYOROV, H. (2009) The Role of Collective Identities in Shaping Local Governance Institutions in Southern Khatlon of Tajikistan. ESCAS XI Conference 2009 on ‘Studying Central Asia: in Quest for New Paths and Concepts?’ Budapest, Hungary, [Conference Paper]. 15 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 CACAARI (2009) Current Agricultural Information System in Tajikistan. IN KARIMOVA, G. (Ed.), Central Asia and the Caucasus Association of Agricultural Research Institutions CACAARI. CHIBBA, M. (2009) Governance and Development. The current role of theory, policy and practice. World Economics, 10, 79-108. CHRISTOPHE, B. (2005) Metamorphosen des Leviathan in einer post-sozialistischen Gesellschaft: Georgiens Provinz zwischen Fassaden der Anarchie und regulativer Allmacht, Bielefeld, Transcript-Verlag. CHRISTOPHE, B. (2006) Metamorphosen des Leviathan. Strategien des State-Building in Georgien. Vortrag gehalten im Rahmen der „Silk Road Lecture“ am Zentrum für Entwicklungsforschung (ZEF) am 7. März 2006. Bonn. CLEAVER, F. (2002) Reinventing Institutions: Bricolage and the social Embeddedness of Natural Resource Management. The European Journal of Development Research, 14, 11-30. DWHH (2010) Landreform in Tadschikistan- Eine Übersicht [Internal Report]. Bonn, Deutsche Welthungerhilfe e.V. EL-BERR, S. (2009) Wer sind hier die Experten? Lokales Wissen und interkulturelle Kommunikation in Entwicklungsprojekten mit Indigenen Ecuadors, Bonn, Rheinische Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universität. ESHCHANOV, R., KAN, E., KHAMZINA, A. & LAMERS, J. P. A. (2007) Farmer’s Knowledge and Perceptions about Multipurpose Trees and Tree Intercropping Systems in Post-independence Private Farming Systems in Uzbekistan ZEF Work Papers for Sustainable Development in Central Asia 10. Bonn, ZEF. EVERS, H.-D. (2008) Knowledge Hubs and Knowledge Clusters: Designing a Knowledge Architecture for Development. ZEF Working Paper Series 27. Bonn, ZEF. EVERS, H.-D., GERKE, S. & MENKHOFF, T. (2006a) Wissen und Entwicklung - Strategien für den Aufbau einer Wissensgesellschaft. ZEF Policy Brief 6. Bonn, ZEF. EVERS, H.-D. & WALL, C. (2006b) Knowledge Loss: Managing Local Knowledge in Rural Uzbekistan. ZEF Working Papers Series 15. Bonn, ZEF. FAO (2008) The Economic Effects of Land Reform in Tajikistan. IN LERMAN, Z. & SEDIK, D. J. (Eds.) EC/FAO Food Security Programme. Phase II Food Security Information for Action. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations FAO. FOSS, N. J. (2007) The Emerging Knowledge Governance Approach: Challenges and Characteristics. Organization, 14, 29–52. FOUCAULT, M. (1978) Dispositive der Macht : Michel Foucault über Sexualität, Wissen und Wahrheit, Berlin, Merve Verlag. GAA (2006) Mid Term Evaluation, Final Report “Support to the Land Reform in Northern Tajikistan through Local Extension and Support Services”. IN ZERHUSEN, D. G. (Ed.) Bonn, German Agro Action/ Deutsche Welt Hunger Hilfe. GERKE, S. & EHLERT, J. (2009) Local Knowledge as Strategic Resource: Fishery in the Seasonal Floodplains of the Mekong Delta, Vietnam. ZEF Working Paper Series 50. Bonn, ZEF. GERKE, S. & EVERS, H.-D. (2006) Globalizing Local Knowledge: Social Science Research on Southeast Asia, 1970 - 2000. Journal of Social Issues in Southeast Asia, 21, 1 -21. GRINDLE, M. S. (2007) Going local : decentralization, democratization, and the promise of good governance / Merilee S. Grindle, Princeton, N.J. :, Princeton University Press. HERBERS, H. (2003) Die postsowjetische Neuordnung der Landnutzung im Pamir: Beeindruckender Erfolg mit kaum lösbaren Defiziten. Wandel und Persistenz in der Landnutzung Tadschikistans seit der Unabhängigkeit. IN BRECKLE, S.