R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Review draft, 5 June 2003. Do not cite without author’s permission. Toward Cost Buydown Via Learning-By-Doing For Environmental Energy Technologies Robert H. Williams Princeton Environmental Institute Princeton University Workshop on Learning-by-Doing in Energy Technologies Resources for the Future Washington, DC 17-18 June, 2003 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Review draft, 5 June 2003. Do not cite without author’s permission. INTRODUCTION There is growing interest in use of learning and experience curves for understanding better the prospects for realizing cost reductions for innovative energy technologies (Cody and Tiedje, 1992: Williams and Terzian, 1993; Goldemberg, 1996; Wene, Voß, and Fried, 2000; Lipman and Sperling, 2000; Wene, 2000; Williams, 2002; McDonald and Schrattenholzer, 2001; Duke, 2002; Rubin et al., 2003; Riahi et al., 2003). Learning curves describe the relationship between cumulative production and labor costs for a given product manufactured by a specific firm. A 1936 study of airplane manufacturing (Wright, 1936) first introduced formal learning curve analysis showing that manufac-turing experience facilitates worker skill improvements and that benefits increase in a regular manner with cumulative production—which serves as a proxy for the stock of worker skill improvements achieved in this process (Argote and Epple, 1990). Arrow called the process “learning by doing” (LBD) in a seminal paper introducing the concept to economics (Arrow, 1962). It has been observed that for many products over long periods of time the cost of producing a unit of a product is related to its cumulative production by the learning-by-doing equation y = ax-b, where: x = cost of producing the next unit of a product, y = cumulative production of the product, a = constant coefficient, b = learning rate exponent. The learning rate exponent is usually presented in a progress ratio PR = (100*2-b) or learning rate LR = 100*(1 – 2-b). For LR = 20% (PR = 80%), b = 0.3219. During the 1970s, the Boston Consulting Group (BCG) introduced experience curves that generalize the labor productivity learning curve (Boston Consulting Group, 1972). The BCG presented evidence that its clients benefited from a predictable percentage reduction in overall costs associated with each doubling of cumulative production. That implies learning-by-doing not only in the narrow sense of labor productivity improvements but from all conceivable opportunities for cost reduction, including technological improvement via the fruits of R&D, input substitution, economies of scale, new product design, and changing input prices. Typically, experience curves are presented in terms of product prices, which are readily observable, instead of costs, which are not. Dutton and Thomas (1984) compiles over 100 firm-level experience curve studies from a variety of manufacturing sectors, finding a mean LR ~ 20% (~ PR = 80%). When innovations spill over among competing firms, an experience curve can be estimated for cumulative industrial output that represents the weighted average of the experience curves for the industry’s individual firms. Cody and Tiedje (1992) points out that highly competitive industries that make major investments in R&D tend to be characterized by high learning rates, while more mature industries that invest little in R&D tend to be characterized by low learning rates. R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. Experience curves for some energy technologies are shown in Figure 1. More generally, LRs are in the range 5-25% with each doubling of cumulative output for energy (McDonald and Schrattenholzer, 2001). Use of an experience curve model for which cumulative production is the main explanatory variable for estimating cost reductions for energy technology that also certainly reflect other important ongoing processes besides labor productivity improvement is appealing in its simplicity. But this model lacks a sound theoretical basis. However, Duke (2002) suggests why both R&D and scale economy impacts (two especially important cost reduction determinants that complement labor productivity improvement) might roughly be captured by the cumulative production index. Regarding R&D, he points out that a key part of the new technology deployment process is R&D carried out by the firm, the cost of which tends to be proportional to sales revenues (Jenen and Black, 1983); and, at least in the United States, government support for industrial R&D is typically cost-shared. Thus, it is plausible that during the deployment period for new technologies, cumulative total R&D investments are roughly proportional to cumulative production. Duke (2002) also argues that production scale cannot be considered independently of experience: “there are…sharp limits on the ability of any firm to reduce costs through dramatic scaleup without first working out the kinks in intermediate scale manufacturing facilities. Learning-by-doing is therefore an integral part of the process of ramping up production (Wene, 2000).” Such considerations suggest the importance of new research aimed at better understanding the causality of cost reduction associated with energy technological innovation, especially the robustness of the parsimonious experience model in which cumulative production is the key explanatory variable for predicting cost reductions. USING EXPERIENCE CURVES Despite the tight data fits for many