Investigating the Negative Relationship Between Wages and Obesity Matt Trombley Department of Economics UNC – Greensboro Abstract A substantial literature has established that obesity is negatively associated with wages, particularly among females. However, prior research has found limited evidence in support of the mechanisms hypothesized to drive this relationship. Utilizing data from a single U.S. telecommunications firm I add to the literature by testing for differences in productivity between obese and non-obese workers, as well as the possibility of coworker and supervisor discrimination, using control variables unavailable in prior studies. Consistent with previous research, I find that obesity is negatively associated with wages among females. Results suggest that differences in productivity account for over half of this wage penalty, but I find no evidence that coworker or manager discrimination against obese employees is occurring among males or females. However, I do find evidence that the wage-obesity penalty among females occurs only among obese mothers, a result that may suggest differences in unobserved productivity between obese and non-obese mothers. October 2013 1. Introduction Obesity is a substantial health issue in the United States, affecting 35% of adults in 2010 – a proportion projected to increase to 51% by 2030 (Ogden, et al., 2012, Finkelstein, et al. 2012).1 Finkelstein et al. (2009) estimate that in 2008 obesity accounted for 10% of medical spending in the US at a cost of $147 billion. In addition to direct medical costs, obesity may incur significant economic costs through lost productivity. Numerous studies link obesity to greater rates of both absenteeism and presenteeism (i.e. reduced work effort while present on the job), and it is estimated that in 2008 obesity-related absenteeism and presenteeism cost employers $40.8 billion in lost productivity (Finkelstein, et al. 2010).2 Perhaps unsurprisingly, obesity has been linked to lower wages across the demographic spectrum in the United States, Europe, and even China (see e.g. Cawley, 2004; Greve, 2008; Shimokawa, 2008, Garcia and Quintana-Domeque, 2007; Lundborg et al., 2007). Subsequent studies using instrumental variables provide evidence of a causal relationship between body mass and wages that is not attributable to reverse causality.3 Recently, studies have attempted to uncover the mechanism(s) that may be driving the wage-obesity relationship. Because results from these efforts have either failed to fully account for this relationship, or have been inconsistent across studies, establishing the mechanism(s) behind the wage-obesity relationship remains an important research endeavor. While diminished productivity provides a likely explanation it is useful to understand why obese workers might be less productive than their non-obese counterparts. Though some inputs to employees’ 1 Body Mass Index (BMI) is the standard scale for establishing a healthy weight to height ratio. BMI is defined as the ratio of kilograms of weight to squared-meters of height. Healthy BMI is classified within the range [18.5,25), while [25,30) is classified as overweight, and people with BMI > 30 are classified as obese. 2 For examples of studies regarding obesity and absenteeism/presenteeism, see Howard and Potter, 2012; Goetzel, et al., 2010; Ricci and Chee, 2005; Tsai et al., 2008; Burton, et al., 1999; Tucker and Friedman, 1998; Schmier, Jones, and Halpern, 2006; Finkelstein et al, 2010; Gates et al., 2008; Pronk et al., 2004 3 For a thorough review of the wage-BMI instrumental variables literature, see Kortt and Leigh, 2010. 1 production function are essentially immutable (e.g. innate ability), other inputs, such as health stock, may be subject to change. To the extent that lost productivity is recoverable through intervention there may be motivation for public or private (i.e. firm-level) health policy to encourage healthier behaviors among employees. Furthermore, productivity may not tell the full story. One hypothesis advanced by Baum and Ford (2004) is that the wage penalty for obesity that remains unexplained after controlling for typical human capital and demographic variables may be attributable to discrimination. Carr and Friedman (2005) report that BMI is positively correlated with perceived workplace discrimination (e.g. rudeness, being treated as less intelligent, etc.) and that such workplace discrimination is more prevalent among white collar workers. Obese workers are also more likely to be perceived as lazy, lacking in self-control, of lower ability, and less likely to get along with and be accepted by coworkers and subordinates (Rudolph, et al. 2009). While the potential presence of systematic discrimination may seem more of a legal or ethical dilemma than an economic one, the socio-economic implications are significant. Nonwhites, less-educated individuals, and low-income females are more likely to be obese than others (Ogden, et al. 2010; Flegal, et al., 2012). To the extent that vulnerable populations are more likely to be obese, the wage effects of discrimination may have repercussions on income equality or equity of opportunity. Additionally, discrimination may exacerbate productivity losses, for instance if it limits beneficial cooperation in the workplace. Discrimination against obese individuals has also been shown to increase the negative health effects of obesity (Schafer and Ferraro, 2011) which may increase absenteeism or presenteeism costs to employers. 2 My study adds to the literature by attempting to identify the underlying mechanism(s) that may be confounding the wage-obesity relationship, using detailed measures unavailable in previous studies. Specifically, I test for differences in productivity between obese and normalweight employees that may be attributable to differences in human capital accumulation or to differences in employee health (e.g. physical function, sleep quality, or cardiovascular fitness). I also test for the possibility of peer or coworker discrimination. This study utilizes a cross-section of employee-level data from a US telecommunications firm, which offers a number of advantages over standard national-level datasets. First, the data contain productivity measures not found in national-level data sets. These include detailed measures of human capital accumulation, health, and a rating of worker presenteeism that may capture previously unobserved differences in productivity between obese and non-obese workers. Second, information on the firm’s organizational structure allows me to test if obese workers are being discriminated against by their peers or supervisors. Third, all employees in the dataset are high-income earners relative to the US population at large. The lowest paid employee earns nearly $40,000 per year, and the median worker earns nearly $85,000 annually. The high income of the sample greatly alleviates concerns about possible reverse causality between low-income and obesity. Additionally the data contain precise measures of the variables of interest. Measures of annual salary used to construct hourly wages are retrieved from administrative records, and BMI measures are directly gathered by trained data collectors. By eliminating self-reports of BMI and salary, the dependent variable and independent variable of interest should be less subject to measurement error than in previous studies.4 4 As acknowledged by previous studies (e.g., Burkhauser and Cawley, 2008), BMI is an imperfect measure of health, as ratios of weight to height do not perfectly account for body frame or muscle mass. To circumvent this issue, several recent studies have substituted percent body fat or waist size for BMI in the regression equation (Bozoyan and Wolbring, 2011; Wada and Tekin, 2010; Johansson et al., 2009). Unfortunately the available data do 3 Consistent with previous research I find that obese females earn significantly less than normal-weight women: a penalty of nearly 7.0%. Controlling for measures of productivity (human capital investment and health) reduces the estimated wage penalty to 3.5% and renders it statistically insignificant. I find no evidence of peer or supervisor discrimination among females, but do find evidence that the wage penalty only occurs among obese mothers, and that obese females with no children may actually earn slightly more than normal-weight females. I also find evidence that obese males earn more than normal-weight males. Controlling for health actually increases the wage premium among males, suggesting that obese males are more productive than normal-weight males, but that the negative health effects associated with obesity diminish this productivity advantage. I reject the hypothesis of peer discrimination against obese males but cannot rule out the possibility of supervisor discrimination. Unlike females, obese males do not suffer any additional wage penalty after having children. The remainder of the study is as follows. Section 2 discusses previous attempts to explain the well-documented negative relationship between wages and obesity. Section 3 introduces the econometric model, while Section 4 describes the data in detail. Section 5 reports the results of tests for both differences in productivity and discrimination. Lastly, section 6 explores the possibility that the wage-obesity relationship is correlated with household fertility decisions. 2. Background and Previous Literature Numerous studies have examined the relationship between BMI/obesity and wages, with initial research utilizing standard exogenous OLS methods to establish a negative correlation. Register and Williams (1990) find that obese females face a significant penalty in hourly wages compared to their normal-weight counterparts but do not find a wage penalty for males. Pagan not contain measures of body fat or waist circumference. Since the majority of the literature uses the BMI measures previously described rather than waist size, using BMI is consistent with providing the best comparison possible. 4 and Davila (1997) corroborate this result, reporting that obese males and females both earn significantly lower than normal-weight workers, but that lower wages for males can be attributed to obese males’ choice of occupation. Loh (1993) does not find a relationship between obesity and wages for males or females but does find that obese males pay a penalty in the growth rate of hourly wages. Looking specifically at females, Averett and Korenmann (1999) find that overweight and obese females have lower wages than their normal-weight counterparts, although the wage penalty is smaller among black females compared to whites. Recently, a subset of the literature has shifted focus from estimating the relationship between BMI and wages to identifying the possible mechanism(s) that may be driving the observed negative relationship between BMI and wages (hereafter referred to as the “wage penalty”). The most straightforward explanation for the wage penalty is that obese workers are less productive than normal-weight ones. Baum and Ford (2004) suggest that one reason for differences in productivity may be due to differences in human capital accumulation. For example, individuals with high future discount rates are both more likely to forego investment in health (and become heavier) and to invest less in training or studying that may lead to future reward. To test for this effect, the authors include an interaction between obesity and tenure. This allows average returns to experience to vary between obese and non-obese workers, which may signal the presence of myopic behavior on the part of obese workers. Using data from the 1979 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY79) the authors find that obese workers have significantly lower returns to tenure, consistent with lower human capital investment (although the authors concede it may be due to discrimination in training opportunities). 