This file was created by scanning the printed publication. Errors identified by the software have been corrected; however, some errors may remain. ECONOMIC FACTORS FOR CONSIDERATION IN CONVERTING ANNUAL GRASSLANDS TO IMPROVED RANGELANDS Neil R. Rimbey same context, range improvement costs amounted to $1.13 and $0.79 per AUM for BLM and FS, respectively. An issue related to deficit spending that also bears mentioning is the inflation of improvement costs and the impact on improvement projects. We have seen substantial increases in improvement material and machinery costs over the past 20 years. The shortages of petroleum products, which first became apparent in the crises of the mid-1970's, dramatically increased petroleum and petrochemical costs. This created a "double-whammy" for traditional rangeland improvement practices. First, input costs for herbicides, fertilizers, and other direct inputs for projects such as brush control were extremely high. Second, "support" inputs such as labor and tractor and airplane fuel increased the operation costs of equipment used in these types of projects. Over the same period of time, appropriations for range improvements within the Federal agencies' budgets have shown some increases. However, actual declines in these appropriations have taken place since the early 1980's (fig. 1). The ultimate impact of these factors has been a dramatic decline in rangeland improvement practices. Figure 2 depicts acres of rangeland seeding projects undertaken by Idaho BLM, by year, since 1960. Recognizing that these projects fluctuate with funding and need, it is still readily apparent from this graph that the general trend is downward. With limited budgets and concerns about spending and subsidization, the role of economics has become more important in the analysis of range improvements. The issue has thus become, "How can we get the biggest bang for our limited range improvement dollars?" Economics can provide range managers with answers to these types of questions, should they decide to use the tools. ABSTRACT Economic feasibility analysis has become a critical element in most land treatment projects. This paper details and compares three methods of economic effu:iency analysis applicable to annual grasslands situations. In addition, comparisons of results of the analyses are made with recommendations on uses of the techniques. Factors besides livestock forage and wildlife habitat influence improvement decisions. Several of these are detailed, with suggestions made for integrating these into economic efficiency analysis. INTRODUCTION The purposes of this paper are to provide range management professionals with a discussion of the theory of economic analysis of range improvement, detail why economic analysis is necessary, and provide an explanation of three methods of analysis. The paper also presents some of the other factors (amenities, nonmarket goods, and risk) that must be considered in any analysis of range improvements. WHY ECONOMIC ANALYSIS? Several factors have resulted in range professionals becoming involved in the mundane task of economic analysis of rangeland improvements. The mounting Federal deficit and resulting concerns about government spending have raised the issue of deficit spending throughout most units of government. Concerns about the costs and returns of the Federal grazing programs have emerged as part of this national debate. In fact, the recent update of the 1986 Grazing Fee Review and Evaluation (USDA and USDI 1992) reports that 1990 range management costs amount to $3.21 per animal unit month (AUM) for grazing administered by the Bureau of Land Management (BLM), U.S. Department of the Interior, and $3.24 per AUM for areas operated under Forest Service (FS), U.S. Department of Agriculture, jurisdiction. From these figures, one can infer that BLM is spending $2.41 per AUM for each $1 received from grazing, while the FS is spending $3.38 per AUM for each $1 received. Within this HOW TO DO ECONOMIC ANALYSIS? Most rangeland improvement projects involve some upfront investments oflabor and capital with benefits accruing over a period of years. The usual question posed by range managers is: "Will this pay?" To answer this critical question, it is necessary to quantify the benefits and costs associated with specific practices and bring all dollar costs and returns into the same timeframe for analysis. It is imperative that the analyst discount future benefits and costs back into today's dollars. Dollars received or spent 20 years from now are not equal to today's dollars. If one wants to have $5 for a party that will occur 6 years down the road, he or she only Paper presented at the Symposium on Ecology, Management, and ResU>ration oflntermountain Annual Rangelands, Boise, ID, May 18-22, 1992. Neil R. Rimbey is Professor and Extension Range Economist, Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology, University of Idaho, Moscow, ID 83843. Stationed at Coldwell Research and Extension Center. 408 1962 1965 1968 1971 1974 19n 1983 1980 1986 1989 Year Figure 1-BLM range Improvement appropriation, 1962-1990. Source: Public land Statistics. 120 ., c 100 80 I:I 0 .c e 60 I ::l 40 20 0 1960 1963 1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1987 1984 Year 1990 Figure 2-Rangeland seecfings, Idaho BLM 196o-1990 (aclyr). Source: Public land Statistics. are all discounted back to today's dollars. This is done using the following equation: needs to put $3.52 in the bank today at 6 percent annual interest. In other words, the present value of $5 that we will receive 6 years from now is only $3.52 in today's dollars. This concept is known as the time value of money (Nielsen 1984; Workman 1986). Time is a critical component in analysis of range improvements. Benefits coming back from range improvements 20 years from now are heavily discounted. A dollar's worth of benefits received in the year 2012 are only worth about 31 cents in today's terms (again, discounted at 6 percent). All of the economic efficiency measures covered in the following section are derived using the concept of present value. In other words, the streams of benefits and costs Vn PV= where: (1 + i) 11 PV =present value Vn = dollar value in year n i = interest or discount rate n =year. The present value of $3.52 was calculated for the $5 that one receives six years from now at a 6 percent discount rate using the formula. 