experience curves (see, for example, Figures 1 and 2), caution should be exercised in using industrial experience curves to make forecasts, especially long-term forecasts, because so many variables are involved, and there can be no assurance that historical trends will persist. Figure 1 shows, for example, that as gas turbine technology became more mature, its learning rate fell from the earlier 20% to about half that value after 1963. One might try to use experience curves to estimate the cost of “buying down” the price of a system to a target level where the technology would be widely competitive in many energy markets. But there are dangers involved in such uses of experience curves. Consider for example, the buy-down cost (shaded area) in Figure 2 for reducing the retail selling price for PV modules from the 2003 level of $3.9/Wpeak to $1/Wpeak—a level at which PV technology is likely to be competitive in many mass energy markets. If the historical average LR (19.7%/y) were to persist, the required cumulative PV production and the associated buydown cost would be 170 GWpeak (5% of total global electric generating capacity) and $70 billion, respectively. But if the LR were 2 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. reduced to 15%/y or increased1 to 25%/y the buydown cost would be increased by more than 3fold or reduced by more than half, respectively.2 Another way the buydown effort might be lightened is if the PV market would come to be dominated by thin-film technologies that require far less photovoltaically active materials than crystalline silicon systems. At present thin-film technologies are characterized by about the same production cost as the dominant crystalline silicon PV modules, but the cumulative production level to date is only about 0.1 as large. If thin film PV were to advance from this point forward at the same historical LR as for crystalline silicon PV (19.7%/y), which is a plausible outcome (Payne et al., 2000; Duke, 2002), the required cumulative production and buydown cost would be 17 GW and $7 billion, respectively. Nevertheless, experience curves can be helpful in improving understanding of the effort required to reach targeted or long-term price levels for innovative energy technologies. One approach to improve confidence that near- to mid-term (10 – 20 year) prices are not underestimated is to combine experience curve analysis with detailed technology assessments of manufacturing costs under mass production conditions; the effort required to get to such cost levels can then be explored as a function of the learning rate—see, for example, Lipman and Sperling (2000) in the case of PEM fuel cells for cars. Or, one might want to take a longer term perspective and “guesstimate” floor prices that reflect ultimate material price constraints and minimal manufacturing costs,3 as Duke (2002) has done for PV technology. A key issue is the influence of energy technology scale on the utility of experience curves. The energy LBD survey analysis of McDonald and Schrattenholzer (2001) indicates generally higher LRs characteristic of more modular systems amenable to mass production in factories4 and lower LRs characteristic of large field-erected power plants5 for which standardized designs are more difficult to realize. However, our energy system is dominated by large-scale energy systems at present, so it is desirable to ascertain if impacts of LBD can be economically important despite the generally low LRs that seem to characterize large-scale technologies. Recent experience curve analyses (Rubin, 2003; Riahi, 2003) to assess LBD benefits in mitigating climate change via CO2 capture and storage (CCS) technologies for fossil fuels suggest the importance of LBD even if LRs are inherently slow for large-scale technologies. 1 The BCG also gave many examples of industry-wide experience curves in which learning rates increase as the industry matures. 2 For LR = 15%, the required cumulative PV production and the associated buydown cost would be 760 GWpeak and $225 billion, respectively. For LR = 25%, the required cumulative PV production and the associated buydown cost to reach a $1/Wpeak price would be 61 GWpeak and $30 billion, respectively. 3 In general such an exercise is frought with uncertainty. However, for thin-film PV technologies [the technologies explored in Duke (2002)] the uncertainties are probably much less than for many other future technologies because the photovoltaically active materials represent a tiny fraction of materials costs, which are dominated by costs for common materials [e.g., substrate (e.g., glass or thin-rolled steel), wires, etc.] from mature industries. A key parameter is the module efficiency, which determines the amount of electric power extractable from a m2 of module in sunlight and can be projected largely on the basis of considerations of the physics of thin films. 4 E.g., a learning rate of 20% (R2 = 0.99) for global sales of PV modules, 1968-1998 [module prices ($/Wpeak) vs cumulative capacity sold (MWpeak] and 16% (R2 = 0.66) for compact fluorescent lamp sales in the United States, 1992-1998 [$/lumen vs. cumulative units sold]. 5 E.g., learning rates of 1.4% (R2 = 0.89), 5.8% R2 = 0.95), and 7.6% (R2 = 0.90), for hydroelectric, nuclear, and coal power plants, respectively, in OECD countries during 1975-1993 [specific investment cost ($/kWe) vs cumulative capacity (MWe)]. 