This file was created by scanning the printed publication. Errors identified by the software have been corrected; however, some errors may remain. Modern Forest Management: It's About Opening Up, Not Locking Up W. Bruce Shepard 1 I Abstract - Ecosystem management, if it is to succeed, must involve more than the application of improved scientific understandings; it must embrace the political responsibilities of the land manager. The idea of forest management as applied science was a highly successful recipe for political success during earlier decades. This was an inadequate response to the challenges that emerged in the 1970's. Today, the land manager must apply an approach to forest management that encompasses scientific, _economic, sociological, and political understandings. This will be difficult: several lines of reasoning lead to the conclusion that the issues that land managers are likely to face will be emotionally charged and political "no win" situations. There are also two challenging questions that must be resolved in designing a modem and more effective approach to forest management: how does one blend national, regional, and local considerations? and how does one integrate SCientific, economic, sociological,and political analyses in decision making? Elements of answers to these questions are considered. INTRODUCTION have sat in seminar rooms where scientists share with practioneers the latest fmdings on soil microorganisms and there is electricity in the air. "Paradigm shift" is a much overused tenn. But, in the questions being asked and being answered, I believe that teon, in its Kuhnian sense, may appropriately descn"be what is happening in the applied science of forestIy (Kuhn 1962). ForestIy is much more than applied science. The very idea of a forest as a natural resource cannot exist apart from a society that values the forest. Without values, forests may be forests but they cannot be resources, whether as sources of wood fiber or wondennent. As Shannon (1992) put it: What we call natural resources are those connections made manifest by social values and realized through available, often changing, technologies. Taking this perspective, natural resources represent the primary organization of a society. Zimmerman's "resources are not, they are becoming" remains the classic statement of this continuously co-creative relationship. Understanding the "soft" sides of forestIy can be particularly difficult within a profession that has largely defined forest management in terms of applied science. That approach, trnceable to Pinehot, has a long history of considerable success. However, the blinders it introduced left the profession ill~uipped for the turmoil that began in the early '70' s when the need was for better politics, not better science (Shepard 1990, It is not just the nation's forests and its forest policy that are undergoing critical reassessments. The profession of forestIy itself is showing inclinations toward change. There are roundtables on the ethical dimensions - not of forest management per se - but of the forestIy profession itself (Banzhaf 1993). Issues of the Journal of Forestry are devoted to assessing the adequacy of curricula for preparing foresters. And, there is increased attention given to issues of diversity within the profession and within natural resource agencies (Bembry 1990; Kennedy 1991; Pytel 1991). That the profession is seeking reorientation seems clear. That there is full appreciation of the depth of change required is less clear. More mwXy still - even among those calling for change - are the details of how a new forestIy profession might operate. Part of the change reflects an exhilarating inteJjection of emerging biological understandings, including a fuller and scientifically grounded understanding of the uncertainties and limits that attach to scientific knowledge. This appears, at least to a fuzzy thinking social scientist, to be very heady stuff. I 1 Assistant Vice President for Undergraduate Studies and Associate Professor of Political Science, Office of Academic Affairs, Oregon State University. 218 However, the dichotomy is false. Policy is made through its application, and policy implementation is bound to have a political element. The role of politics in policy implementation is accentuated in the political systems of the United States because of a dependence on interest groups as the vehicle for linking citizens to government. In many developed democracies, political parties petfonn the linkage function by offering coherent programs and canying out those programs when in power. In the United States and for a variety of structural reasons, political parties are only vehicles for winning elections; they are not, as Bill Clinton is discovering, mechanisms for governing. Interest groups, almost by default, become the mechanism for translating citizen preferences into policy. Bargaining among interest groups is the major mechanism for the development of public policy and that bargaining extends from early stages of policy formation through to policy implementation. 1\\'0 models of the policy process yield predictions about the types of questions that are likely -to be encountered by natural resource managers. In a model found to have wide utility, Salisbury and Heinz (1970), building upon the wolk of Lowi (1964), present a policy typology that relates types of public policies to the nature of the politics - demands, and supports - surrounding the matter. Their basic distinction is between allocative and structural policies: allocative policies allocate they deliver the goods (or services); structural policies set up or designate structures and processes for subsequent allocations. The National Forest Management Act (NFMA) is a structural policy. It sets up rules and procedures - page after page but never decides the harvest controversies that caused it. Legislation banning (or dictating) clear cutting would be an allocative policy. Structural and allocative policies are further broken down as shown in Figure I. Allocative policies may be distributive if they confer benefits to all active