409 ~URESOFECONONUC some of the other factors impacted by rangeland improvements has created some analysis problems for the range professional. There has also been ~ ~ppar~nt shift ~ agency priorities away from the traditional commodity" programs to factors such as recreation, amenity values, biodiversity, and others. Options for valuing benefits from market commodities such as livestock forage are fairly straightforward (Wagstaff and Pope 1987; Workman 1986) and should pose very few problems for the analyst. However, attempting to value some of the other factors raises some new issues and problems. Wildlife numbers have increased dramatically in Idaho and other Intermountain States (Nielsen and McBride 1989· Rimbey and others 1991). With this we are also seem'g increased recreational opportunities and associated consumer spending. Opportunities to include wildlife benefits in economic analysis of range improvements are present in most range improvement projects. Research in Idaho (Donnelly and Nelson 1986; Donnelly and others 1985; Sorg and Nelson 1986; Sorg and others 1985) .has derived willingness to pay and contingent value estunates of wildlife-based economic values for inclusion in range improvement analysis. These estimates were derived on a species basis and provide an estimate of hunters' and other recreational users' willingness to pay for access to increased numbers of these species. However, one should realize some of the issues and problems in including these in range improvement analysis. There is no direct tie to a market system for use in validating these values of wildlife resources. Questions to ponder include: "What's an additional antelope worth?" "What's an inch of topsoil on this site worth?" "What's this view worth?" They must be answered before including amenity values in the economic analysis of rangeland improvement. In terms of competition for limited forage or habitat (for example, livestock versus wildlife), there are some issues of "apples and oranges" of livestock and wildlife values that need resolution before informed policy decisions can be made. Similar issues are present in attempting to value other resource values such as erosion control, water quality enhancement, biodiversity, and others. Some peoples' perspective of biodiversity is to add forbs to a seeding mix. From one economist's perspective, the value ofbiodiversity must more than cover the increased costs of short-lived forbs included in the seeding mix. How do you place an economic value on biodiversity? Opportunities do exist for valuing some of these other factors in the annual grassland areas of the Intermountain region. Fire danger is an excellent example of one of these. BLM records for Idaho (USDI/BLM) reveal some interesting facts relative to fire rehabilitation costs. Over the last 6 years, there have been 149 fire rehabilitation projects in Idaho. Funding for these projects has amounted to $9.4 million since 1985. Average annual expenditures amounted to $1.5 million, or $63,000 per project. It would appear that there is an excellent opportunity to use these types of figures in conjunction with some fire frequency and probability work to derive estimates of the "cost of doing nothing" to slow the invasion of annual grasses. Risk is inherent in most activities of our lives. Risk also impacts range improvement decisions through factors such EFFICIENCY The following discussion of measures of economic efficiency is all seated in the discounting process and formula just discussed. Each measure relies on the concept of discounting, with variations in the final calculation of efficiency measures. The range improvement analyst must first develop estimates of the annual benefits and costs over the life of the project. The annual values are then discounted to derive present value. The streams of discounted benefits and costs are summed. Efficiency measures are then calculated using the following methods. Benefit/Cost Ratio A common investment analysis tool is the Benefit/Cost Ratio (B/C). This efficiency measure is calculated by taking the ratio of the sum of discounted benefits to the sum of the discounted costs. In other words, discounted benefits are divided by discounted costs. The investment opportunity is deemed efficient if the ratio is greater than 1. Net Present Value Net Present Value (NPV) is the difference between discounted benefits and discounted costs, or discounted benefits minus discounted costs. The investment is efficient if the difference is greater than zero. Internal Rate of Return Internal Rate of Return (IRR) is the discount rate that equates the sum of discounted benefits to the sum of the discounted costs. IRR indicates the annual rate of return on an investment in rangeland improvement. In efficiency terms, the higher the calculated IRR, the better the investment opportunity. Uses of this efficiency measure may be most applicable in private investment decisions. For example, comparisons can be made between IRR and the interest rate on borrowed capital. An IRR of 15 percent may look quite favorable in relation to current interest rates of 7 percent. Workman (1984) provides a discussion of the uses and misuses of these efficiency measures and some of the inconsistencies of the different measures. He concludes that NPV should be used as the "exclusive criterion" when choosing between two alternatives. B/C should be used to rank alternatives in attempting to select the optimum combination of projects, with NPV "side calculations" performed to verify the accuracy of the combinations. Workman