5 Atella et al. (2008) attempt to recreate this result using data from the European Household Community Panel 5 Although the tenure-interaction model renders the obesity term insignificant in Baum and Ford (2004), no subsequent study utilizing the NLSY79 has attempted to recreate these results. 5 (EHCP). Rather than tenure, obesity is interacted with an indicator variable for participation in a training program. The authors find no evidence that returns to training vary by BMI category among European workers. A second productivity-related hypothesis is that obese workers are less productive due to health limitations caused by obesity. Brunello and D’Hombres (2009) and Baum and Ford (2004) control for health using a binary indicator for “poor health” or “health limitations,” respectively, while Atella et al. (2008) use a measure of absenteeism (days of work missed in the last four work weeks due to illness). All three studies fail to find evidence that obese workers are less productive due to lower average health. Johansson et al. (2009) do find that a binary indicator for “good health” is significantly correlated with wages among Finnish workers, but inclusion of the measure only slightly attenuates the observed wage penalty for obesity. Ultimately, no supplemental control for productivity has been able to fully account for the observed wage penalty, leading researchers to consider alterative explanations. Baum and Ford (2004) and Atella et al. (2008) both hypothesize that the wage penalty remaining after attempts to control for employee productivity may be due to some form of discrimination.6 Baum and Ford (2004) test for the possibility that the penalty is due to customer discrimination (i.e. customers prefer to deal with non-obese rather than obese workers). To do so, the authors create a binary indicator signaling that an employee works in a “customeroriented” job. This indicator is interacted with obesity to determine if obese workers in 6 A third hypothesis posits that total compensation for obese employees is consistent with normal-weight employees, but that wages decrease as employers shift compensation to cover higher insurance premiums incurred by obese workers but borne by the firm. Bhattacharya and Bundorf (2009) find strong evidence for this effect in the US, but Baum and Ford (2004) find that obese American workers with employer-provided insurance actually earn more than obese workers without it. Atella et al. (2008) also fail to find evidence for the insurance hypothesis among European workers. 6 customer-oriented jobs earn lower wages than non-obese workers in the same jobs. However, the authors find no evidence for discrimination by customers. Two recent studies take this strategy a step further, finding evidence for the possibility of customer or coworker discrimination. Han, Norton, and Stearns (2009) include a set of six “interpersonal skills” (e.g. speak-signal, supervise, instruct), which are defined by the U.S. Employment Service, and which correspond to the skill deemed most critical for a given occupation. (For instance, economics professors require “instructing” skill, while non-academic economists would require “speaking-signaling” skills.) The authors interact indicators for overweight and obese with five of the six skills to test if heavier workers face different returns for a given interpersonal skill. (“Taking instructions,” presumed to be the least “social” of the job skills, serves as the reference category). The authors find that obese white and black women face significantly higher wage penalties for two of the five social skills (“serve” and “speak-signal”), but that obese Hispanic women actually earn higher wages than normal-weight women in occupations using those two skill sets. A similar approach is undertaken by Johar and Katayama (2012). The authors classify all respondents as belonging to “social” or “non-social” occupations. Social occupations are those deemed to require “authority” or “nurturance,” (e.g. management/supervision, sales, teaching, customer service). Separate models are estimated for the social and non-social occupation subsamples. The authors find that obese females face a wage penalty regardless of occupation type, but that those in social occupations face nearly double the wage penalty as those in nonsocial occupations. Obese males only face a wage penalty in social occupations, while those in nonsocial occupations do not earn less than normal-weight males. 7 Although both studies find some evidence supporting a discrimination hypothesis neither is able to discern the particular kind of discrimination occurring (customer, coworker, or supervisor). The current data include information regarding each employee’s “work group,” a group of employees that reports to the same manager. I can use this organizational information to account for peer attributes that may affect coworker discrimination, as well as the possibility of discrimination by an employee’s direct supervisor. Moreover, the data contain detailed measures of physical function, cardiovascular health, and presenteeism that allow me to test for differences in productivity between obese and non-obese workers to an unprecedented degree. 3. Econometric Model The standard approach to estimating the effect of BMI on wages is an adaptation of the classic Mincer (1974) wage model, which expresses the log of hourly wages as a linear function of a vector of control variables (X) and the independent variables of interest (overweight and obese).7,8 The relationship is described by the equation ln(Wij) = β + δ1OVERWEIGHTi + δ2OBESEi + εij (1) where OVERWEIGHTi and OBESEi refer to indicators for each of these two BMI categories, with BMI < 25 (normal weight) serving as the reference category.9 Wij refers to the hourly wage rate of individual i in work group j, and Xi is a set of standard individual-level controls outlined in Section 4.2. 7 Several studies utilize semi- or non-parametric methods to account for a nonlinear relationship between BMI and wages (Kline and Tobias 2008; Shimokawa 2008; Ruhm and Gregory, 2009; Hildebrande and Van Kerhm, 2010; Kan and Jae-Lee, 2012 ) The current paper is concerned primarily with the mechanism driving the wage penalty, rather than precise estimation of the distribution of the penalty. This is at odds with the semi- and non-parametric literature in the field, and therefore such approaches are not considered in this study. 8 A separate branch of the literature utilizes a quantile regression approach to determine if the observed relationship varies by level of income (Atella, Pace, and Vuri, 2008; Johar and Katayama, 2012). Given the homogeneity of wages and occupations within the current sample, as well as the small sample size, this method is considered inappropriate for the present analysis. 9 I omit the “underweight” category as only 5 respondents meet this definition. Therefore the normal-weight category refers to anyone with a BMI of less than 25, rather than the strict definition of individuals with a BMI between 18.5 and 25. 8 Estimates of δ = [δ1 δ2] are expected to be zero since clinical BMI classification should not be correlated with wages per se. However, the set of basic controls may omit (or fail to fully account for) factors that affect wages and are correlated with obesity, such as human capital accumulation, health, or discrimination. Therefore, estimates of δ that are significantly different from zero may indicate that ̂ is biased by one or more omitted variables. I assume that εij = γ + uij (2) where Zij is a vector of individual and group-level controls for productivity and/or discrimination that are not contained in Xi. For one or more elements of Zij, corr(OBESEi,Zij|Xi) ≠ 0 so that bias in the estimates of ̂ is attributable to some subset of Zij.10 Accounting for this possibility, the full equation of interest can be written as ln(Wij) = β + λ1OVERWEIGHTi + λ2OBESEi + γ + uij (3) The residual error uij is a stochastic shock that satisfies the assumption E[uij|Xi,Zij] = 0. It is assumed that uij may be correlated between individuals in the same group j and consequently, all models cluster standard errors at the workgroup level.11 If Zij and BMI category are correlated then including Zij in the model should correct for omitted variable bias and ̂ should be different in magnitude compared to ̂ I can determine whether a given subset of Zij accounts for a significant portion of the estimated wage-obesity relationship (̂) by testing the null hypotheses that ̂ 1 - ̂ 1 = (and the same for ̂ 2 and ̂ 2). To 10 Some omitted variables cannot be accounted for by including a specific variable (i.e. a binary proxy for discrimination) but can be tested for by allowing the relationship between ln(Wij) and Xij or Zij to vary between obese and normal-weight employees through the use of interaction terms. In the interest of notational efficiency these interactions were left out of Equation 3. 11 Due to the multilevel nature of the data, a hierarchical linear model (HLM) was considered. The HLM assumes that the variance of wages is homoscedastic within workgroups, and also that the distribution of the variance is known. The standard random effects approach loosens the assumption that the variance distribution is known but retains the assumption of within-group homoscedasticity. Clustered standard errors do not require the within-group homoscedasticity assumption. Choosing the least efficient but most general method for estimating standard errors makes hypothesis testing as conservative as possible and the reported results more robust to faulty assumptions. 9 determine whether ̂ and ̂ are significantly different I jointly estimate equations (1) and (3). I then use a Wald statistic to test the null hypothesis that ̂ and ̂ are identical.12 Rejection of this hypothesis provides evidence that a given subset of Zij is (one of) the explanatory mechanism(s) underlying the wage-obesity penalty. This approach is an adaptation of Baron and Kenny’s (1986) test for mediating effects. The key distinction is that I do not hypothesize any direction of causality between Zij and BMI category. I am not testing whether a variable mediates the wage-obesity relationship, but rather whether a given variable is correlated strongly enough with both wages and obesity to cause significant bias in the estimated obesity coefficient. Although statistical testing cannot “prove” the presence of omitted variables bias, statistical evidence, coupled with valid theoretical consideration, can make a strong case for Zij as an explanatory mechanism for the wage-obesity penalty. Elements of Zij include controls for employee productivity (human capital accumulation and health) as well as controls for peer or supervisor discrimination. These elements will be detailed in Sections 4.3 and 5.3. 