participants; "polk barrel" and " log rolling" are terms typically applied to distributive policies. Allocative policies become redistributive if there are both winners and losers and if the losers understand that others have benefited at their expense. Structural polices are self-regulatory if decision making is left largely in the hands of the regulated; professional licensing boards - e.g., for doctors, lawyers, realtors, even wonn growers in Illinois - are common examples. Regulatory policies redistribute power and authority, taking power previously held by individuals or groups and vesting that power in different arrangements. Distinctions in types of policy depend upon differences in the structure of political demand - is it split among many groups or integrated? - and the net political costs to decision makers. If the political benefits of making an allocation are high compared with costs, then legislators will make the allocation and reap the political benefits. If political benefits are low relative to costs - a common occurrence in a pluralist, interest group based politics - then structural policies result. Put more simply: the buck is passed. NFMA is a classic e~ple. 1993). The need to deal explicitly with contending social values goes against the grain of long professional tradition. With all the excitement - and controversy - about emerging scientific understandings, one may lose sight of the fact that it is people, not spotted owls, that are posing the most significant professional challenges. Today, there may be wider understanding of the need to pay attention to the political responsibilities of the natural resource manager. However, as Ellefson (1993) has pointed out, even in modem university curricul~ the focus tends to be upon teaching policy analysis but not the origins of policy in incremental processes characterized by widespread bargaining and the use of non-economic criteria for policy selection I will push beyond the policy-analysis level of dealing with the political. Some wag has obselVed that we should never look too closely at the making of sausages or laws. I am going to get into some of the sausage making. I will approach the subject by considering three questions: . 1. How do political matters end. up on the desks of natural resource managers? 2. What are the roles of planning in politics? 3. What are the roles of politics in planning? In a fmal section, my attention will be upon two as yet inadequately answered questions that must be successfully addressed in order to design a modem and more effective approach to forest management: 1. How does one blend national, regional, and local considerations? 2. How does one integrate scientific, economic, sociological, and political analyses in decision making? HOW DO POLITICAL QUESTIONS END UP ON THE DESKS OF NATURAL RESOURCE MANAGERS? In my experience, students preparing to wolk for natural resource management agencies are almost always motivated by a desire to be close to the resource being managed: to be on the land. Yet, fonner students report that they spend all their time dealing with people and paper. They are often involved deeply - and resentfully - in political issues. How can this be? In part, the answer is simple: to recognize the false dichotomy between policy and administration One dominant feature of American political culture is to hide or disguise the political elements of decisions - to expect that decisions about who is going to win and who is going to lose can be answered as technical matters through three shelf-feet of EIS statements, benefit cost analyses, and the like. We evolved institutions the city manager is an example as is the professional forest manager - to tty to maintain the fiction of a separation between making policy and implementing policy. This belief that management as applied science could eliminate politics has long and strong roots in the area of natural resources (Hays 1959). 219 ALLOCATIVE Integrated Re-Distributive STRUcruRA L ~ ~/ Demand Fragmented Distributive [MY-SU] . . -----::> Self-Regulatory [Organic Act] Regulatory [NFMA] High Low Net Benefits to Decision Makers Figure 1. - Types of public policies. The arrows in Figure 1 identify a pattern in the evolution of public policy that Salisbwy and Heinz descnbe as common and that seems to fit the area of forest policy. Policies start out as self-regulatory: demands are limited and those interested in a resource decide its use. As demands increase, distributive policies result, each interest getting some of what it wants, as suggested by the language of the Multiple Use Sustained Yield Act. Eventually, demands cannot all be met, and policy is forced to become regulatory. It is structural policies that end up on the desks of naturnl resource managers. These are politically difficult situations, issues for which any particular solution (any particular allocation) is almost certain to upset more people than will be pleased. If there were some solution that had a positive political payoff, then the legislature would have adopted it and claimed the credit. Murray Edelman (1967) took a different approach to linking types of policies with types of politics. Edelman studied many examples of regulatory policies, and he was interested in explaining a phenomenon called "regulatory capture" in which the interests being regulated end up heavily influencing those regulating them. He distinguished between material goods e.g., money, timber, power - and symbolic goods. Symbolic goods are actions designed to provide the unorganized but anxious with psychological reassurance. His studies lead him to conclude that - often in the same piece of legislation organized groups get material goods in proportion to their bargaining strength while the unorganized get symbolic actions that provide reassurance without conferring material benefits. Edelman's analysis went on to observe that symbolic reassurance kept the anxious but unorganized from getting organized and going after material goods. This fit an earlier period when studying such matters as the regulation of railroads or airlines. Edelman's analysis