also suggests that IRR has more application in private land range improvement analysis, where comparisons between the IRR and interest rates on borrowed capital are critical factors. OTHER FACTORS Traditionally, rangeland improvement projects have included the value of increased livestock forage as the only quantifiable benefit in the analysis. Recent concern for 410 as weather, seeding or improvement technology, and market changes. Bernardo and Engle (1990) provide an assessment of the impacts of private land manager attitudes toward risk on range improvement decisions. In other work, Bernardo and others (1988) concluded that a range improvement practice (prescribed fire) was a risk-reducing practice. From the range practitioner's perspective, consistency in the analysis should be the goal. If risk considerations are included as a cost in the analysis, do not also reduce the benefit side of the analysis by the same risk factor. Bernardo, D. J.; Engle, D. M. 1990. The effect of manager risk attitudes on range improvement decisions. Journal of Range Management. 43(3): 242-249. Donnelly, Dennis M.; Loomis, John B.; Sorg, Cindy F.; Nelson, Louis J. 1985. Net economic value ofrecreationalsteelhead fishing in Idaho. Resour. Bull. RM-9. Fort Collins, CO: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. 23 p. Donnelly, Dennis M.; Nelson, Louis J. 1986. Net economic value of deer hunting in Idaho. Resour. Bull. RM-13. Fort Collins, CO: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. 27 p. Loomis, John B.; Donnelly, Dennis M.; Sorg, Cindy F.; Oldenburg, Lloyd. 1985. Net economic value of hunting unique species in Idaho: bighorn sheep, mountain goat, moose and antelope. Resour. Bull. RM-10. Fort Collins, CO: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service,Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. 16 p. Nielsen, Darwin B. 1984. Economic factors to be considered in Sagebrush/Grassland management. In: Developing strategies for rangeland management: a report by the committee on developing strategies for rangeland management. NRC/NAS. Boulder, CO: Westview Press: 1373-1386. Nielsen, D. B.; McBride, K. 1989. Losses on private land due to big-game animals. Utah Science. Summer 1989: 78-87. Rimbey, N. R.; Gardner, R. L.; Patterson, P. E. 1991. Wildlife depredation policy development. Rangelands. 13(6): 272-275. Sorg, Cindy F.; Loomis, John B.; Donnelly, Dennis M.; Peterson, George L.; Nelson, Louis J. 1985. Net economic value of cold and warm water fishing in Idaho. Resour. Bull. RM-11. Fort Collins, CO: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. 23 p. Sorg, Cindy F.; Nelson, Louis J. 1986. Net economic value of elk hunting in Idaho. Resour. Bull. RM-12. Fort Collins, CO: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station. 21p. USDA and USDI. 1992. Grazing fee review and evaluation update of the 1986 final report. Report of the Secretaries of Agriculture and the Interior; April 30, 1992. USDIIBLM. [Various issues.] Public Land Statistics. Washington, DC. Wagstaff, Fred J .; Arden, Pope C., III. 1987. Finding the appropriate forage value for analyzing the feasibility of public range improvements. Res. Pap. INT-378. Ogden, UT: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Intermountain Research Station. 5 p. Workman, John P. 1984. Criteria for investment feasibility and selection. In: Developing strategies for rangeland management: a report by the committee on developing strategies for rangeland management. NRC/NAS. Boulder, CO: Westview Press: 1475-1507. Workman, John P. 1986. Range economics. New York: Macmillan. 217 p. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS This presentation has detailed some of the basis for economic analysis for range improvements, some of the methods available to range managers, and some of the other factors to consider in the analysis. In addition, there are several suggestions that will help with these analyses on annual grasslands. Conflicts in goals of the actors in the management process were fairly obvious during the course of the conference. Are annual grasslands a problem or a solution? Presentations relating to the positive value of cheatgrass as livestock forage conflicted with presentations relating the danger associated with annual grass invasions. These conflicts must be resolved before consideration of rangeland improvements is undertaken. Seedings may be a benefit in some peoples' eyes and a cost to others. The era of throwing money at problems in hopes that they will fix themselves appears to be over. Limited funding should be spent only on projects where a broad spectrum of support and commitment is present. This implies some type of cooperative management process to determine group goals and objectives for an allotment, to which economic analysis of range improvements is one piece of the puzzle. Economic analysis of range improvements must be done BEFORE the projecis are undertaken. Use the analysis as a tool in making management decisions, not as justification for what was done. Allocation of scarce range improvement funding can only be done efficiently with the use of economic analysis. The goal of range managers should be to achieve the biggest bang for the limited funds available. Economic analysis must be consistent. Do not reduce benefits to account for nonuse or risk of failure and also include these factors as a cost. Finally, in terms of conversions of native vegetation to annual grasslands, there appears to be an opportunity for estimating a site-specific "cost of doing nothing" factor for inclusion in economic analysis. Probability theory and fire frequency and danger may form the basis for some future work in this area that will hopefully provide range managers with another tool for use in improvement analysis. REFERENCES Bernardo, D. J.; Engle, D. M.; McCollum, E. T.1988. An economic asseSBment of risk and returns from prescribed burning on tallgrass prairie. Journal of Range Management. 41(2): 178-183. 411