4. Data 4.1 Work Family and Health Network The data were obtained from the Work, Family, and Health Network (WFHN). The WFHN was created by the National Institutes of Health (NIH) and Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) in order to study the relationship between work, family life, and health outcomes. The WFHN is comprised of four research centers, a translational coordinating center (TCC), and a data and methods coordinating center (DCC). The four research centers are the University of Minnesota, Penn State University, Harvard University in conjunction with Portland State, and Michigan State in conjunction with Purdue University. The Kaiser Permanente Center 12 Wald tests are 1 tailed with p < 0.1 as the cutoff for “significant” difference. The residuals (ej) used to estimate ̂ 2 are clustered at the work group level. For K parameters in equation (1) and L parameters in equation (3), the resulting covariance matrix for the estimates is KL x KL, accounting for correlation between X ij and Zij. 10 for Health Research serves as the TCC, and RTI International serves as the DCC. Members of the WFHN were tasked with determining the health effects of an intervention intended to: a) increase employees’ control over their work time and b) improve supervisor and coworker support for employees’ family and personal lives. Two firms were selected for intervention, one of which is an American telecommunications firm. A single cross-section of data from this firm, collected prior to the intervention, is utilized in the present study. The sample is limited to full-time, permanent (non-contractor) employees, each of whom belongs to one of 115 “work groups.”13 The J work groups are collections of employees who report to the same manager and may collaborate with each other frequently. Employees operate at one of thirteen sites, and all sites are located in one of two urban locations in two separate states.14 The average work group size in the sample is approximately 12. The average work site hosts about 58 employees. Employees are classified by the firm’s human resources (HR) department as either support personnel (e.g. tech support, project coordinators) or core personnel (those directly involved in the firm’s core business). Core personnel are further distinguished between staff and senior employees. Within the firm there are also four broad job functions. Each workgroup emphasizes or is entirely devoted to one of the four functions. Each employee in the sample is designated by HR as belonging to one of four job categories based on the function emphasized by her or his workgroup.15 13 The data do not contain any “blue collar” support personnel (e.g. custodians, security). In addition to work site indicators all models include an indicator for those who did not report a work site. 15 The distinction between core/support and job category assignment are defined for the benefit of researchers and are not official administrative divisions. However, these divisions represent real and significant differences between tasks performed and potentially the compensation that accompanies each task. Disclosure of details regarding the four job functions is prohibited. 14 11 4.2 Standard Variables Consistent with the literature, the dependent variable of interest is the natural log of hourly wages. Annual income is obtained from administrative records, and annual hours are constructed by multiplying self-reported average weekly hours by 52. Hourly wages (Wij) are the ratio of annual income to annual hours. Controls for hourly wage (Xij) include age, tenure with the firm, education, race, nativity, married/cohabitating status, number of children, job category, an indicator to differentiate between support and core employees, and indicators for state and worksite.16,17,18 Following the literature, separate models are run for males and females. Observations with missing data for BMI or salary are dropped from the sample.19 All missing observations are assumed to be missing at random (Rubin, 1976) and the observed subsample is thus representative of the full population of non-executive, white-collar employees within the firm. Due to the small sample size, extra attention is paid to outliers that may have an undue influence on the parameter estimates. As a final step I drop any observation that fulfills both of two conditions: belonging to either the top or bottom 1-percentile of BMI, and belonging to either the top or bottom 1-percentile of log hourly wages. This resulted in one additional male and two additional females being dropped, leaving a final sample of 452 men and 295 women. Summary statistics are provided in Tables 1a (females) and 1b (males). Respondents’ annual salaries average about $82,000 for females and $88,000 for males: equivalent to hourly wages of roughly $35 for females and $38 for males. The majority of the 16 The binary division between support and core workers is a qualitative distinction in job type not captured by the four job categories. The difference between staff and senior workers may reflect differences in ability or human capital accumulation and therefore this distinction is not considered until later models in Section 5.3. 17 A common strategy in wage models is to include a squared age term, but including a squared term to the specification rendered both the linear and squared term insignificant, and the linear and quadratic terms were jointly insignificant. Therefore only a linear age term was adopted in the final model. 18 Race enters the equation as a binary white/nonwhite variable. Roughly half of non-whites are Indian-Asians, while about 20% are “Other Asian”, 10% are African American, and the remainder are Pacific Islander, Native American, or “Other.” 19 See Appendix I for information regarding missing data. 12 sample has at least a four-year degree with virtually the entire remainder having some college education and only a few holding just a high school diploma.20 Employees are generally midcareer with a mean age of about 46 (minimum 26, maximum 64) and 12-15 years of experience with the current company. Roughly 25% of the sample is nonwhite, while about 32% of males and 19% of females were born abroad. Approximately 85% of males and 71% of the females are married or cohabitating, and both subsamples have slightly less than two children, on average. Both men and women have an average BMI of about 28, about 1.5 units higher than the national average, with females having a slightly higher variance. About 32% of females and 42% of males are clinically overweight (< 25 BMI < 30), while about 30% of males and 32% of females are clinically obese (BMI > 30). The proportions overweight and obese are roughly consistent with unadjusted national averages (except for the slightly high proportion of overweight males).21 Comparisons between obese and normal-weight employees indicate significant differences between the two subsamples. Compared to their normal-weight coworkers, obese females are significantly less likely to be married, nonwhite, or born abroad. The average obese female is also about three years older than her normal-weight peers, with an extra two years of tenure with the present firm. Despite the additional experience, obese females earn nearly $3 less per hour than normal-weight women, a significant difference equivalent to nearly 1/2 of a 20 Testing found no significant difference in wages between those with just a high school diploma and those with some college but no bachelor’s degree. Individuals without a bachelor’s degree do not appear to have diminished standing with the firm. Employees without a degree are more likely to be classified as senior than staff, and are represented across all four job classes. The primary difference is that employees without a degree have been with the company longer, suggesting a longer path to promotion, or the possibility that older employees were “grandfathered” in before more rigorous selection was enacted. 21 Parametric studies typically model the relationship between BMI and wages by utilizing a linear measure of BMI, possibly paired with a quadratic term, or by creating a set of categorical BMI indicator variables defined as underweight (BMI<18.5), overweight (25<BMI<30), or obese (BMI>30), with the normal range (18.5 < BMI < 25) as the reference group. Testing suggests a nonlinear relationship between wages and BMI that is best captured by the categorical measures. 13 standard deviation. However, obese females are nearly 20% less likely to have completed a 4year degree, and 10 percentage points less likely to be “senior” core personnel. Among males, obese workers actually earn significantly more than their normal-weight peers, a difference of $1.50, or about 1/5 of a standard deviation. Obese males are significantly less likely to be nonwhite or born abroad, and also significantly less likely to have finished college. Like females, obese males in the sample are roughly three years older with an additional two years of experience with the firm. 4.3 – Additional Controls for Productivity The control variables (Xij) in Section 4.2 are those that are included as standard in virtually every wage model in the wage-obesity literature. However, these controls may be insufficient to fully account for differences in productivity between obese and normal-weight workers (as evidenced by the significant wage-obesity relationship typically estimated in the literature). The WFHN data include additional controls (Zij) for employee productivity that allow me to more precisely account for differences in productivity that remain after accounting for the standard controls.22 The additional productivity measures allow me to consider the two productivity-based hypotheses introduced earlier (human capital investment and health). The first set of variables controls for possible differences in accumulation of occupation-specific human capital, i.e. skills and abilities that directly translate to the job (and which should entail a mixture of workplace experience and natural ability). Core personnel in the data are differentiated between “staff” and “senior” level workers. Senior level workers do not possess administrative authority over staff workers. Rather, senior status indicates a meaningful accumulation of human capital that has 22 Tests for discrimination rely on organizational data rather than specific variables. The approach for these methods will be outlined in Section 5.3. 14 resulted in one or more promotions. 23 Indicator variables accounting for this division should capture potential differences in human capital accumulation between obese and non-obese employees. Among both males and females roughly 60% of employees have reached senior status, and approximately 35% are staff level (with the remainder belonging to support positions). Obese females are significantly less likely to be senior-level employees, a difference of nearly 10 percentage points, although this discrepancy does not hold among males. The second set of variables contains proxies for facets of health that may affect productivity, including physical function, sleep, and cardiovascular health. The first health proxy is a comprehensive measure of physical function, rated on a scale from 0-100. This variable is constructed from nine separate questions, which assess self-reported limitations on everyday activities such as walking up stairs, carrying groceries, and bending/stooping, among others. Responses may be either “Yes, limited a lot”; “Yes, limited some” or “No, not limited at all.” The responses are transformed by the DCC (RTI, International) into a 0-100 scale based on scoring devised by the RAND Corporation. 