-W. (Ed.) Bielefelder Ökologische Beiträge. Bielefeld: [Conference Proceedings] Abteilung Ökologie/ZiF/Universität Bielefeld & GTZ CCD-Projekt/Bonn. HERBERS, H. (2006a) Landreform und Existenzsicherung in Tadschikistan. Die Handlungsmacht der Akteure im Kontext der postsowjetischen Transformation, Erlangen, Selbstverlag der Fränkischen Geographischen Gesellschaft. HERBERS, H. (2006b) Handlungsmacht und Handlungsvermögen im Transformationsprozess. Erfahrungen aus Tadschikistan. Geographica Helvetica 61, 13-20. HOANG, L. A., CASTELLA, J.-C. & NOVOSAD, P. (2006) Social Networks and Information Access: Implications for agricultural Extension in a Rice Farming Community in northern Vietnam. Agriculture and Human Values, 23, 513-527. HODGSON, G. M. (2006) What Are Institutions? Journal of Economic Issues, XL, 1-25. 16 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 HOFFMANN, V., GERSTER-BENTAYA, M., CHRISTINCK, A. & LEMMA, M. (Eds.) (2009) Rural Extension. Vol. 1: Basic Issues and Concept. Vol. 2. Examples and Background Materials Vol. 3. Training Concepts and Tools, Weikersheim, Wageningen, Margraf Publishers & CTA. HORNIDGE, A.-K. (2010) Transdisciplinary Innovation Research in Uzbekistan – one year of ‘Following The Innovation’. Development in Practice. ICG (2005) The Curse of Cotton: Central Asia's Destructive Monoculture. Asia Report N°93. Brussels, Bishkek, International Crisis Group ICG. ICG (2011) Central Asia: Decay and Decline. Asia Report N°201. Brussels, Bishkek, International Crisis Group ICG. INHETVEEN, H., SPIEKER, I., SCHMITT, M. & SCHLUDE, U. (2004) Hat Agrarwissen ein Geschlecht? Göttinger Studien zur Agrarwissenschaftsgeschichte aus einer Gender and Science-Perspektive. Zeitschrift für Agrargeschichte und Agrarsoziologie 98-103. JASANOFF, S. (Ed.) (2004) States of Knowledge: The Co-Production of Science and Social Order, London, Routledge. JASANOFF, S. & WYNNE, B. (1998) Science and Decisionmaking. IN RAYNER, S. & MALONE, E. L. (Eds.) Human Choice and Climate Change: the Societal Framework. Columbus, Ohio, USA, Batelle Press. KLERKX, L., HALL, A. & LEEUWIS, C. (2009) Strengthening Agricultural Innovation Capacity: Are Innovation Brokers the Answer? Working Paper Series 2009-019. Maastricht, United Nations University Maastricht Economic and social Research and training centre on Innovation and Technology. KOEHLER, J. & ZÜRCHER, C. (2004) Der Staat und sein Schatten. Zur Institutionalisierung hybrider Staatlichkeit im Süd-Kaukasus. WeltTrends, 12, 84 - 96. LACHENMANN, G. (1994) Systeme des Nichtwissens. Alltagsverstand und Expertenbewusstsein im Kulturvergleich. IN HITZLER, R., HONER, A. & MAEDER, C. (Eds.) Expertenwissen. Die institutionelle Kompetenz zur Konstruktion von Wirklichkeit. Opladen, Westdeutscher Verlag. LAUTH, H.-J. & LIEBERT, U. (Eds.) (1999) Im Schatten demokratischer Legitimität. Informelle Institutionen und politische Partizipation im interkulturellen Demokratien-Vergleich, Opladen, Westdeutscher Verlag. LEACH, R. & PERCY-SMITH, J. (2001) Local governance in Britain, Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire; New York, Palgrave. LEBEDEVA, A. (1998) Russia’s economy of favours, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. LEEUWIS, C. & BAN, A. V. D. (2004) Communication for Rural Innovation: Rethinking Agricultural Extension, Oxford, Blackwell Science LEMMA, M. (2007) The Agricultural Knowledge System in Tigray, Ethiopia: Recent History and Actual Effectiveness, Weikersheim, Margraf Publishers. LERMAN, Z. & SEDIK, D. J. (2009a) Sources of agricultural Productivity Growth in Central Asia. Agricultural & Applied Economics Association 2009 AAEA & ACCI Joint Annual Meeting. Milwaukee, Wisconsin, [Conference Paper]. LIVINETS, S. (2007) Report on Republic of Tajikistan for FAO Assistance. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations FAO. LOERSCH, A. & GRIGORIAN, M. (2000) Report on the Media Situation in Tajikistan. Geneva, Switzerland, CIMERA. MANDLER, A. (2010) Social and political context of agriculture advisory services in the Republic of Tajikistan. IN LABAR, K., PETRICK, M. & BUCHENRIEDER, G. (Eds.) Challenges of Education and Innovation for Agricultural Development. Studies on the Agricultural and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe. Proceedings of the 4th MACE Green Week Scientific Conference 2010. Halle (Saale), Leibniz Institute of Agricultural Development in Central and Eastern Europe, IAMO. MAŠRABOVIČ, D. B. (2008) Osobennosti formirovanija i funkcionirovanija dechkanskich (fermerskich) chozjajstv v usovijach maloseml’nogo regiona (na primere Respubliki Tadžikistan). [Besonderheiten bei der Bildung und Funktionsweise privater Dehkan Betriebe unter den Bedingungen geringer Verfügbarkeit von Land (Am Beispiel der Republik Tadschikistan)], Dušanbe. MEDA (2006) Pro-Poor Agricultural Development in Northern Tajikistan. 4th Semi-Annual Report October 1, 2005 – March 31, 2006. Waterloo, Canada, Mennonite Economic Development Associates MEDA. MIELKE, K. & SCHETTER, C. (2007) "Where is the Village?" Local Perceptions and Development Approaches in Kunduz Province. ASIEN, 71-87. 17 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 MIELKE, K., SCHETTER, C. & GLASSNER, R. (2007) Local Governance in Farkhar and Warsaj Districts of Takhar Province in Northeastern Afghanistan ZEF Amudarya Research Series Paper. Integrated Development, Environment and Sustainability Paper 7. Bonn, ZEF. MIELKE, K., SCHETTER, C. & WILDE, A. (2010) Social Order beyond the State. ZEF Working Paper Series. Bonn, ZEF [forthcoming]. MORGOUNOV, A. & ZUIDEMA, L. (2001) The Legacy of the Soviet Agricultural Research System for the Republics of Central Asia and the Caucasus. ISNAR Research Report 20. The Hague, ISNAR. NANSMIT (2009) Media Monitoring. Dushanbe, Tajikistan, NANSMIT, National Association of Independent Media in Tajikistan. NEEF, A. (2001) Land Tenure and Soil Conservation Practises - Evidence from West Africa and South East Asia. IN D.E. SCOTT, R. H. M., G.C. STEINHARDT (Ed.) Sustaining the Global Farm, 10th International Soil Conservation Meeting. Purdue University and the USDA ARS National Soil Erosion Research Laboratory. NISSEN, S. W. (2004) Tajiks’ Promised Land: A Farm of one’s Own. OSCE Magazine, 1, 4-7. NORTH, D. C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. NORTH, D. C. (1994) Economic Performance Through Time. The American Economic Review, 84, 359-368. NORTH, D. C., WALLIS, J. J. & WEINGAST, B. R. (2009) Violence and social orders : a conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history, Cambridge; New York, Cambridge University Press. OBERKIRCHER, L. (2010) Water-Saving in the Landscapes and Lifeworlds of Khorezmian Farmers, Uzbekistan. Fachbreich Geowissenschaften. Münster, Westfälischen Wilhelms-Universität Münster. OBERKIRCHER, L., TISCHBEIN, B., HORNIDGE, A.-K., SCHORCHT, G., BHADURI, A., AWAN, U. K. & MANSCHADI, A. M. (2010) Rethinking Water Management in Khorezm, Uzbekistan. Concepts and Recommendations. ZEF Working Paper Series 54. Bonn, Center for Development; Research Department of Political and Cultural Change. PIERRE, J. & PETER, G. (2000) Governance, Politics and the State, London, Macmillian. PORTEOUS, O. C. (2005) Land Reform in Tajikistan. Field Exchange, 3-12. RAMMERT, W. (2004) Two Styles of Knowing and Knowledge Regimes: Between ‘Explicitation’ and ‘Exploration’ under Conditions of ‘Functional Specialization’ or ‘Fragmental Distribution’. Technical University Technology Studies Working Papers. TU Berlin, Institute of Sociology. RISSE, T. (2007) Regieren in Räumen begrenzter Staatlichkeit. Zur "Reisefähigkeit" des GovernanceKonzeptes. SFB-Governance Working Paper Series Nr.5. Berlin. ROBINSON, S., HIGGINBOTHAM, I., GUENTHER, T. & GERMAIN, A. (2008) Land Reform in Tajikistan: Consequences for Tenure Security, Agricultural Productivity and Land Management Practices. IN BEHNKE, R. (Ed.) The Socio-economic Causes and Consequences of Desertification in Central Asia. NATO Science Series. Heidelberg, Springer. ROELING, N. G. & WAGEMAKERS, M. A. E. (1998) Facilitating sustainable agriculture : participatory learning and adaptive management in times of environmental uncertainty, Cambridge, U.K; New York, Cambridge University Press. RÖLING, N. G. (1994) Agricultural Knowledge and Information Systems. IN BLACKBURN, D. J. (Ed.) Extension Handbook: Processes and Practices. 