IdahoStatesman.com, ID 12-27-07 Lotterman: Why meat, milk, grain prices are rising In economics, predicting which direction prices will move in response to changing market conditions is relatively easy. Forecasting how much they will change or estimating what proportion of a price change stems from each of several relevant factors is more difficult. Consumer food prices are rising in response to higher producer prices for grains, meat and milk. But what is causing these increases? Some point to increasing use of corn and, to a much lesser extent, soybeans, to produce biofuels. Others focus on growing demand from China and other Asian countries, where economic growth is stoking demand for better diets and industrialization is shrinking available cropland. A "weakening" dollar is yet another factor. When the dollar becomes cheaper in terms of other countries' currencies, so do U.S. exports. While new growth in U.S. farm exports is most conspicuous in Asia, Europe also remains a major customer, particularly for soybeans. A euro buys 21 percent more in value of any U.S. export than it did in December 2005. It may buy even more in 2008. As U.S. soybeans shipped to Rotterdam get cheaper, Europe buys more of them. That increases prices all the way back to the U.S. farm level. Determining which direction prices move in response to changing conditions may be obvious to economists, but curiously opaque to others. In the 1950s, government programs raised farm prices by buying up large quantities of wheat, corn, cotton and other farm products. The problem was that the government ended up storing enormous amounts of these commodities. There were few ways to dispose of such surpluses without nullifying the program's goals. A bright agricultural economist named Willard Cochrane determined that it would be cheaper and more efficient to simply pay farmers to not produce anything on some fraction of their land rather than waste valuable resources to produce grain that had no use. Existing government surplus purchase programs increased demand for farm products. Cochrane's plan reduced supply. Both actions would tend to raise farm prices. In 1960, Cochrane convinced presidential candidate John Kennedy that his idea was better than the unpopular policies of the outgoing Eisenhower administration, which were associated with Kennedy's opponent, then-Vice President Richard Nixon. Kennedy announced this new plan in a speech at a plowing contest in South Dakota. Reporters peppered JFK with questions. What would this do to food prices? one asked. Kennedy turned to Cochrane, who bluntly replied, "Well hell, it will raise them of course!" That was as obvious to economists as the sun rising in the east, but anathema to political handlers, just as it would be today. Two of Kennedy's campaign workers quickly hauled Cochrane from the room and sharply instructed him that he had to keep his mouth shut from then on. No reporter asked the obvious follow-up question, "How much will this program raise prices?" As it turned out, the answer was "not a lot." The plan was implemented and, holding all other things equal, food prices were somewhat higher than they would have been otherwise. But at the same time, improved seeds, fertilizer and other technology were boosting farm productivity so much that real food prices drifted steadily downward through the 1960s and have mostly continued to do so ever since. All three factors described above - biofuel production, economic growth in Asia and a cheap U.S. dollar - act to increase U.S. producer prices, and hence U.S. food prices. That is as clear as for Cochrane's acreage-limitation program. But the amount by which each separate factor raises prices is not obvious. Ethanol opponents, including some consumer groups and beef industry associations, argue that biofuels are driving up food prices sharply. Ethanol proponents argue the opposite. Recent studies at Iowa State University point to food price increases of just a couple of percent as a result of the increased ethanol use mandated by the latest energy bill. But other ag economists at the same school and elsewhere see larger price hikes resulting. One important factor is the length of the adjustment period. A given increase in demand has greater effects in the short run than over a longer period. So the current spike in farm and food prices need not be permanent. But the change in demand is not over. Under current policies and the energy bill President Bush signed just this week, ethanol production will continue to ramp up for years. The debate on how that will be felt at the checkout lane will last even longer.