24 A score of 100 reflects full functionality (able to run and play sports) and 0 is barely functional (health severely limits all everyday activities). Although software development is not a physically strenuous job, it is still reasonable to assume that diminished physical function may affect on-the-job performance. In general, the sample is highly functional, with average ratings over 90%. However, obese employees are significantly limited compared to their normal-weight coworkers, a difference of 10 percentage points 23 Staff may be either “Staff I” or “Staff II” and seniors as “Senior I” or “Senior II”. Therefore someone joining the firm as a Staff I would need two promotions to reach Senior I, while someone hired as a Senior I could be promoted and still appear in the data as a “Senior.” The distinction between sub-levels I and II is unavailable in the data. 24 The questions comprising the physical limitations measure are derived from the Medical Outcomes Study 36-Item Short-Form Survey (Ware and Sherbourne, 1992). Scoring from 0-100 is based on the RAND 36-Item Health Survey 1.0 (www.rand.org/health/surveys_tools/mos/mos_core_36item_scoring.html) . 15 (roughly 1 standard deviation) among females and 5 percentage points (roughly ½ a standard deviation) among males. Another way in which obesity may result in reduced productivity is if obesity substantially disrupts sleep. Obesity is significantly correlated with obstructive sleep disorder (aka “sleep apnea”), which in turn has been associated with decreased cognitive function (Engleman and Douglas, 2004; Ulfberg et al., 1996; Vgontzas et al., 1994). Although the data lack an exact measure of sleep apnea, they do contain a self-reported indicator variable for “loud snoring.” The indicator denotes positive response to the question “During the past month, have you ever snored loudly, or been told you were snoring loudly?”25 Severity of snoring has been identified as one of the primary predictors of sleep apnea among obese patients (Vgontzas et al., 1994). Therefore, controlling for loud snoring may serve as a proxy for the effect of obesity on sleep. Approximately 1/4 of females and 1/3 of males report loud snoring. Females are more likely to snore heavily by 30 percentage points, while for males the differences is 15 percentage points. The final set of health variables contains four measures of cardiovascular health including blood serum levels of C-reactive protein (CRP), a biomarker for inflammation; blood serum levels of cholesterol; blood pressure; and heart rate. 26 All four of these measures capture elements of risk for cardiovascular disease, as well as overall cardiovascular fitness. Measures of cholesterol are transformed into a ratio of total to HDL (“good”) cholesterol, a measure that is 25 This question distinguishes people who have reported snoring (but not loudly) from people who have reported “loud” snoring. Nested within the “loud snoring” indicator are respondents who have “Snorted/gasped” or “stopped breathing/struggled for breath.” These sub-measures are not considered separately due to the small number of respondents (particularly females) who suffer from these conditions. Moreover, analysis by Maislin et al. (1995) suggests that loud snoring is nearly as correlated with apnea as snorting/gasping, and more correlated with apnea than stopped breathing/struggled for breath. 26 Data for C-Reactive protein and cholesterol are missing for 7% and 13% of the sample, respectively. Several observations were also missing data on heart rate. Since these are not the variables of interest and are assumed to be missing at random, missing values were imputed using a modified regression-based EM algorithm. See Appendix 1 for details. 16 more strongly correlated with heart disease than total cholesterol or LDL (“bad”) cholesterol and that may better capture the negative lifestyle behaviors associated with BMI (Kinosian et al, 1994). Measures of both CRP and the cholesterol ratio appear to follow a lognormal distribution (and to be heteroskedastic in relation to log wages), and so these variables are transformed by the natural log before entering the model. Measures of blood pressure and heart rate refer to the mean value of three measures obtained on three separate days. The average blood pressure measure is used to construct an indicator for high blood pressure (hypertension), which refers to systolic pressure greater than 140 mmHg or diastolic pressure greater than 90 mmHg. Among both males and females, obese employees have significantly worse measures of cardiovascular health compared to their normal-weight coworkers. Obese females measure nearly one standard deviation higher for cholesterol ratio and CRP levels, and are approximately 25 percentage points more likely to have clinically high blood pressure. Females also have significantly higher heart rates, although the difference is not substantial (about 2.5 beats per minute: less than 1/5 a standard deviation). Obese males also have higher measures of inflammation and cholesterol ratio compared to normal-weight males, equal to approximately1/2 of a standard deviation. Obese males are also 25 percentage points more likely to have high blood pressure by, and have a heart rate approximately 5 bmp (1/2 standard deviation) higher than normal-weight employees. Taken together, the set of health variables suggests that obese workers are less healthy than normal-weight employees in physical function, cardiovascular health, and potentially in quality of sleep. Incorporating these measures should capture differences in productivity that are attributable to health. To account for unexplained differences in productivity that may remain, I include one additional measure of productivity. Relative presenteeism indicates workers’ self-assessment of 17 their performance relative to workers with similar jobs. This performance measure does not control for any specific hypothesized cause of differences in productivity but may serve as a general indicator for whether differences in wages are attributable to differences in productivity. The variable is reported as a ratio of an individual’s perception of their own job performance and the perceived “average” performance for somebody else with their job (each rated on a scale of 1-10, with 1 being poor performance and 10 being exemplary). The relative presenteeism measure was initially developed by the World Health Organization in order to quantify the workplace costs of health problems in terms of reduced job performance. Tests of validity show a significant and monotonic relationship between the presenteeism self-assessment and employer-based ratings (e.g. peer assessments, supervisor assessments, or work audits) among a variety of occupations (airline reservation agents, customer service representatives, automobile company executives, and railroad engineers). (Kessler, et al., 2003). Summary statistics indicate that obese females report significantly lower levels of productivity, although the difference is not substantial (equivalent to approximately 1/5 of a standard deviation). Among males obese employees do not appear to be less productive than their normal-weight coworkers, although an effect may net out conditional on other control variables. Tests for differences in productivity between obese and normal-weight workers are provided in Section 5.2. 5. Results 5.1 –Baseline Results Results from the initial model containing only standard control variables (equation 1) are reported in Table 2. Among females, overweight employees earn approximately 5.7% less than those in the normal-weight category, while obese employees earn 7.0% less, on average. Neither overweight nor obese males earn significantly different wages to their normal-weight coworkers. 18 The lack of a significant wage-obesity relationship for males is consistent with the literature, which has found mixed results regarding the BMI-wage relationship among men. The most plausible explanation is that BMI is a more imperfect measure of physical health for males, since BMI does not distinguish muscle from other body mass. It may also be the case that the wageBMI pathway operates differently for males versus females, a possibility that will be explored further in the remainder of Section 5. Tables 3a and 3b report the results of tests for the productivity hypotheses (human capital accumulation, health) among females and males, respectively. Results examining the peer and supervisor discrimination hypotheses for both males and females are reported in Table 4. For the sake of brevity, only results for obese workers relative to normal-weight workers will be reported in results tables moving forward. All subsequent models include indicators for overweight, and all interaction models include an overweight interaction term in addition to the reported obese interaction term. Results for overweight employees are qualitatively similar to those for obese ones. 5.2 – Productivity The unexplained gap in wages between obese and normal-weight employees suggests that there may be a significant difference in the average productivity of employees in each BMI category. There are two broad hypotheses that may account for this difference in productivity. The first is that normal-weight and obese workers have different levels of human capital accumulation that cannot be discerned by standard control variables. The second is that obese workers have poor health compared to normal-weight employees, which leads to missed work, or reduced productivity while at work. Tests for these two hypotheses are conducted one at a time in order to better distinguish the exact mechanism that may be biasing the obesity coefficient. Mechanisms that are found to be significantly correlated with wages are then combined to see if 19 a full model of productivity is able to completely account for the wage-obesity penalty estimated in Model (1). Controls for the human capital hypothesis enter the model in one of two ways. Consistent with Baum and Ford (2004) and Atella et al. (2008) I include an interaction between job tenure and the overweight and obesity indicators (Model 2). This allows returns to experience to vary by BMI category. The interaction coefficient allows me to test whether returns to tenure differ between obese and normal-weight workers. For the second approach, I replace the indicator for “core” jobs with two indicators differentiating between staff and senior positions (Model 3). The division between the staff and senior level provides a distinct indication of overall human capital accumulation. If obese employees accumulate human capital at a different rate than normalweight employees (or if they are discriminated against in promotion), they may be disproportionately represented at the staff level. If this is the case, controlling for the staff/senior distinction should attenuate the coefficients for the overweight and obese indicators. Model 2, which includes interactions between tenure and overweight/obese, does not provide any evidence that obese males or females receive different returns to tenure within the firm. For both males and females the tenure-interaction coefficient is insignificant, and the change in the obesity coefficient is also statistically insignificant.27 Accounting for the distinction between staff and senior employees in Model 3 fails to explain any substantial amount of wage differences between obese and normal-weight males, although both staff and senior employees earn significantly more than support personnel. Among females staff 27 To consider the total horizon of professional time, I construct a variable “potential experience” (PE) where PE = age-22 for college graduates, PE = age-20 for those with some college, and PE = age-18 for those with just a high school diploma. Replacing tenure and tenure-obesity interactions with PE and PE-obesity interactions yielded qualitatively similar results to the tenure-interaction model, albeit with coefficients slightly larger in magnitude. However, in the PE model, neither the interactions nor the overweight/obesity coefficients are significant among males or females. 