Regulatory Improvement Act of 1997 Testimony Prepared for Presentation to Committee on Affairs U.S. Senate September 12, 1997 By Paul R. Portney, Senior Fellow and President Resources for the Future RFF is home to a diverse community of scholars dedicated to improving environmental policy and natural resource management through social sciences research. Resources for the Future provides objective and independent analysis and encourages scholars to express their individual opinions, which may differ from those of other RFF scholars, officers, and directors. 1616 P Street, NW • Washington, DC 20036 • www.rff.org • 202-328-5000 Regulatory Improvement Act of 1997 Testimony for presentation to the Committee on Governmental Affairs U.S. Senate, September 12, 1997 by Paul R. Portney, Senior Fellow and President, Resources for the Future Senators Thompson and Levin, and other distinguished members of the Committee on Government Affairs. Thank you very much for inviting me here today to testify on S.981, the Regulatory Improvement Act of 1997. Before I begin, let me say that the views I will express here today are mine and mine alone. They should not be attributed to Resources for the Future (RFF), the research organization for which I work; indeed, RFF does not take institutional positions on legislative or regulatory matters. I had the pleasure of testifying before this committee last year on the regulatory review activities of the Office of Management and Budget’s Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA). You may recall from that appearance that I have spent the better part of the last 20 years of my professional life thinking and writing about ways to improve the quality of health, safety, and especially environmental regulation in the United States. During that period I have seen many pieces of proposed legislation intended to improve federal regulation. The bill that Senators Thompson and Levin have crafted is by far the best of the lot. It successfully walks the very fine line between, on one side, requiring so little as to be vacuous and, on the other, creating so many requirements for affected agencies as to run the risk of making matters worse, not better. Before I go in to my specific observations about S.981, let me make two prior observations about regulation in general. The first has to do with the economic significance of regulation in the United States today. According to OIRA’s recent and very good report on the annual costs and benefits of regulations, we spend nearly $300 billion each year in this country in pursuit of environmental protection and a variety of other safeguards for consumers and workers. Since this amounts to more than $1,000 per person per year in the U.S., it is well worth being sure both that we are choosing the least expensive means of accomplishing our regulatory objectives, and also that we are pursuing only those objectives that we believe do more good than harm. There is compelling evidence, incidentally, that a number of regulatory programs—including some major ones such as the 1970 amendments to the Clean Air Act—do generate benefits well in excess of their costs. It is worth scrutinizing regulation more carefully so that we might one day say confidently that that is true of all major programs. My second observation deals with generic regulatory reform legislation, such as S.981, as a means of ensuring that environmental, safety, and health rules pass a qualitative, judgmental benefit-cost test. While useful and appropriate, such bills are simply no substitute for amending those sections of the underlying enabling statutes that spell out how our federal regulators are to set standards. If I may be blunt, it is hypocritical for legislators to lambaste the Administrator of the Environmental Protection Agency for setting National Ambient Air Quality Standards for ozone and fine particulate matter that (in the eyes of the critics) fail a benefit-cost test unless these same legislators try to change Section 109 of the Clean Air Act to make such balancing a legal requirement. While such an effort would be politically difficult (to say the least), it is by far the best way to ensure reasoned and cost-effective regulation for environmental, health, and safety purposes. Let me now turn my attention to specific provisions of S.981. Although one seldom discovers grist for comment in the "Findings" section of proposed legislation, that is not the case with S.981. In particular, paragraph (2) of Section 2 states that "…[costbenefit analysis and risk assessment] do not replace the need for good judgment and consideration of values" in formulating rules. This is exactly right, and the most we can do in regulatory reform bills like S.981 is to encourage decisionmakers to make informed use of cost-benefit analysis and quantitative risk assessment in forming their considered judgments about what to do. To put the matter in a more familiar and colloquial form, cost-benefit analysis is one of several decision tools, not a necessary and sufficient decision rule. I am similarly quite supportive of the language you have carefully chosen in Section 621 (3), where you suggest that benefits and costs should only be "…quantified to the extent feasible and appropriate and otherwise qualitatively described…" I think of myself as being a very strong advocate of cost-benefit analysis in environmental regulation, for instance. Yet I have no idea how I might confidently assign a dollar value to the reduced risk of a birth defect that might result from a regulation, or—for that matter—to the opportunity costs arising from a regulation that discourages the development of new consumer products. As a regulator, however, I ought to have to spell out carefully in qualitative terms—as S.981 would require me to do—the nature of these nonquantifiable and/or nonmonetizable effects, as well as the role they played in my decisionmaking. Let me turn now to the requirement in Section 623(b)(2)(iv) that agencies evaluate the benefits and costs not only of the approach they choose, but also of a "reasonable number of reasonable alternatives." Although this provision has attracted less attention than those pertaining to benefit-cost analysis, I believe it is a "sleeper" in S.981 that has the potential to do a great deal of good. If agencies take this requirement seriously—more seriously, incidentally, than they have comparable provisions in a series of presidential executive orders going back to the mid-1970s—we might be able to shave off a chunk of the nearly $300 billion OIRA estimates we spend each year on environmental, health, and safety regulation. More importantly, we could do so without compromising the benefits we get from regulations in these areas. Imagine for a moment that the savings possible from innovative approaches are only 10 percent. (I say "only" because virtually every careful study of regulation suggests that the savings from nontraditional approaches to regulation, including information provision, taxes, marketable permits, deposit-refund schemes, etc., are significantly larger.) Even a cynical public ought to warm to a $30 billion "free lunch" each year that does not compromise the quality of their environment or the safety of the food and other products they consume each year. Why do agencies not currently jump at