can be expanded to recognize that individuals care very much about symbols. Symbolic policies involve identity, morality, and status. Capital punishment, prayer in schools, gays in the military, and abortion are examples of policy issues that have major symbolic components. In contrast to what Edelman found, battles over symbols can be the basis for effective political organization The civil rights movement and the Equal Rights Amendment are cases where early efforts focused on largely symbolic matters that, nevertheless, became the basis for groups to organize and to later demand material goods. Another symbol would be the clear cut. There is hetbicide spraying. And, of course, the spotted owl. When we add Lowi, Salisbury and Heinz, and Edelman together, we get explanations of how political matters end up on the desks of naturnl resource managers. We get more. We get the prediction that the types of political questions that natural resource managers are forced to deal with will be emotionally highly charged, political "no win" situations. But, then, who needs political science to come to that conclusion? What are the Roles of Planning in Politics? Politics is about who gets what, when, and how. It is about the authoritative allocation of things people value. It is about winners and losers. Think about the National Forest Management Act of 1976. That legislation had its roots in harvest controversies on the Bitteroot and Monongahela National Forests. When groups successfully used the language of the Organic Act of 1897 to halt clear cutting, Congress was forced to act. It responded with a piece of planning legislation Why? What are the political uses of planning? What role does planning play in politics? There are many possible political uses of planning. In particular cases, it may be used to open decision making processes to wider involvement or it may be used to centralize decision making authority. In more general tenns, planning legislation can be politically attractive for three reasons: 1. Almost by definition, planning legislation is a structural policy. It allows legislators to avoid the political pain of making an allocative decision by passing responsibility for the decision to another body. 220 salience of preferences as well as analyses of what people prefer. There are both empirical (why it is that way) and oormative (why it ought to be that way) reasons. Political decision makers - and this means natural resource managers as well as elected officials - must pay attention to salience if they wish to hang onto their jobs. Who is going to follow what an official does and reward or punish that official at the next election - or the next budget hearing? It will be those for whom the issue is salient. This principle explains, for example, why we do not have stronger hand gun control legislation even though poll after poll shows that 80 percent or more of U.S. citizens ,would prefer such legislation There is a minority for whom the issue is very salient while, for the majority, the issue is not salient. The empirical "that-is-the-way-that-it-is" reason for paying attention to salience may be initially offensive. It rubs against our democratic sensibilities for it means that some preferences count more than other preferences. It is an unavoidable characteristic of our political -system: to the extent that democratic institutions require that government officials be responsive, the mechanisms force responsiveness to those who participate. However, there is also an rugument that political systems ought to pay attention to salience. This is the normative rationale, and it is the same as is used to justify a marketplace as a mechanism for distributing goods and selVices. Briefly put, the logic begins with the assumption that goods should go to those who derive the most reward from them If you prefer fine Bordeaux wines and I am happy with Ripple, it makes no sense to allocate the grape crop equally among us. Instead, the salience of our preferences is measured by our willingness to pay at the liquor store check-out counter. Note the logical leap here: we have gone from a premise that goods should be distributed based upon their utility to people to a conclusion that goods should be distributed based upon prices people will pay. So long we are comfortable with that leap - namely, with differences in people's ability to pay - then the justification for markets, and for paying attention to salience, is tight. Just as in the private mruketplace, so too with some government goods and selVices, it would be wasteful to give the same attention to my preferences as to yours if the issue has very little value to me while the matter is of great importance to you. Governments rely upon two rruyor techniques for measuring salience: making participation costly and logrolling. By making participation costly, one obtains the preferences of those for whom the issue is important enough to pay the costs of participation. That, for example, is why elected officials give more attention to mail counts than to opinion polls. An opinion poll is, in a sense, a form of participation in which the people conducting the poll have subsidized the costs of participation Writing a letter requires effort. A member of Congress who believes the polls on hand gun control legislation instead of mail counts will not be responding to salience and risks losing office. Polls, testimony at public meetings, and the like, suffer from the "strategic lying" problem If participants believe someone else will pay the costs of what they want, then they have an 2. Planning legislation provides symbolic reassurance to the anxious but unorganized. There is the appearance of having done something even if none of the underlying controversies have been addressed. 