20 employees do not earn significantly more than support personnel, but seniors earn roughly 23% more per hour. Inclusion of these variables decreases the magnitude of the estimated wageobesity relationship from -7.0% to -5.5%, a statistically significant reduction. This suggests that differences in human capital accumulation account for nearly 1/4 of the observed wage penalty among females. To account for the remaining wage differences I also test for three facets of health that may be biasing the estimated relationship between wages and obesity. These include physical function, sleep quality, and cardiovascular fitness. Model 4 includes a measure of physical function to determine if limitations in daily activity result in reduced productivity on the job, while Model 5 introduces an indicator for loud snoring to test whether poor sleep quality is associated with productivity. Model 6 adds measures for cholesterol ratio and C-reactive protein, as well as heart rate, and an indicator for hypertension, in order to test whether cardiovascular health may be correlated with productivity on the job. Results for the productivity models are reported in Tables 3a (females) and 3b (males). Model 4 shows that differences in productivity are not attributable to physical limitations. The measure for physical limitations is insignificantly correlated with wages, and does not change the coefficient for overweight or obese males or females. Introducing an indicator for loud snoring in Model 5 also fails to significantly alter the overweight or obese coefficients among males or females, and the coefficient on loud snoring is insignificant. Adding controls for cardiovascular health (Model 6) significantly attenuates the wage penalty for obese females but leaves a significant penalty of -5.5%. Among males controls for cardiovascular health increase the wage premium for obesity from 2.2% to 6.6%, a significant change. This suggests that obese males with average cardiovascular health are more productive than their normal- 21 weight coworkers, but that the diminished cardiovascular health that often accompanies obesity means that the average obese male is not significantly more productive than a normal-weight male. Overall, cardiovascular health seems to be a significant omitted variable among both males and females. Model 7 combines controls for cardiovascular health, loud snoring, and the indicators for staff and senior to determine if a joint model of productivity is able to explain a significant portion of the wage-obesity relationship. (Physical function and tenure-interactions are omitted due to their lack of correlation with wages). Among males the health and human capital variables essentially cancel each other out. Controlling for human capital accumulation reduces the wage premium significantly, whereas including controls for cardiovascular health significantly increases the wage premium. The net effect is a small positive increase that leaves a large but insignificant wage premium of 3.7%. For females the combined model reduces the obesity penalty from -7.0% to -3.3%, a significant reduction. Model 8, the final productivity model, controls for relative presenteeism to see if ratings of productivity on the job can account for the large remaining differences in wages between obese and normal-weight employees. Among both males and females the presenteeism measure is uncorrelated with wages, and does not alter estimates of the overweight or obesity coefficients, indicating that presenteeism is unable to account for potential remaining differences in productivity. Although the female wage penalty and male wage premium are statistically insignificant, the sign and magnitude of the estimates are not inconsistent with the previous literature, suggesting that meaningful unexplained wage differences may still exist between obese and normal-weight employees. Consistent with prior research I consider the possibility that the remaining differences in wages may be attributable to discrimination. 22 5.3 Discrimination This section utilizes three approaches to test for possible discrimination. The first two use work group-level measures to test for coworker discrimination. Work group-level measures include the proportion of obese coworkers in an employee’s workgroup, and the proportion of the work group of opposite gender in each employee’s workgroup. 28,29 Research has shown that individuals are more likely to discriminate publicly when it is considered socially acceptable to do so (Crandall, Eshelman, and O’Brien, 2002). Presumably as the proportion of obese workers in a work group increases, the acceptability of discrimination towards obese members of that work group will diminish. The proportion of work group members of the opposite gender is also hypothesized to affect the probability of discrimination. The most likely explanation is that discrimination towards obese individuals may be at least partially discrimination based on attractiveness, the social norms of which may be more likely to be applied to the opposite gender. However, the possibility that workers discriminate more against obese coworkers of the same gender is left open. The peer discrimination models include an interaction between the indicators for overweight/obese and the measures of proportion opposite gender and proportion obese. This provides a test of whether the wage penalty varies based on either workgroup characteristic. The third discrimination model utilizes workgroup fixed effects to test whether unobserved work group attributes are driving the wage penalty among obese workers. 30 Recall that each work group reports to a single manager. Therefore key unobserved work group 28 The sample mean of the workgroup characteristics is consistent with the sample mean of the characteristics themselves (i.e. the mean proportion of obese coworkers across workgroups equals the proportion of the overall sample that is obese). 29 An attempt was made to generate gender-specific obesity proportions, but there were several workgroups that had only one male or female, making this approach infeasible. 30 Hausman testing rejects the pooled model in favor of workgroup fixed effects. However, the pooled model is maintained for two reasons: first, as seen in the results, fixed effects reveal a positive rather than negative bias, suggesting that the biased pooled results are a conservative estimate. Second, the fixed effects model substantially reduces the available power making it virtually impossible to test for any of the proposed underlying mechanisms. 23 characteristics include the attributes of the manager and her or his potential attitude towards obese subordinates. The first two discrimination models should account for the primary channels through which coworker discrimination would manifest. Therefore the work group fixed effects model can be thought of as a manager fixed effects model that is able to account for direct supervisor discrimination. Results of the discrimination models are reported in Table 4. Models 9 and 10 in Table 4 show that among females there is no evidence for coworker discrimination. The proportion of male coworkers in a work group is insignificantly correlated with wages, and the coefficients on the interaction terms do not indicate that the relationship between work group gender composition and wages varies by BMI category. Controlling for the proportion of obese coworkers in one’s work group reduces the observed wage penalty to -1.5%, although this is not a significant change from the estimate in Model (8). The proportion of obese coworkers is insignificantly correlated with wages, and the coefficient for the obesity interaction is also insignificant. Moreover, the sign of the interaction coefficient for both overweight and obese employees is the opposite of the hypothesized direction. The wages for both obese and overweight females diminishes as the proportion of obese coworkers increase. Among males the proportion of females in the workgroup (Model 9) has no effect on the wage of overweight or obese males. However, as the proportion of obese workers in a group increases, the wages of overweight and obese males actually fall significantly (Model 10). In this model an obese male with no other obese group members earns a significant wage premium of approximately 10%, while obese males in a group comprised entirely of obese coworkers earn roughly the same as normal-weight males. It is unclear what is causing this result. If work groups comprised almost entirely of obese workers are less productive as a group, then higher proportions of obesity should be negatively 24 correlated with wages among normal-weight workers as well. An alternative explanation is that normal-weight workers are able to outperform more of their immediate peers if they are in a work group with a high proportion of obese coworkers. If this were the case, then overweight workers should also perform better in comparison in comparison to obese employees. However, the overweight interaction term is actually more negative than the obesity interaction for both males and females, suggesting that whatever factor is diminishing wages for heavier employees the effect is greater for overweight than obese employees. While the underlying explanation of these results is uncertain, the results do not suggest that peer-level discrimination is an issue within the sample. I turn next to the possibility of supervisor discrimination. Controlling for unobserved workgroup (manager) attributes (Model 4) increases the wage premium among obese males from 3.7% to 4.9%. The overweight coefficient has an equally substantial shift in magnitude but does not become statistically significant. Although the direction of bias from unobserved workgroup attributes is consistent with manager discrimination, it would seem contradictory for obese males to be discriminated against and still earn more than their normal-weight peers. It is possible that obese males are more productive than normal-weight males, but that the full premium earned from this productivity difference are only realized under non-discriminating managers. Controlling for work group fixed effects among female employees increases the magnitude of the wage penalty by approximately one percentage point for both overweight and obese employees. This suggests that the coefficients in the pooled work group model are positively biased - the opposite of what would be expected if manager discrimination was a dominant factor, and a result at odds with the results from the male fixed effects model. 