3 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. Consider that if society should eventually seek to stabilize atmospheric CO2 at some level in the range 450 – 550 ppmv, many zero- and low-CO2 emitting options will have to be pursued simultaneously, including fossil fuel decarbonization via CO2 capture and storage (CCS) as well as renewables. Although renewables (esp. wind and PV) hold great promise for climate change mitigation in the electricity sector (Williams, 2002), their potential for reducing GHG emissions at relatively low costs in energy markets that use fuels directly (other than for electricity generation) is limited. If underground storage of CO2 proves to be a viable option in large-scale applications, CCS will be an important, low-cost climate mitigation option for markets that use fuels used directly.6 Although most of the component technologies needed for CCS are well established in the refining and chemical process industries, few costs for integrated systems are available in the public domain, because hardly any integrated systems have been built. However, Rubin et al. (2003) presents a detailed LBD analysis for flue gas desulfurization and selective catalytic reduction, for which LRs for the specific investment costs ($/kWe) were found to be 11% and 12%, respectively. This analysis was followed up with an extrapolation to CCS technologies, assuming alternative average LRs of 0%/y and 12%/y for CCS technologies deployed for electricity generation, H2 production, and carbon-based synthetic fuels production in runs of the IIASA MESSAGE-MACRO integrated assessment model to explore impacts of constraining the A2 scenario of the IPCC’s Special Report on Emissions Scenarios (Nakicenovic, 2000) so as to reduce the atmospheric CO2 concentration in 2100 from 783 ppmv for the A2 scenario (existing base case) to 550 ppmv (new GHG emissions-constrained variant). To accomplish this, CCS technologies were introduced and their costs were considered both without and with LBD. The modeling exercise found that the total amount of CO2 stored by 2100 would be twice as much with LBD as without, and that the required carbon tax would be reduced from $25/tC to $19/tC by 2020 and from $82/tC to $27/tC by 2050 (Riahi et al., 2003). Despite this example suggesting the importance of experience in realizing cost reductions for large-scale technologies, care should be exercised in extending learning curves blindly to all large-scale energy technologies. Consider nuclear power, for which experience has often led to cost increases rather than cost reductions. In the early 1970s Fisher (1974) raised concerns about rising costs of nuclear power with experience,7 pointing out that for many decades plant construction in the power industry followed a pattern in which part of the construction (mainly the building and the boiler) was carried out in the field and part (manufacture of the turbine, generator, and power conditioning equipment) was carried out in large factories serving many 6 Markets that use fuels directly account for about 2/3 of global CO2 emissions—a fraction that is not likely to decline much in the future, despite the expected continuing trend toward electrification of the global energy economy (Williams, 2003). 7 “When measured in constant dollars per kilowatt of capacity, the cost of constructing a nuclear power plant increased by perhaps 50 percent in the last decade…When power plant costs rises an explanation is required, as we expect all power plant costs to decline through the economies of scale and new technology. The environmental movement was responsible for part of the rise in nuclear plant costs, by causing various procedural delays and by requiring additional safeguards to protect against hypothetical accidents. But there appears to be another cause for increasing construction costs, associated with a growing portion of high-cost field construction and a shrinking proportion of low-cost factory construction for the very large power plants now being built…The costs associated with a shift to field from factory can more than offset anticipated economies of scale….” 4 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. power plants. As electric generating capacity doubled every decade, factory capacity also doubled, as did field construction at each site. Manufacturing and construction costs per kWe declined both at the factory and in the field along with these scale increases. As long as both activities grew in proportion, the economies of scale produced similar percentage cost reductions in each, and therefore overall cost reductions, even though the unit cost of field construction was higher than that for factory construction. This pattern held until plant size reached about 200 MWe and resulted in a good fit of the US average electricity price to a 75% experience curve during most of the period up to 1970 (Williams and Terzian, 1993). This trend was upset, however, with the introduction of nuclear power. Because of the requirement for shielding and containment and other features specific to nuclear power, nuclear plants were expected to be more capital-intensive than fossil fuel plants of the same capacity. Because such costs account for a smaller fraction of total costs at larger plant sizes, it was reasoned that nuclear plants should be built larger. Accordingly, nuclear plants were built in the early 1970s to sizes of the order of 1000 MWe. But building such large plants requires shifting a large fraction of total construction from the factory to less economically-efficient field