3. Planning approaches can improve the legitimacy of the decisions that eventually result. The last point requires elaboration. Governments worry enonnously about their legitimacy. Policies viewed as legitimate will be obeyed. If policies do not have legitimacy, governments can soon exhaust their resources in trying to enforce policies. Controversial policies will be accepted as legitimate by many if the processes that produced the· policies are accepted as legitimate. Consequently, governments invest great effort in designing processes that are accepted as legitimate when controversial decisions are anticipated. To figure out what will make processes legitimate, one must look at a country's political culture. In the United States, processes that provide opportuni1;ies for participation have increased legitimacy. Since it is extremely difficult for individuals to trace the influence of their participation through to [mal policy outcomes, it is the opportunity for participation, and not its effectiveness, that is politically relevant. Second, our political culture places great emphasis on decision making that incorporates non-political, scientific, rational, quantitative, technical analysis. That questions of winners and losers cannot be settled on scientific grounds is irrelevant to the political cover provided by such processes. Planning processes, of course, can appeal to both key values. This is the greatest political attraction of planning, and planning legislation has been the institutional response to many allocation controversies. Politically, the attraction of planning is not that it might lead to making better decisions~ rather, it makes decisions look better. as What are the Roles of Politics in Planning? Whatever the role of politics may be in planning, it will involve interest groups. In the United States, it is interest groups that provide governments with political information. For simplicity, the examples and illustrations that follow sometimes refer to individuals. Please keep in mind that, in the real world, individuals are usually represented politically by the groups that they belong to and support. There are both advantages and disadvantages to such a system for linking citizens to government. It is, though, a political reality that natural resource managers must recognize. In planning, politics provides information about what people want. More important, it conveys information about how badly people and their groups want things. It is this last type of information - known to political scientists as "salience" that is the central contribution of politics to planning processes. Planning processes must incorporate information about the 221 an opinion poll is the only basis for allocating areas, eve:ry area will go to snowmobilers. That would not only be inequitable what about the poor skiers? - but would also be highly inefficient. Even areas that are worthless for snowmobiling but highly prized by cross count:ry skiers would be closed to skiing. Imagine two other approaches. In the logrolling approach, managers could estimate which areas are most important to snowmobilers and which areas are of greatest importance to cross count:ry skiers and offer a forest plan that takes advantage of such trading opportunities. Or, participation could be made costly. Imagine something as simple as an area-by-area election where the choicesI are "snowmobile only" or "cross count:ry ski only." Snowmobilers, because we have assumed that they are more numerous, may win the first few elections. Eventually, though, they become at least somewhat sated while the cross count:ry skiers are becoming panicked. Or, areas of little value for snowmobiling but of great value for cross country skiing may come up for a vote. Participation by snowmobilers drops while participation by skiers ~creases. Cross count:ry skiers start winning elections. By this very simple device of making participation costly - and not by listening to what people say things are worth to them - resources are allocated in a way that is more equitable and more efficient than would have been the case if an opinion poll - eve:rybody's preference counting equally - had been used. Providing infonnation about salience is a key role for politics in natural resource planning. However, the two common techniques for obtaining this infonnation - logrolling and making participation costly - have imbedded within them a guarantee that, if they alone are relied upon, they will fail. Academics who study public choice identify logrolling as a useful technique whereby legislative bodies can achieve the provision of optimal levels of public goods. Yet, newspapers treat logrolling as an unseemly and disreputable practice. In part, this may be because logrolling requires that representatives vote against the interests of their constituents on matters of less importance. It is also true that tenns like "polk barrel" are frequently attached to the results of logrolling. Logrolling wotks in theo:ry if all affected individuals can participate in the decision However, if the costs of providing a public good can be transferred to non-participants, then logrolling can lead to over provision Legislation laden with ridiculously inefficient water projects would be a typical example. Various interests in assorted districts trade support for each other's projects, and the practice fails on efficiency grounds because the costs of the projects are transferred to the general taxpayer who is not involved in the trading. Logrolling fails when costs can be transferred to nonparticipants. There will always be strong incentives to make the transfer, to make somebody else pay. Note that the second means for measuring salience - making participation costly assures that there will be nonparticipants. One technique for measuring salience guarantees conditions that will lead the other to fail. Economists build a rationale for governmental involvement because "matket failures" lead to the under supply incentive to overstate its value. If people believe they may be forced to pay entirely for what they desire, then they may understate its value. The histo:ry of the testimony of grazing interests on user fees for grazing on public lands is replete with examples of the strategic lying problem. People cannot, though, lie with their behavior. They either pay the costs of participating by participating. Or, they don't. So, at a public meeting, it is not what the people