25 The combined results of the discrimination models suggest that the wage penalty among female employees is not attributable to mistreatment at work, while obese males appear to earn a wage premium and may be subject to supervisor discrimination. The final section considers the possibility that the female wage penalty and male wage premium that remains unaccounted for may be attributable to household fertility decisions. Although this is expected to affect females more than males, males are included in the analysis for comparison of the results. 6 - Children One hypothesis that has not been previously considered in the literature is that having children is a mechanism that may both increase BMI and decrease wages. Such a mechanism would help to explain the discrepancy in wage penalty between obese males and females sometimes encountered in the literature (e.g., Cawley, 2004; Greve, 2008; Johannson, 2009; Hildebrande and Van Kern, 2010). Women have larger biological roles in pregnancy and childbirth that may affect body mass or disrupt human capital accumulation, and in the US women still handle the majority of child care responsibilities (Craig, 2006). Children are a standard control variable in the literature and therefore not the source of any omitted variables bias. What has not been accounted for is the possibility that the relationship between children and wages differs between obese and normal-weight women, or that the relationship between wages and obesity differs between mothers and non-mothers. Research has suggested that women who are obese in early adulthood are less likely to ever have children and that those who do will have fewer children than mothers who were not obese in early adulthood (Frisco and Weden, 2013; Frisco et al., 2012). Therefore measures of fertility may provide information on the timing of obesity. The timing of obesity may influence the wage-obesity relationship in ways that can be captured by this variation. To control for this 26 possibility I estimate equation (3) treating interactions between overweight/obese and the total number of children the respondent has ever had as Zij. Results are presented in Table 5. Results from Models 12 and 13 show that omitting children from the model does not have any effect on the estimated obesity coefficients for males or females. As expected, including an interaction between children and obesity (Model 14) does not produce any significant results among males. However, results from Model 14 demonstrate a significant difference in the wage-obesity relationship between obese mothers and non-mothers. Obese females appear to pay a significant penalty of over 5% for each additional child. Obese females without children no longer face any wage penalty, and may in fact earn a wage premium. This appears to be a binary distinction: including an interaction between obesity and an indicator for “any children” results in an estimated wage penalty of 9.5% for the average obese mother. These results do not hold for overweight females, who face no additional wage penalty for fertility. Moreover, overweight females without children continue to incur a wage penalty of approximately 4%, although the estimate remains insignificant. These results suggest that the timing of obesity has important implications for future wages. Females who are obese in early adulthood, at the beginning of their careers, do not seem to encounter any wage penalty relative to their normal-weight coworkers (although the current model cannot control for the ways in which early obesity may affect decisions to attend college or choice of career). However, females who do not begin their careers obese but become obese in the intervening years after having one or more children seem to bear the entire observed wage penalty in the current sample. The results also indicate that there are important underlying differences between mothers who become obese and those who do not since there is no wage penalty associated with children 27 among normal-weight mothers. The most likely explanation is that the process of becoming obese is a manifestation of unobserved differences in productivity between normal-weight and obese mothers. Females who are more efficient at work may also receive greater returns to investment in health. It may be possible that these differences between obese and normal-weight mothers manifest as differences in human capital accumulation, although accounting for the distinction between staff and senior employees cannot account for the wage penalty attributed to obese mothers. It may be the case that obese mothers are more likely to be single mothers, which may influence both body mass and productivity. However, controlling for single-motherhood (Model 15) does not significantly change the coefficient on the child-obesity interaction, suggesting that having a spouse present is not the primary factor that differentiates obese mothers from normalweight mothers. The exact mechanism underlying this result remains an issue for future research. 7. Conclusion Consistent with previous literature I find that a negative relationship exists between wages and obesity among females in the current sample, and find some evidence for a wage premium among males. To explain this result, I test for differences in productivity between obese and normal-weight employees. I find evidence that human capital investment and cardiovascular health are both key omitted variables. Controlling for these factors explains over half of the wage penalty among obese females, and actually reveals a significant wage premium among obese males. In particular, controls for cardiovascular health reduce the wage penalty among females by approximately 1.5 percentage points, and increase the wage premium among 28 males by nearly 4 percentage points. This suggests a substantial portion of productivity losses attributable to obese workers may be recoverable through appropriate health intervention. There is some evidence for supervisor discrimination among males. Accounting for unobserved work group attributes using a work group fixed-effects approach suggests that the obesity coefficient estimated in the pooled work group model is negatively biased. Among females unobserved work group characteristics positively bias the obesity coefficient from the pooled model, which calls into question whether any supervisor discrimination is occurring, or whether the negative bias in the male obesity coefficient is attributable to some other source. However, I find no evidence for peer discrimination among males or females. Subsequent analyses indicate that obese females with children are the primary recipients of the wage-penalty for obesity in the sample: obese females without children may actually earn more than normalweight women, while obese mothers incur a roughly 5% wage penalty per additional child, on average. The difference between obese mothers and obese non-mothers is likely attributable to differences in the timing of obesity: obese females with no children or fewer children are more likely to have been obese at early adulthood, whereas females with more children are likely to have become obese after having one or more child. It is uncertain why this distinction in the timing of obesity results in a wage penalty, as controls for human capital are unable to account for any of the observed difference. The wage difference between obese mothers and normal-weight mothers is likely attributable to unobserved differences in productivity. However, this discrepancy cannot be ascribed to human capital accumulation or single-parenthood.31 Uncovering the exact mechanism driving the productivity difference between obese and normal-weight females is a 31 Although without a full panel of adulthood it is impossible to account for past spells of single-motherhood that may have affected investments in health or interruptions in work experience. 29 promising avenue for future research: a better understanding of this mechanism could yield valuable information for employers or policymakers wishing to improve maternal health and well-being. These results may also inform research on women’s wages in other branches of the literature. For instance, the motherhood wage penalty established in the labor literature (see e.g. Budig and England, 2001) may fall more heavily on obese than normal-weight women. Lastly, these results may provide guidance for future wage-obesity analyses at the national level. If the frequently observed wage penalty for obese women is primarily attributable to obese mothers across region and industry, this may provide justification for public policy aimed at promoting maternal health. Such policy could help to recover some of the lost productivity and medical spending currently attributable to obesity. 30 Works Cited Aitkin, Murray and Irit Aitkin. “A Hybrid EM/Gauss-Newton Algorithm for Maximum Likelihood in Mixture Distributions.” Statistics and Computing, Vol. 6. 1996. pp.127-130. Atella, Vincenzo, Noemi Pace, and Daniela Vuri. “Are Employers Discriminating with Respect to Weight? European Evidence Using Quantile Regression.” Economics and Human Biology, Vol. 6. 2008. pp. 305-329. Baron, Reuben M and David A. Kenny. “The Moderator-Mediator Variable Distinction in Social Psychological Research: Conceptual, Strategic, and Statistical Considerations.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 51(6). 1986. pp.1173-1182. Baum, Charles II and William Ford. “The Wage Effects of Obesity: a Longitudinal Study.” Health Economics, Vol. 13. 2004. pp.885-899. Bhattacharya, Jay and M. Kate Bundorf. “The Incidence of the Healthcare Costs of Obesity.” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 28(3), 2009. pp.649-658. Bozoyan, Christiane and Tobias Wolbring. “Fat, Muscles, and Wages.” Economics and Human Biology, Vol. 9. 2011. pp.356-363. Brunello, Giorgio and Beatrice D’Hombres. “Does Body Weight Affect Wages? Evidence from Europe.” Economics and Human Biology, Vol. 5(1), 2007. pp.1-19. Budig, Michelle J. and Paula England. “The Wage Penalty for Motherhood.” American Sociological Review, Vol. 66(2). April 2001. pp. 204-225. Burkhauser, Richard V. & Cawley, John. “Beyond BMI: The Value of More Accurate Measures of Fatness and Obesity in Social Science Research.” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 27(2). 2008. pp. 519-552. Cameron, A. Colin and Pravin K. Trivedi. “Microeconomics: Methods and Applications.” Cambridge University Press, 2006. Carr, Deborah, and Michael A. Friedman. “Is Obesity Stigmatizing? Body Weight, Perceived Discrimination, and Psychological Well-Being in the United States.” Journal of Health and Social Behavior.” Vol. 46. 