such cost-effective alternatives? There are several reasons. First, bureaucratic inertia often pushes them to "do it the way we’ve always done it." Yet the fact that an alternative approach may, at least initially, mean more work for the agency ought not prevent the agency from trying it if it would save large sums of money for individual, corporate, or state and local government regulatees. In some cases, however, the agency has little or no choice but to pursue the more expensive route to the same goal because the enabling statute requires a technology-based standard or some other kind of prescriptive approach. In such cases, and they are not infrequent, it is up to Congress to amend the statutes to encourage rather than prohibit creative alternative approaches. There, S.981—if taken seriously by the agencies and by Congress—will call attention to the inefficiencies, illuminate the price we are paying for them, and with luck, lead to their eventual elimination. This would be no small feat, indeed, and would not involve you or the agencies in the messier (though still important) questions about the balance between benefits and costs. One last word on this subject. Those interested in real-world proof of the costsaving potential of alternative approaches need look no farther than the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments, specifically the cap-and-trade program put in place there to control sulfur dioxide emissions from coal-fired electricity power plants. Taking this route instead of requiring all affected plants to install flue gas desulfurization equipment will eventually save rate payers as much as $4 billion annually, I estimate, or more than 50 percent of the price tag for unenlightened command-and-control. In some respects, to be fair, sulfur dioxide control from power plants represented an ideal opportunity for innovative regulation. But there are now and will be countless other potential applications; I believe S.981 can help make these a reality. If I might now, let me speak to several criticisms that have been leveled against S.981, beginning with one directed at the "advisory committees" that would be established under Section 632(a)(1)(A) to make recommendations to the agencies about existing rules to be considered for possible modification. The concern expressed is that those with a possible financial stake in agency rules will be allowed to participate in such advisory groups unless they fail to disclose these possible conflicts. My response takes two forms. First, it is literally impossible to find any citizen of the United States who has no financial stake in regulation, since all of the benefits and all of the costs ultimately accrue to individuals. Interestingly, and perhaps subtly, each member of an environmental advocacy group bears his or her share of the $300 billion in annual regulatory compliance costs as a consumer of gasoline, a use of electricity, a purchaser of consumer products, and finally, as a shareholder (generally through retirement plans) in U.S. companies. Similarly, every employee of a regulated firm benefits in important ways from federal regulation, as do their children, since they breathe the air, consume drinking water, and use consumer products. Thus, it is not as easy as it may seem to determine who is disinterested and who is not, or even which way their sympathies lie. I am not sure how one would go about divining which conflicts were so remote as to be trivial and which are not. What some critics want, of course, is for no employee of a regulated firm to participate on these advisory councils. But I have served on countless committees of the National Academy of Sciences, and participated in the deliberations of the Executive Committee of EPA’s Science Advisory Board, alongside businessmen and women who were as committed to environmental protection as any of the other members, including academics and environmental advocates. So long as all prospective members of the proposed advisory councils are open about their interests, financial and otherwise, I see no reason whatsoever why these councils cannot be useful in suggesting rules that might be ripe for review. I foresee, incidentally, many opportunities for public interest advocates to propose the review of long-standing rules where accumulated scientific or economic evidence suggests a possible tightening of existing standards. Let me deal more briefly with several other criticisms that have been raised in regard to S.981. First, with respect to the claim that S.981 will force agencies to do a lot of new work that will bog them down and slow rulemaking, I am puzzled. There is very little that S.981 asks of regulatory agencies that they are not required to do under Executive Order 12866. If they are not complying with the executive order, of course, S.981 imposes new burdens on them—but burdens that are well worth imposing. But most agencies take this executive order seriously, I believe, and hence will not be taxed anew by the requirements of S.981. Similarly, I have trouble understanding the claim that S.981 is a "supermandate" in sheep’s clothing; that is, that it would "trump" statutes that are currently interpreted as prohibiting benefit-cost comparisons. In fact, it seems quite clear to me that this is not the case. Were I a regulator, for instance, I would have no trouble whatsoever explaining that I had issued a rule for which the benefits were less than the costs because I was regulating under a statute that prohibited me from considering costs. Similarly, where the law requires technology-based standards, I could easily see myself explaining that I had no choice under the law but to issue a standard that was not as cost-effective as another for the simple reason that I was following statutory dictates. Current and future regulators will find this similarly easy. Finally, let me address the legitimate concerns some have expressed about judicial review. First, it seems to me that this would be limited under S.981 to whether or not an agency complied with the requirements to conduct such an analysis, but this should be made clear if that is not the case. Secondly, I am torn as to whether courts ought to be able to overturn rules based on the contents of the accompanying analysis. On the one hand, courts should—and do, generally—give great deference to the views of the agency to which rulemaking responsibility has been delegated. On the other hand (and to concoct an admittedly far-fetched example), if an agency head decided that it was worth $1 billion to society to spare a single pigeon, I would want a panel of judges to be able to question the appropriateness of such a determination. I hope today’s hearing will clarify the scope of judicial review intended in S.981. To summarize, S.981 will add statutory weight to the requirements imposed by the last four presidents—two Republicans and two Democrats—concerning regulatory analysis. This bill avoids the excesses of earlier regulatory reform legislation, while retaining the best features of previous bills. It should strengthen future rules and ensure that the many environmental, safety, and health safeguards these rules provide are had as inexpensively as possible. Thank you again for inviting me to appear here today. I will be happy to answer any questions you may have.