who show up say that counts; it is who shows up that conveys the relevant political infonnation on salience. Logrolling is the other technique for obtaining infonnation on salience. Logrolling involves bartering away one's support on something of less importance to obtain another's support on something of greater importance. It often occurs in legislatures. Imagine a senator from North Carolina and a senator from Oregon getting together to discuss two bills: a bill the Oregon senator wants that would promote replanting of clear cuts in the Pacific Northwest and a bill to provide tobacco price supports introduced by the solon from 1{orth Carolina. Though the North Carolina senator may be opposed to helping economic rivals in the Pacific Northwest with a timber subsidy and even though the Oregon senator may oppose using her constituents' tax dollars to help tobacco farmers produce a poison, each senator may agree to swap votes and support both bills. This can occur if the "no" vote that each would give up is worth less than the ''yes'' vote that each would obtain in exchange. Salience is revealed in the trades that people are willing to make. (Note, again, it is not what people say, but their actual behavior - just as in a private marketplace - that reveals infonnation about salience.) Logrolling need not be restricted to legislatures. You and your family probably engaged in logrolling to figure out this summer's vacation plans. (You certainly did if, like me, you had four teenagers to deal with.) A set of alternative forest plans can be thought of as a group of possible logrolling packages designed to offer various trading opportunities. Successful logrolling packages make distinctions based upon salience; they offer people opportunities to obtain something of greater importance to them by giving up something of less importance. The extension of logrolling and making participation costly to the goods and services that governments provide may not be obvious. Consider an example. Imagine an extremely simple national forest on which there are only two uses: snowmobiling and cross count:ry skiing. As this is a greatly simplified illustration, I will call this the Dan Qualye Nationale Forest. Further imagine that, since these two categories of users do not get along well, that the management of the DQNF have subdivided the forest into many different areas, each of which will be allocated to one or the other use. Your problem, as a manager, is to decide how each area will be designated: for exclusive cross count:ry skiing or for exclusive snowmobiling. If we did not rely upon salience and instead conducted an opinion poll, then the outcome would depend upon which of the two groups of users were most numerous. Imagine that a slight majority of the potential users are snowmobilers. Then, if 222 Integrating National, Regional, and Local Concerns of public goods. However, "government failures" can lead to the over supply of publicly provided goods. This realization is important in natural resource management for it suggests partial answers to questions that I wish to explore in conclusion How are natural resource management policies ,-- say, a forest plan - to integrate national, regional, and local constraints and concerns? As Behan (1972) pointed out twenty years ago, one may start by interacting with local interest groups. However, it is dangerous to assume that local politics are a microcosm of regional or national politics. Different groups have different degrees of influence depending upon the level of government involved. Even within a single sector, say in wood products, national ftrq1S with headquarters out-of-state are not going to be able to compete as effectively with local finns if decisions are being made at multiple local sites. A great deal of political bargaining can be involved in simply establishing the level at which decisions will be reached, and groups will seek to force decisions to that level at which they are most influential. Federalism is not a tight structure of clearly defined governmental authorities. Rather, the pattern of intergovernmental arrangements that exist at any particular moment is a dynamic and changing bargain among various interests concerning the appropriate arrangement of responsibilities. Not a layer cake but a matble cake that never quite makes it to the oven From the perspective of a ranger or a forest supervisor, a wotkable model might be one in which statute, "Washington Office," and regional policies establish the boundaries within which "on the ground" policies and decisions are developed. This seems to be the model implicit in the organization of the Forest Service Manual and Handbook. The approach has some utility. Laws reflecting interests articulated at the national level do establish constraints: say, in the area of protecting cultural heritage, in the procedures for etwironmental impact statements, and the like. Consider, though, the Endangered Species Act. This is as unambiguous a piece of federal legislation as is ever likely to emerge from Congress; it lacks the usual weasel words and delegations of responsibility and is, consequently, allocative rather than structural. The statute is a statement of interests that have been effectively articulated at the national level. But, that has not lead to much clarity concerning just what are the real national political constraints that must be recognized in local decision making. Instead, there has been paralysis. There are several difficulties with a model of hierarchically arranged le~els of legal and policy constraints as a way to integrate national concerns with local decisions. For reasons discussed earlier, structural and symbolic legislation adopted at the national level will frequently and intentionally avoid providing specific guidance on the controversies that gave rise to the act. Witness NFMA. More important, national institutions are increasingly incapable of providing any kind of guidance. James Madison designed for us a political system that multiplied points of access to reduce the possibility of rule by a "majority faction" We ended up