2005. pp.244-259. Cawley, John. “The Impact of Obesity on Wages.” The Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 39(2). Spring 2004. pp. 451-474. Craig, L. “Does Father Care Mean Fathers Share? A Comparison of How Mothers and Fathers in Intact Families Spend Time with Children.” Gender and Society, Vol. 20. 2006. pp.259-281. 31 Crandall, Christian S., Amy Eshleman, and Laurie O’Brien. “Social Norms and the Suppression of Prejudice: The Struggle for Internalization.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 82(3). March 2002. pp.359-378. Engleman, HM and NJ Douglas. “Sleep 4: Sleepiness, Cognitive Function, and Quality of Life in Obstructive Sleep Apnoea/Hypopnoea Syndrome.” Thorax, Vol. 59. pp.618-622. Finkelstein, Eric A., Olga A. Khavjoi, Hope Thompson, Justin G. Trogdon, Liping Pan, Bettylou Sherry, and William Dietz. “Obesity and Severe Obesity Forecasts Through 2030.” American Journal of Preventive Medicine. Vol.42(6). June 2012. pp.563-570. Finkelstein, Eric, Marco daCosta DiBonaventura, Somali Brgess, and Brent Hale. “The Costs of Obesity in the Workplace,” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, Vol. 52(10), October 2010. Flegal, Katherine, Margaret Carroll, Brian Kit, and Cynthia Ogden. “Prevalence of Obesity and Trends in the Distribution of Body Mass Index among US Adults, 1999-2010.” Journal of the American Medical Association, Vol. 307(5). February 1, 2012. pp.491-497. Frisco, Michelle L. and Margaret Weden. “Early Adult Obesity and U.S. Women’s Lifetime Childbearing Experiences.” Journal of Marriage and Family, Vol. 75. August 2013. pp.920-932. Frisco, Michelle L., Margaret M. Weden, Adam M. Lippert, and Kristin D. Burnett. “The Multidimensional Relationship Between Early Adult Body Weight and Women’s Childbearing Experiences.” Social Science and Medicine, Vol. 74. 2012. pp.1703-1711. Gates, Donna, Paul Succop, Bonnie Brehm, Gordon Gillespie, and Benjamin Sommers. “Obesity and Presenteeism: The Impact of Body Mass Index on Workplace Productivity.” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, Vol. 50(1). January 2008. pp.39-45. Garcia, Jaume and Climent Quintana-Domeque. “Obesity, Employment, and Wages in Europe.” The Economics of Obesity – Advances in Health Economics and Health Services Research, Vol. 17. 2007. pp. 187-217. Goetzel, Ron, et al. “A Multi-Worksite Analysis of the Relationships Among Body Mass Index, Medical Utilization, and Worker Productivity.” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, Vol. 52(1), January 2010. pp. 52-58. Greve, Jane. “Obesity and Labor Market Outcomes in Denmark.” Economics and Human Biology, Vol. 6. 2008. pp. 350-362. Han, Euna, Edward Norton, and Sally Stearns. “Weight and Wages: Fat Versus Lean Paychecks.” Health Economics, Vol. 18. 2009. pp. 535-548. 32 Hildebrand, Vincent and Philippe Van Kerm. “Body Size and Wages in Europe: A semiparametric analysis.” CEPS/INSTEAD Working Paper 2010-09, 2010. Howard, Jeffrey and Lloyd Potter. “An Assessment of the Relationships Between Overweight, Obesity, Related Chronic Conditions, and Worker Absenteeism.” Obesity Research and Clinical Practice, 2012. Johansson, Edvard, Petri Bockerman, Urpo Kiiskinen, and Markku Heliovaara. “Obesity and Labour Market Success in Finland: The Difference Between Having a High BMI and Being Fat.” Economics and Human Biology, Vol. 7. 2009. pp.36-45. Johar, Meliyanni and Hajime Katayama. “Quantile Regression Analysis of Body Mass and Wages.” Health Economics, Vol. 21. 2012. pp.597-611. Kan Kamhon and Myoung-Jae Lee. “Lose Weight for a Raise Only if Overweight: Marginal Integration for Semi-Linear Panel Models.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 27. 2012. Pp.666-685. Karasek, R., Brisson, C., Kawakami, N., Houtman, I., Bongers, P., & Amick, B. (1998). The Job Content Questionnaire (JCQ): An instrument for internationally comparative assessments of psychosocial job characteristics. Journal of Occupational Health Psychology, 3(4), 322-355. Kessler, R.C., Barber, C., Beck, A., Berglund, P., Cleary, P.D., McKenas, D., Pronk, N., Simon, G., Stang, P., Üstün, T.U., Wang, P. The World Health Organization Health and Work Performance Questionnaire (HPQ). Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, 45 (2), 2003. 156-174. Kline, Brendan and Justin Tobias. “The Wages of BMI: Bayesian Analysis of a Skewed Treatment-Reponse Model with Nonparametric Endogeneity.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 23. pp.767-793. 2008. Loh, Eng Seng. “The Economic Effects of Physical Appearance.” Social Science Quarterly, Vol. 74(2). June 1993. pp. 420-438. Lundborg, Petter, Kristain Bolin, Soren Hojgard, and Bjorn Lindgren. “Obesity and Occupational Attainment Among the 50+ of Europe.” The Economics of Obesity – Advances in Health Economics and Health Services Research, Vol. 17. 2007. pp.219251. Maislin, Greg, Allan I. Pack, Nancy B. Kribbs, Philip L. Smith, Alan R. Schwartz, Lewis R. Kline, Richard J. Schwab, and David F. Dinges. “A Survey Screen for Prediction of Apnea.” Sleep. Vol. 18(3). 1995. Pp.158-166. Mincer, Jacob A. “Schooling, Experience, and Earnings.” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 83(2). April 1975. pp.444-446. 33 Ogden, Cynthia, Margaret Carroll, Brian Kit, and Katherine Flegal. “Prevalence of Obesity in the United States, 2009-2010.” NCHS Data Brief No. 82, January 2012. Accessed from < http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/databriefs/db82.pdf> February 16, 2013. Ogden, Cynthia, Margaret Carroll, Brian Kit, and Katherine Flegal. “Obesity and Socioeconomic Status in Adults: United States, 2005-2008.” NCHS Data Brief No. 50, December 2010. Accessed from < http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/databriefs/db50.pdf> February 16,2013. Pronk, Nicolaas, Brian Martinson, Ronald Kessler, Arne Beck, Gregory Simon, and Philip Wang. “The Association Between Work Performance and Physical Activity, Cardiorespiratory Fitness, and Obesity.” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, Vol. 46(1). January 2004. pp.19-25. Register, Charles, and Donald Williams. “Wage Effects of Obesity Among Young Workers.” Social Science Quarterly, Vol. 71(1), March 1990. pp.130-141. Ricci, Judith and Elsbeth Chee. “Lost Productive Time Associated with Excess Weight in the US Workforce.” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, Vol. 47(12). December 2005. Pp.1227-1234. Rubin, D.B. “Inference and Missing Data.” Biometrika, Vol. 63. 1976. pp.581-592. Ruhm, C. J. & Gregory, C. A. (2009). "Where Does the Wage Penalty Bite.," In Press, In Michael Grossman and Naci Mojan (Ed.) Economic Aspects of Obesity. University of Chicago Press. Schafer, Markus H. and Kenneth F. Ferraro. “The Stigma of Obesity: Does Perceived Weight Discrimination Affect Identity and Physical Health.” Social Psychology Quarterly, Vol. 74(1). pp.76-97. Schmier, Jordana, Mechelle Jones, and Michael Halpern. “Cost of Obesity in the Workplace.” Scandinavian Journal of Work, Environment, and Health, Vol. 32(1). February 2006. pp. 5-11. Shimokawa, Saturo. “The Labour Market Impact of Body Weight in China: A Semiparametric Analysis.” Applied Economics, Vol. 40. 2008. pp.949-968. Tsai, Shan et al. “The Impact of Obesity on Illness Absence and Productivity in an Industrial Population of Petrochemical Workers.” Annals of Epidemiology, Vol. 18. 2008. pp. 8-14. Ulfberg, Jan, Ned Carter, Mats Talback, and Christer Edling. “Excessive Daytime Sleepiness at Work and Subjective Work Performance in the General Population and Among Heavy Snorers and Patients with Obstructive Sleep Apnea.” Chest, Vol. 110(3). September, 1996. pp.659-663. 34 Vgontzas, Alexandro N., Tjiauw L. Tan, Edward O. Bixler, Louis F. Martin, Duane Shubet, and Anthony Kales. “Sleep Apnea and Sleep Disruption in Obese Patients.” Archives of Internal Medicine, Vol. 154(15). 1994. pp.1705-1711. Wada, Roy and Erdal Tekin. “Body Composition and Wages.” Economics and Human Biology, Vol. 8. 2010. Pp.242-254. Ware, J.E. Jr. and Sherbourne, C.D. The MOS 36-item short-form health survey (SF-36). I. Conceptual framework and item selection. Medical Care, 30(6), 1992. 473-483. 35 Standard Variables (X) BMI Overweight Obese Hourly Wage Log Hourly Wage Married or Cohabitating Total Number of Children Nonwhite Born Abroad College Graduate (4-year) Age Tenure with Firm (years) Support Personnel Productivity Staff Controls Senior (Z) Physical Function Loud Snoring Presenteeism C-Reactive Proteina Cholesterol Ratiob Hypertension Heart Rate Table 1a – Summary Statistics Female Full Sample (n = 295) Obese (n = 92 ) Mean Standard Mean Standard Deviation Deviation 28.28 6.61 36.05*** 5.68 31.18% 0.46 31.18% 0.46 35.23 6.96 33.63*** 7.04 3.54 0.20 3.49*** 0.21 70.85% 0.46 54.34%*** 0.50 1.63 1.24 1.73* 1.34 24.07% 0.43 17.39%* 0.38 19.32% 0.40 8.70%*** 0.28 66.44% 0.47 55.43%*** 0.50 46.88 8.38 48.49** 7.68 16.04 9.94 17.66** 10.19 5.76% 0.23 8.70% 0.28 36.27% 0.48 38.04% 0.49 57.97% 0.49 53.26%** 0.50 92.63% 13.38 87.14*** 17.69 25.76% 0.44 40.22%*** 0.49 1.13 0.22 1.10* 0.19 3.06 4.34 5.74*** 6.24 3.87 1.09 4.17*** 1.18 31.18% 0.46 43.48%*** 0.50 72.35 11.10 73.66* 12.39 Normal Weight (n=111) Mean Standard Deviation 22.44 1.75 36.69 3.59 72.97% 1.48 27.03% 27.03% 75.68% 45.11 15.01 5.41% 32.43% 62.16% 96.00 10.82% 1.14 1.53 3.61 18.92% 71.37 6.74 0.19 0.45 1.19 0.45 0.45 0.43 9.14 9.96 0.23 0.47 0.49 7.61 0.31 0.21 2.25 0.94 0.39 10.58 Notes: a: C-Reactive Protein is measured in mg/L. For reference, CRP levels below 1.0 are considered low-risk for heart disease, 1.0-2.99 is considered average risk, and greater than 3.0 is high risk. b: A cholesterol ratio below 3.5 is considered optimal, 3.5-5 is normal, and >5 is considered high. Standard Variables (X) BMI Overweight Obese Hourly Wage Log Hourly Wage Married or Cohabitating Total Number of Children Nonwhite Born Abroad College Graduate (4-year) Age Tenure with Firm (years) Support Personnel Productivity Staff Controls Senior (Z) Physical Function Loud Snoring Presenteeism C-Reactive Proteina Cholesterol Ratiob Hypertension Heart Rate Table 1b – Summary Statistics Male Full Sample (n = 452) Obese (n = 135 ) Mean Standard Mean Standard Deviation Deviation 28.10 4.90 33.74*** 4.38 42.92% 0.50 29.87% 0.46 37.70 7.81 38.65* 8.36 3.61 0.22 3.63* 0.23 84.74% 0.36 85.93% 0.35 1.64 1.43 1.83** 1.49 29.20% 0.46 17.04%*** 0.38 31.89% 0.44 16.30%*** 0.37 83.63% 0.37 73.33%*** 0.44 45.12 8.70 46.96*** 9.04 12.07 8.16 12.60** 8.11 6.86% 0.25 4.44%* 0.21 33.41% 0.47 34.07% 0.48 59.73% 0.49 61.48% 0.49 95.28 10.21 92.96*** 12.30 32.74% 0.47 40.00%** 0.49 1.87 2.32 2.53*** 2.86 4.47 1.35 4.60** 1.11 45.35% 0.50 57.04%*** 49.69 69.75 11.33 73.40*** 11.96 1.16 0.25 1.13 0.24 Normal Weight (n=123) Mean Standard Deviation 23.04 1.55 37.16 3.60 81.30% 1.32 45.53% 47.97% 91.87% 43.24 10.82 10.47% 33.33% 56.10% 97.02 23.58% 1.04 4.31 33.33% 68.26 1.16 7.28 0.20 0.39 1.25 0.50 0.50 0.27 9.38 7.35 0.31 0.47 0.50 6.57 0.43 1.08 1.68 0.047 10.73 0.21 Notes: a: C-Reactive Protein is measured in mg/L. For reference, CRP levels below 1.0 are considered low-risk for heart disease, 1.0-2.99 is considered average risk, and greater than 3.0 is high risk. b: A cholesterol ratio below 3.5 is considered optimal, 3.5-5 is normal, and >5 is considered high. Table 2 – The Relationship Between Wages and Obesity with Standard Control Variables (Model 