sites, thereby raising costs. Fisher’s important insight is that economies of scale in power generation are constrained by the empirical facts that (i) field construction is inherently more costly than factory construction, and (ii) with field construction, it is much more difficult to advance along experience curves, in contrast to the situation with factory construction. Although no nuclear power plants have been ordered in the United States since 1974 as a result of both widespread public opposition to nuclear power and skepticism about its economic prospects in the investment community, the nuclear power industry flourished under central planning conditions throughout much of the last quarter of the 20th century in France. There standardized nuclear power plant designs were introduced in an attempt to control costs, but plant sizes grew to ~ 1300 MWe, despite Fisher’s prescient early warnings about the economic pitfalls of large plants. Installed nuclear capacity grew rapidly in France, from 1.8 GWe in 1977 to 65.2 GWe in 2000. Yet, despite the favorable conditions for nurturing nuclear power, specific costs ($/kWe) increased in this period (see Figure 3).8 An important research issue is to ascertain the causes of this “negative learning”—whether it reflects merely misjudgments about scale economies or whether nuclear technology issues were also to blame. BUYDOWN SUBSIDIES FOR ENVIRONMENTAL ENERGY TECHNOLOGIES Perhaps the most important potential use of energy technology experience curves is as an analytical tool that can be used in conjunction with government programs that help buy down the costs of new energy technologies offering promise in dealing with environmental and energy supply insecurity challenges—as an important complement to government support for research and development (R&D) for such technologies. Experience curves can be used both to help shape such technology commercialization programs and in monitoring cost performance in the field. 8 These data for France stand in sharp contrast to the 5.8% LR for OECD countries, 1975-93, reported in McDonald and Schrattenholzer (2001). The latter is especially difficult to understand in light of the fact that nuclear costs also rose in the US during this period, the fact that France and the US together accounted for ~ 60% of OECD nuclear power generation in that period, and the likelihood that nuclear industrial activities in France and the US affected nuclear construction activities in other OECD countries during that period. 5 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. Addressing effectively the multiple environmental and energy insecurity challenges posed by conventional energy while providing affordable energy, especially to meet the economic aspirations of developing countries, will require a major speeding up the rate of technological innovation worldwide for energy technologies that offer promise in addressing sustainable development objectives (PCAST Energy R&D Panel, 1997; PCAST Panel on International Cooperation in ERD3, 1999; UNDP, UN DESA, and WEC, 2000; Williams, 2001a). Climate change seems to be the most daunting challenge. Avoiding “dangerous anthropogenic interference” with the climate system might require stabilizing atmospheric CO2 in the range 450 – 550 ppmv (O’Neill and Oppenheimer, 2002). Achieving such a goal would require reducing CO2 emissions from the energy system relative to a BAU future (the IPCC’s IS92a scenario) 3065% by mid-century and 70-90% by 2100 (Hoffert et al., 1998). However, external costs associated with air pollution (especially health impacts of small particle air pollution) and oil supply insecurity might well have comparable values (see, for example, Rabl and Spadaro, 2000; Ogden, Williams, and Larson, 2003). The needed technological innovation requires substantial government support for both energy R&D and for commercialization (technology cost buydown). The economic case for government support for R&D is familiar: the private firm will invest in R&D less than the optimal amount from a societal perspective because the firm cannot appropriate the full benefits of such long-term investments, which are needed to spur technological innovation, the single most important contributor to long-term economic growth. In the case of energy, there is compelling evidence that government R&D support should be increased substantially (PCAST Energy R&D Panel, 1997; Margolis and Kammen, 2000). There are some scattered government programs promoting energy technology commercialization but there is no integrated framework or analytical rationale for such programs, which are often lampooned as “corporate welfare.” Indeed, a widely held view is that the government’s role in the energy technological innovation process should end with R&D. One reason for supporting energy technology commercialization is to compensate for the fact that there are damages associated with climate change, air pollution, and energy supply insecurity are not internalized in market prices for energy. But even with full internalization of such damage costs it would be desirable for government to subsidize commercialization of promising energy technologies because of a significant positive externality: a private firm that invests in technology cost buydown via LBD runs the risk that the fruits of its investments will spill over to its competitors (Duke and Kammen, 1999; Duke, 2002). When new technologies are introduced into markets, their costs tend to be higher