getting government by "interest group veto." Neither Congress nor the executive nor the bureaucracy nor the courts have the capacity or the inclination to exert CONCLUSION Challenges for Modern .Forest Resource Management A forestry that approaches resource management and allocation as largely a technical problem amenable to technical solutions - bigger and more ~ophisticated versions of FORPLAN - is inadequate (Alston and Iverson 1987). It simply follows the trajectOlY of the past in which forest management was defined in tenns of applied science. Foresuy today is about values, cultures, communities, and also about politics, about winners and losers. That recognition is, itself, a significant step fOlWard in developing modem forest resource management. Programs like "New Perspectives" are attempting to bring together such significant changes: a shift from emphasis upon the production of wood fiber toward protecting ecosystem vitality; the introduction of emerging scientific understandings; and, a recognition of the social and political responsibilities of the forest manager. What does it mean to recognize the political elements in resource management? This paper has explored some elementary implications. Paying attention to the political means recognizing that it is the politically most difficult and most emotionally charged issues that are likely to end up being assigned to public natural resource management agencies. It means understanding the important role of planning processes in lending legitimacy to unavoidably controversial decisions. It means that, in managing natural resources, one must pay attention not only to what people want but also to how badly people want things. It does not mean finding the final, politically correct solution; rather, it involves assisting a society in a constant process of reevaluating and redefming what constitutes appropriate uses of the nations's forests. It does not mean locking up, it means opening up. I see two major procedural questions that must be addressed before there is a system of mQdern forest management adequate to the tasks ahead. The questions are: how does one blend national, regional, and local considerations?, and how does one integrate scientific, economic, sociological, and political analyses in natural resource decision making? As in any flexible and evolving human system, we will never find "the right answer" to these questions. Rather, we will experiment, fail, and experiment again 223 complementary rather than duplicative. Consequences identified through economic analyses add to the broader range of effects identified through social impact assessments. Inferences about economic demand are quite different from the infonnation on demand provided by political assessments. They address the demands of different audiences. There is a more fundamental difference. While economic analyses can provide useful insights into overall efficiencies, demands for goods including public goods, net social benefits, and the like, it is individuals - not societies - that pay costs and receive benefits. Economic analysis cannot, generally, provide conclusions about whether any particular distribution of costs and benefits is preferable. Who will win and who will lose? Societies have governments - including natural resource managers - to handle such distributional questions, and that is where political information becomes germane. The complementarities go further. Earlier, I introduced the notion of "salience" as an important dimension of political information That presentation ended with a significant dilemma: mechanisms that are available to assess salience will, if solely relied upon, guarantee inefficient resource allocations. The problem arises because political analyses of salience must, necessarily, be restricted to identifying the interests of those for whom the issues are important. Many, indeed most people, are left out of any particular analysis. Yet, decisions may have consequences for them Large groups, each of whom have a small stake in the outcome of a natural resource decision will be particularly disadvantaged by political participation mechanisms. Well designed social impact assessments and economic analyses provide decision makers with information about these consequences. To the extent that political analyses allow decision making latitude, the natural resource manager can use this information to move decisions toward greater efficiency and greater equity than would emerge were the salient interests of the most involved participants the only guide. Social impact assessments and economic analyses can also shape public political involvement. The results of such analyses about policy consequences can change people's perceptions of various options, thereby shifting their political demands. Education can occur. However, this possibility may often be overstated. The politically involved generally already have above average levels of information and, more important, have strongly held opinions and beliefs. Discordant messages are unlikely to penetrate these perceptual barriers. Social impact assessments and economic analyses may, however, identify logrolling options that were not apparent to the participants. Such analyses may also change the mix of participants by providing information that provokes other interests to realize that they have a stake in decisions. Social, economic, and political analyses provide needed, complementary information How is that information to be integrated with other assessments, in particular, with scientific understandings about the natural resource being managed? One finds prominent ecologists emphasizing the role of the social sciences (Hardin 1968). And, there are social scientists who leadership. Instead, publics and their leaders focus upon largely symbolic entertainments, pale imitations of governing. Frustrations grow. This is the fundamental predicament for the "on-the-ground" natural resource manager: not only is there inadequate guidance from above, but "higher ups" may very well be issuing contradictory demands - e.g., congressional requirements to protect