1) Overweight Obese Married or Cohabitating Total Number of Children Nonwhite Born Abroad College Graduate (4-year) Age Tenure with Firm (10 years) Core (Staff and Senior) Female (n = 295) -0.057* (0.030) -0.070** (0.031) 0.023 (0.035) -0.005 (0.011) -0.058* (.0230) 0.053 (0.040) 0.045 (0.027) 0.004** (0.002) -0.002 (0.019) 0.183** (0.072) Male (n = 452) -.005 (0.022) 0.031 (0.025) 0.017 (0.026) 0.005 (0.009) -0.012 (0.024) 0.046* (0.026) 0.050 (0.031) 0.004*** (0.001) 0.008 (.015) 0.248*** (0.036) Note: Dependent variable is log hourly wages. The overweight and obese coefficients report wages relative to normal-weight employees (BMI < 25). The model includes indicators for worksite, state, and job category. Standard errors in parentheses. * Significant at the 0.1 level ** Significant at the 0.05 level *** Significant at the 0.01 level Table 3a – Potential Productivity-Related Explanations for the Wage-Obesity Relationship (Females) Obese Tenure (10 years) Core (Staff and Senior) Obese x Tenure (10 yrs) Staff Senior Physical Function (10 pts) Heavy Snore Log Cholesterol Ratio Log C-Reactive Protein Hypertension Heart Rate (10 bpm) Presenteeism (2) -0.098* (0.057) -0.014 (0.027) 0.180** (0.071) 0.017 (0.032) (3) -0.055* # (0.030) -0.006 (0.017) (4) -0.071** (0.032) -0.002 (0.019) 0.182** (.073) (5) -0.064* (0.033) -0.004 (0.019) 0.181** (0.072) (6) -0.055* # (0.032) -0.002 (0.019) 0.182** (0.070) 0.093 (0.074) 0.243*** (0.075) -0.001 (0.012) -0.022 (0.027) -0.058 (0.039) -0.017* (0.010) 0.038 (0.024) 0.016** (0.008) (7) -0.035 # (0.032) -0.008 (0.016) (8) -0.035 # (0.030) -0.006 (0.016) 0.090 (0.071) 0.240*** (0.072) -0.004 (0.011) -0.030 (0.024) -0.053 (0.034) -0.019** (0.009) 0.046** (0.022) 0.016* (0.009) 0.090 (0.070) 0.241*** (0.071) -0.004 (0.011) -0.030 (0.024) -0.054 (0.035) -0.019** (0.009) 0.042* (0.022) 0.016* (0.009) -0.015 (0.057) Note: Dependent variable is log hourly wage Models control for employee’s state, site, age, race, nativity, marital status, number of children, tenure with the firm (in years), and job category, unless reported otherwise. All models also contain an indicator for overweight, and overweight is interacted with tenure in model (2). The normal-weight category therefore serves as the point of reference for all obesity and obesity-interaction coefficients. Standard errors in parentheses. # Signifies that the obesity coefficient is significantly different from the coefficient estimate in model (1). * Significant at the 0.1 level ** Significant at the 0.05 level *** Significant at the 0.01 level Table 3b – Potential Productivity-Related Explanations for the Wage-Obesity Relationship (Males) Obese Tenure (10 years) Core (Staff and Senior) Obese x Tenure (10 yrs) Staff Senior Physical Function (10 pts) Heavy Snore Log Cholesterol Ratio Log C-Reactive Protein Hypertension Heart Rate (10 bpm) Presenteeism (2) 0.031 (0.034) -0.002 (0.022) 0.250*** (0.035) 0.001 (0.026) (3) 0.012 # (0.023) -0.003 (0.013) (4) 0.032 (0.026) 0.008 (0.015) 0.247*** (0.036) (5) 0.035 (0.025) 0.008 (0.015) 0.025*** (0.036) (6) 0.066** # (0.026) 0.008 (0.015) -0.235*** (0.036) 0.147*** (0.034) 0.330*** (0.036) 0.002 (0.009) -0.027 (0.017) 0.002 (0.038) -0.027*** (0.009) -0.029 (0.018) -0.003 (0.008) (7) 0.037 (0.024) -0.002 (0.013) (8) 0.037 (0.024) -0.002 (0.013) 0.142*** (0.035) 0.322*** (0.037) -0.002 (0.009) -0.012 (0.016) 0.029 (0.033) -0.019** (0.009) -0.030* (0.017) -0.002 (0.007) 0.144*** (0.035) 0.323*** (0.036) -0.002 (0.009) -0.012 (0.015) 0.029 (0.033) -0.019** (0.009) -0.031* (0.017) -0.002 (0.007) -0.017 (0.032) Note: Dependent variable is log hourly wage. Models control for employee’s state, worksite, age, race, nativity, marital status, number of children, tenure with the firm (10 years), job category, and an indicator for core jobs, unless reported otherwise. All models also contain an indicator for overweight, and overweight is interacted with tenure in model (2). The normal-weight category therefore serves as the point of reference for all obesity and obesity-interaction coefficients. Standard errors in parentheses. # Signifies that the obesity coefficient is significantly different from coefficient estimate in model (1). * Significant at the 0.1 level ** Significant at the 0.05 level *** Significant at the 0.01 level Table 4 – Potential Discrimination Explanations for the Wage-Obesity Relationship Females Obese Proportion Opposite Gender Obese X Proportion OG (9) -0.031 (0.060) -0.060 (0.10) 0.005 (0.101) Proportion Obese Obese Proportion Opposite Gender Obese X Proportion OG Proportion Obese Obese x Proportion Obese (11) -0.067** (0.032) 0.084 (0.096) -0.066 (0.105) Obese x Proportion Obese Males (10) -0.016 (0.049) (9) (10) (11) 0.019 (0.041) -0.047 (0.51) 0.044 (0.90) 0.107** # (0.034) 0.049* (0.025) 0.159** (0.067) -0.239*** (0.087) Note: Dependent variable is log hourly wage. Models control for employees’ state, site, age, race, nativity, marital status, number of children, tenure with the firm (in years), job category, indicators for staff and senior, an indicator for loud snoring, as well as cholesterol ratio, CRP plasma concentration, hypertension, and heart rate. All models also contain an indicator for overweight, and overweight is interacted with proportion opposite gender in model (9) and proportion obese in model (10). The normal-weight category therefore serves as the point of reference for all obesity and obesity-interaction coefficients. Standard errors in parentheses. # Signifies that the obesity coefficient is significantly different from the obesity coefficient in model (7), the full productivity model. * Significant at the 0.1 level ** Significant at the 0.05 level *** Significant at the 0.01 level Table 5 – Household Fertility as a Potential Explanation for the Wage-Obesity Relationship Females Obese (12) -0.035 (0.033) Children Married 0.020 (0.030) (13) -0.033 (0.032) -0.011 (0.011) 0.030 (0.033) (14) 0.053# (0.043) 0.010 (0.014) 0.026 (0.045) -0.053*** (0.017) (15) 0.046# (0.045) 0.012 (0.014) 0.016 (0.042) -0.066*** (0.022) 0.021 (0.023) (13) 0.037 (0.024) 0.005 (0.007) -0.001 (0.024) (14) 0.031 (0.030) 0.011 (0.012) 0.001 (0.023) 0.002 (0.012) (15) 0.029 (0.031) 0.011 (0.012) 0.006 (0.026) 0.038 (0.029) -0.037 (0.028) Obese x Children Obese x Married x Children Males Obese (12) 0.039 (0.024) Children Married Obese x Children Obese x Married x Children 0.006 (0.022) Note: Models control for employee’s state, site, age, race, nativity, marital status, number of children, tenure with the firm (in years), job category, indicators for staff and senior, an indicator for loud snoring, as well as cholesterol ratio, CRP plasma concentration, hypertension, and heart rate. All models also contain an indicator for overweight, and overweight is interacted with children in models (14) and (15). The normal-weight category therefore serves as the point of reference for all obesity and obesity-interaction coefficients. Standard errors in parentheses. # signifies that the obesity coefficient differs significantly from model (13) – which is identical to model (7). Models 12 and 13 are re-runs of Model (7) – the full productivity control model - with and without a control for children. * Significant at the 0.1 level ** Significant at the 0.05 level *** Significant at the 0.01 level Appendix I – Missing and Imputed Data Reason Omitted Salary nonresponse BMI nonresponse TOTAL Omitted Observations Females 19 (5.9%) 6 (2.0%) 25 (7.9%) Males 36 (7.2%) 5 (1.1%) 41 (8.4%) Values in parentheses refer to percentage of original (full) sample dropped for each reason Observations were dropped from the analysis sample if respondents did not provide their salary or a BMI value. Nineteen females and thirty-six males failed to provide salary data. This represents approximately 6% of all females and 7% of all males. Six females and five males failed to provide their BMI. This represents 2% of females and 1% of males. Among the remainder of the control variables in Model (1) no nonresponses are recorded. The following table reports differences in means between nonrespondents and respondents. On average, non-responding females have less tenure, and are more likely to be nonwhite or foreign. Male non-respondents also have less tenure, and more likely to be nonwhite or foreign. They are also significantly younger, on average. These marginal differences do not suggest that weight or salary-level are correlated with item non-response. Summary Statistics for Observations with Omitted Data Females Males Omitted Retained Omitted Retained Married or 60.00% 70.85% 85.37% 84.74% Cohabitating (0.50) (0.46) (0.34) (0.36) Total Number of 1.52 1.63 1.61 1.64 Children (1.45) (1.24) (1.28) (1.43) Nonwhite 36.00%* 24.07% 48.78%* 29.20% (0.49) (0.43) (0.49) (0.46) Born Abroad 32.00%* 19.32% 53.65%* 31.89% (0.48) (0.40) (0.53) (0.44) College Graduate 76.00% 66.44% 88.80% 83.63% (4-year) (0.44) (0.47) (0.32) (0.37) Age 46.52 46.88 41.95* 45.12 (12.56) (8.38) (9.20) (8.70) Tenure with Firm 11.12* 16.04 8.80* 12.07 (years) (10.87) (9.94) (8.60) (8.16) Support Personnel 12.00% 5.76% 9.75% 6.86% (0.33) (0.23) (0.30) (0.25) Staff 24.00% 36.27% 29.27% 33.41% (0.44) (0.48) (0.46) (0.47) Senior 64.00% 57.97% 60.98% 59.73% (0.50) (0.49) (0.49) (0.49) * Indicates significant difference in means between omitted and retained observations. Omitted observations were left out of the sample due to missing salary, missing BMI, or because the respondent was the only responder in her/his group. C-Reactive Protein Cholesterol Ratio Heart Rate Comparison of Means Between Imputed and Reported Health Variables Females Males Imputed Non-imputed Imputed 1.65* 3.14 1.88 (2.10) (4.42) (0.84) [15] [280] [34] 3.76 3.88 4.48 (0.25) (1.15) (0.26) [30] [265] [58] 73.40 72.35 68.85 (0.43) (11.14) (3.88) [2] [293] [4] Non-imputed 1.87 (2.41) [418] 4.47 (1.44) [394] 69.76 (11.38) [448] Standard errors in parenthesis. N in brackets. * Indicates significant difference between imputed and non-imputed means. Among control variables the only item non-response occurred among biological measures that proxy for cardiovascular health. Due to the relatively high number of non-responses values were imputed for missing observations rather than dropping the entire observation from the sample. Imputation followed the modified regression-based EM algorithm detailed in Cameron and Trivedi (2006) Section 27.5 (pp. 931-932). X1 refers to control variables for observations with no missing responses. X2 indicates control variables for observations with a missing response for one of the above biological variables. There are N1 complete observations and N2 incomplete observations. The algorithm is as follows: Estimate ̂ using the N1 complete observations. Estimate 2 using only N1 complete observations. Generate N2 estimates of the missing values: ̂ MIS = X2 ̂ Estimate ̂ [ ̂ MIS] = 2( + X2[X1ʹX1]-1X2ʹ) 5. Generate adjusted values ̂ = ( ̂ -1/2 ̂ MIS) um where um is a Monte Carlo draw from the N(0, element by element multiplication. 6. Using the augment sample (y1 and ̂ )obtain a revised estimate of ̂ 7. Repeat steps 1-6 using the revised ̂ in step 1 at each iteration. 1. 2. 3. 4. 2 ) distribution and denotes Consistent with Aitkin and Aitkin (1996) this algorithm is cycled until the difference between successive log likelihood values is less than 10-5