2nd ed ed. Toronto, Thompson Educational. ROWE, W. C. (2010) Agrarian adaptations in Tajikistan: land reform, water and law. Central Asian Survey, 29, 189 - 204. ROY, O. (1999) Kolkhoz and Civil Society in the Independent States of Central Asia. IN RUFFIN, M. H. & D.WAUGH (Eds.) Civil Society in Central Asia. Washington, Center for Civil Society International. ŠARIPOV, A. F. (2007) Zemel’naja reforma v Respublike Tadžikistan [Bodenreform in der Republik Tadschikistan], Dušanbe, Nacional’naja associacija dechkanskich (fermerskich) chozjajstv (NADFCh). SCHETTER, C. (2006) Why do States Collapse, and What Exactly Happens? agriculture & rural development, 2006, 30-32. SCHETTER, C. (2009) Local Politics in Afghanistan. From a State-oriented Approach to Social Order. Concept Paper for the Symposium “Beyond the State - Local Politics in Afghanistan”. Center for Development Research (ZEF), Bonn, [Conference Paper]. SEHRING, J. (2006) The Politics of Water Institutional Reform. A comparative Analysis of Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan. Conference on Human Dimensions of Global Environmental Change. Berlin: Freie Universität, [Conference Paper]. 18 Andreas Mandler, ZEF Research Proposal 03 19/3/2011 SPOOR, M. (2007) Rural Poverty, Agrarian Reform and the Role of the State in Rural Growth and Poverty Reduction in Central Eurasia. Ten Propositions regarding Agricultural Development and Rural Poverty Reduction. Technical Consultation Meeting. FAO Regional Office for Central Asia (FAO/SEC), Ankara [unpublished]. TEHERANI-KRÖNNER, P., SCHMITT, M. & HOFFMANN-ALTMANN, U. (Eds.) (2000) Wissen, Bildung und Beratung für Frauen im ländlichen Raum, Berlin, Humboldt Universität zu Berlin. TREVISANI, T. (2007) After the Kolkhoz: rural elites in competition. Central Asian Survey, 26, 85-104. TREVISANI, T. (2011) Land and Power in Khorezm: Farmers, Communities and the State in Uzbekistan's Decollectivisation Process, Berlin, Lit Verlag. UNDP (2009) Human Development Report. New York, United Nations Development Programme UNDP. VELDWISCH, G. J. A. (2008) Cotton, Rice & Water. The Transformation of Agrarian Relations, Irrigation Technology and Water Distribution in Khorezm, Uzbekistan. Bonn, Rheinischen Friedrich-WilhelmsUniversität. VINCENT, J. (2002) The anthropology of politics : a reader in ethnography, theory, and critique, Malden, Mass., Blackwell Publishers. WALL, C. (2006a) Knowledge Management in Rural Uzbekistan: Peasant, Project and Post-Socialist perspectives in Khorezm, Bonn, Rheinische Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universität. WALL, C. (2006b) Knowledge for Development: Local and External Knowledge in Development Research. ZEF Working Paper Series 12. Bonn, ZEF. WASON, A. (2002) Az Dekhon ba Dekhon (Farmer to Farmer): A Participatory Radio Series for Private Farmers in Tajikistan. Communication for Development Case Study 18. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations FAO. WFP (2005) Household Food Security and Vulnerability Survey in Rural Tajikistan. ODAV (VAM) – WFP. Rome, World Food Programme WFP. WHH (2010) Landreform in Tadschikistan - Eine Übersicht. Bonn, Deutsche Welthungerhilfe e.V. WIEGMANN, G. (2007) Staatszerfall und -aufbau in Tadschikistan. Lokales Regieren nach dem Bürgerkrieg. Osteuropa, 57, 209-224. WIEGMANN, G. (2009) Socio-political change in Tajikistan: The development process, its challenges since the civil war and the silence before the new storm?, Hamburg, Staats- und Universitätsbibliothek Carl von Ossietzky. ZÜRCHER, C. (2005) Gewollte Schwäche. Internationale Politik, 13-24. 19