sustainability while keeping the ASQ's up - and solutions developed locally may be vetoed on up the line. The delicate WaIp and weave in the fabric of federalism woven by James Madison is tearing. At least part of the answer is to start the reweaving process at the local level. This means iriterest group politics at the local level: messy sausage making involving bargaining, logrolling, interests, influence, and salience. It means exploring ad hoc and quasi-governmental arrangements outside the ordinary way of approaching problems. It means involving "outsiders" throughout resource management processes and procedures. It means experimentation, which means failing. And, it means local officials sensitively understanding national and regional interests and, in so doing, providing the leadership that our national political institutions may be structurally incapable of delivering. Integrating Scientific, Social, Political, and Economic Analyses Whether it is a simple draft environmental impact statement or a complex, interagency regional management plan, many types of information must be brought together. Figuring out how to accomplish this integration is, perhaps, the single greatest challenge for the development of a modem forest management. I will approach the subject in two parts, first identifying the complementarities among social, political, and economic analyses, and then exploring how these analyses are integrated with scientific understandings of the physical and biological resources being managed. Political information - for example, the results of public involvement processes - economic analyses, and social impact assessments are frequently confused. However, they serve quite different but complementary purposes. The differences in purposes need to be understood if appropriate designs for each analysis are to be employed (Shepard 1981). Natural resource management and planning boil down, at its most basic level, to answering two questions: where do we want to be tomorrow? and where will today's decisions (or lack of decisions) leave us tomorrow? Political analyses address the frrst question: "where do we want to be?" Social impact assessments and economic analyses do not. Rather, those efforts help answer the second question: "what are the consequences tomorrow of the options we are considering today?" Social impact assessments provide information on how people will be affected. Political analyses reveal infonnation about what people want, about demand. Economic analyses provide both types of information - impacts and demands - but are 224 • Professional judgement and ethics are crucial ingredients of decision making processes. Professional ethics are a source for criteria that will be used to evaluate options. Professional standards are also the basis for determining the reliability and the validity of the various assessments that are used in making decisions. The basic view taken in this section can be summarized diagrammatically. Starting at the left side of Figure 2, decisions are the result of evaluations of the consequences of various options. Alternatives are judged based upon how close they get us to where we wan~ to be. The values to be applied to the consequences come from political analyses, professional ethics, and intetpretations of applicable laws and policies. The consequences to be evaluated result from various assessments and professional judgments as to the soundness of those assessments. Figure 2 represents one type of answer to the question of integrating different sources of i!lformation in natural resource decision making. It is also possible to approach the question as a challenge in human relationships. In natural resource management, the interdisciplinary team is an example of this approach. Rather than tty to precisely define uses for each type of analysis, a sociological - and political ~ institution is designed with the expectation that it will achieve the desired reject that position (Crowe 1969) or who would leave the ball in the ecologist's court (Caldwell 1987). Sort of an interdisciplinary tennis match. Whatever the type of analysis - social or biological several principles seem to apply: • Information is not understanding. Understanding is the result of a creative act by the observer and "accepted" understandings - scientific or political - are the result of ongoing social processes. • Facts have no meanings until humans intetpret them. No amount of data collection is going to obviate the need for judgement. • Science does not make decisions. Societies do. Whether society should take .an action that will lead to the extermination of a species is a political, not a scientific, question. • Information and understandings will always be incomplete, tentative, subject to change, and possibly wrong. During long life, one will mistakenly reject the null ·hypothesis at the .05 level 1 in 20 times. One will never know which of the times were the errors. Risks must be taken. This does suggest weighing the consequences of various types of errors in establishing when to be particularly cautious. a Other Assessments (Biological, economic, ... ) 1 Social Impact Assessment I Estimation of i J --+ 1 ---~ Professional Judgement and Ethics Political Analysis I --+~_______ E_f_f_e_c_t_s________= Criteria for Evaluating Effects Evaluat ion of Eff ects a nd Compari son of Alter natives !Decision j i Laws/Policies Affecting Acceptability of Certain Effects Figure 2. - Integrating political, social, economic, and biological information in natural resource decision making. 225 integration of understandings. On-the-ground "New Perspectives" experimentation with structures that incorporate " non-traditional" publics provides other examples (Lichen 1993). Wondolleck's (1988) advocacy of conflict management techniques and Brown and Peterson's (1993) suggested use of " citizen juries" are other examples of the more general strategy: to integrate various understandings by focusing upon the structuring of inteq>ersonal communication and social and political relationships rather than upon the flow charting of steps in a process. There are many ways in which one might restructure decision making to achieve an improved forest management although, being· nontraditional, the variations require imagination to conceive, organizational fleXIbility for implementation, and a willingness to risk failure. With today's controversies and challenges, it is easy to lose track of how far natural resource management has come in "opening up" to publics, to perfonning the political act of allocating resowces based, in part, on assessments of what people want and how badly thej want things. Twenty years ago, lack of responsiveness to publics lead to harvest controversies and then to the National Forest Management Plan (Weitzman 1977). Fifteen years ago, euphemisms like "institutional analysis" still had to be used to refer to political responsibilities (Shepard 1980). Even when such euphemisms were used, personnel in agencies like the Forest Service denied that their jobs entailed such responsibilities, asserted that such matters were for "higher ups" to take care of, and the "much higher ups" were reluctant to provide line personnel with increased understanding of means for being politically responsive to publics. Undertakings like "New Perspectives" and "ecosystem management" represent a dramatic change from that earlier orientation because they acknowledge that social and political responsiveness is a legitimate aspect of a forest manager's job, and this is found both in agency policy (Salwasser 1990; Robertson 1992; Kessler 1992; Overbay 1992) and practioneers' beliefs (Clatk 1991). "Being responsive" and "opening up" sound great. However, as this paper has explored, the political aspects of natural resource management are complex, challenging, and may require uncomfortable confrontations with conventional assumptions about the uses of both political and scientific infonnation in decision making. Behan, R. W. 1972. Para-politics and natural resource administration, or what to do while waiting for the Sierra Club to arrive. USDA Forest Senrice Conference, Boise, Idaho, April 27. Bembry, L.; Osborne, N. 1990. Removing barriers to diversity; multicultural representation in upper management. Journal of Forestty. 90(10): 28-32. Brown, T.; Peterson, G. 1993. A political-economic perspective on sustained ecosystem use and development. In this volume. Caldwell, L. K. 1987. Biocracy: public policy and the life sciences. Westview Press, Boulder, CO. Clatk, R. N.; Spmkey, G. H. 1991. New forestty or new perspectives? The importance of asking the right questions. Forest Perspectives. 1(1) 9-13. Crowe, B. L. 1969. The tragedy of the commons revisited. Science. 166: 1103-1107. Edelman, M. 1967. The symbolic uses of politics. University of Illinois Press, Uroana. Ellefson, P. V. 1993. Poliq.cs and policy making: a teaching challenge in forestty. Journal of Forestty. 91(3): 24-27. Fairfax, S. 1982. Old recipes for new federalism. Environmental Law. 12: 945-980 Hardin, G. 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science. 162: 1243-1248. Hays, S. 1959. ConselVation and the gospel of efficiency. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Hite, J. 1979. Room and Situation Nelson-Hall, Chicago. Kennedy, J.J. 1991. Integrating gender diverse and interdisciplinary professionals into traditional U.S. Department of Agriculture-Forest SelVice culture. Society and Natural Resources. 4(4): 165-176. Kessler, W. B.; Salwasser, H.; Cartwright Jr., C. W.; Caplan, J. A. 1992. New perspectives for sustainable natural resources management. Ecological Applications. 2(3): 221-225. Kuhn, T. S. 1962. The structure of scientific revolutions. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Lowi, T. J. 1964. American business, public policy, case studies, and political science. World Politics. 16(July): 677-715. Lowi, T. J. 1969. The end of liberalism; ideology, policy, and the crisis of public authority. Norton, New YOtic. Olson, M. 1965. The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Overbay J. C. 1992. Ecosystem management-keynote address. ill: Proceedings National Workshop, Taking an Ecological Approach to Management, WO-WSA-3, USDA, Forest Service, Watershed and Air Management, Washington, D.C. 3-15. Pytel, C. 1991. IncOIporating our nations's diversity: a strategy to achieve full multicultural participation Journal of Forestry. 91(1): 16-19. Robertson, D. F. 1992. Ecosystem management of the National Forests and Grasslands. Memorandum to Regional Foresters and Station Directors, June 4. LITERATURE CITED Alston, R. M.; Iverson, D. C. 1987. The road from Timber RAM to FORPLAN: how far have we travelled? Journal of Forestty. 85(6): 43-49. Banzhaf, W. H. et al. 1993. Ethical decisionmaking: a roundtable. Journal of Forestty. 91(4): 10-13. 226 Salisbwy, R.; Heinz, J. 1970. A theory of policy analysis and some preliminary applications. In: Policy Analysis in Political Science, ed. by I. Sharkansky. Markham, San Francisco, CA Salwasser, H. 1990. New perspectives in sustainable multiple-use management and research. In: Proceedings Environmental Agenda/New Perspectives Workshop, USDA Forest Service, Pacific Southwest Region, San Francisco, CA. Shepard, W. B. 1981. Avoiding confusion between social assessment and analysis of public involvement. Office of Policy Analysis, USDA Forest Service, Washington, D.C. Shepard, W. B. 1990. Seeing the forest for the trees: new perspectives in the Forest Service." Renewable Resources Journal. 8(4):9-12. Shepard, W. B. 1993. Ecosystem management in the Forest Service: political implications, impediments, and imperatives. PNW Technical Bulletin, in press. Weitzman, S. 1977. Lessons from the Monongahela experience. USDA, Forest Seryice, Washington, DC. Wondolleck, J. M. 1988. Public lands conflict resolution: managing national forest disputes. Plenum Press, New Yolk. C-l~-13. Shannon, M. A. 1992. Foresters as strategic thinkers, facilitators, and citizens. Journal of Forestry. 90 (10): 24-27. Shepard, W. B. 1980. Institutional analysis in forest resource management. USDA Forest Service National Area Platming and Development WoIkshop, Atlanta,. Georgia, October 27-31. 227