than the costs of the technologies they would displace. Early investments are needed to “buy down” the costs of new technologies along their experience curves to levels at which the technologies can be widely competitive. In principle, a firm introducing a new technology should consider experience effects when deciding how much to produce and consequently to “forward-price”: that is, it should initially sell at a loss to gain market share and thereby maximize profit over the entire production period. In the real world, however, the benefits of a firm’s production 6 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. experience spill over to its competitors, so that the producing firm will forward-price less than the optimal amount from a societal perspective; that phenomenon provides a powerful rationale for public-sector support of technology cost buy-downs (Duke and Kammen, 1999; Duke, 2002). Still another rationale for government support of technology cost buydown activities relates to technology lock-in and lock-out (Cowan, 2000). The LBD phenomenon can impart a powerful market advantage to technologies that are launched first in the market (lock-in), making it difficult for alternative technologies to catch up (lock-out), even if they have superior attributes and better long-term economic prospects. Buy-down support for a portfolio of technologies would help minimize the risks of technology lock-in/lock-out and in the process enhance the prospects for good economic returns on earlier government R&D investments in the alternatives. Duke (2002) develops a methodology for estimating the NPV of the net benefits of government investments in technology cost buydowns and has shown that in principle, in order to maximize social welfare, government support for buydowns should persist for qualifying technologies not just to the point of breakeven with competing technologies but all the way to the (ultimate) price floor for such technologies. The high costs of commercialization activities compared to R&D and the general scarcity of public-sector resources dictate that public-sector investments in such innovative activities be prioritized. Duke (2002) also formulates a set of criteria for technology choice aimed at maximizing NPV of such investments [see Duke (2002) for details]: • • • • • There is high LBD spillover; The technology has begun to sell in commercial niche markets and emerging data suggest a reliably steep experience curve while technology assessment projects a low price floor; Niche markets have proven insufficient to pull prices down rapidly, but at lower prices demand is price elastic such that buydown subsidies can open up large markets; Based on the preceding criteria, no other technology (including both incumbent and emerging substitutes) has better long-term prospects in the relevant market segments; The targeted technology produces strong public benefits not related to private underinvestment in LBD—e.g., major environmental benefits. If government is to subsidize the energy technology cost buydown process, it would necessarily have to try to “pick winners”—a prospect that makes many policy analysts uncomfortable. But because of the paucity of experience with truly radical clean technologies, public-sector decision-makers are unlikely to be less prescient than those in the private sector (Baumol, 1995). An appropriate strategy for dealing with the winner-picking concern is to support a portfolio of technologies that satisfy the formal selection criteria and offer great promise in addressing societal goals relating to environment and energy supply security—thus reducing the overall buy-down program performance risk through diversification. The activity would have to be carried out in a manner that minimizes the potential for evolving political pork barrel projects such as present grain ethanol subsidies. Duke (2002) suggests the establishment of an Energy Commercialization Policy Agency (ECPA) where teams of technologists, economists, and scientists would: • provide energy technology assessment advice to policymakers regarding candidate technologies for buydown support; 7 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. • • monitor and evaluate field performance of technologies being subsidized; and provide advice on periodic reallocation of subsidy resources in light of such monitoring/evaluations. An EPCA should be independent of the DOE or any other agency that is promoting advanced technologies that might become candidates for government buydown support. And the analysis carried out by an EPCA should be subject to rigorous external review by academics and managers with generic expertise in technology commercialization but no particular attachment to the technologies in question. Establishment of a criteria-based energy technology cost buydown activity would represent a major change in US energy technology innovation policy, which has focused on R&D (however inadequately), and there are many uncertainties as to how to proceed…but it is difficult to imagine how the major 21st century challenges posed by conventional energy can be addressed effectively without extending R&D policy to address the formidable technology commercialization issues as well. Although the basic thrust of such a policy would represent a major departure from the status quo, implementation could be advanced with relatively minor modifications of promising policy instruments that have already been tested. POLICY INSTRUMENTS FOR BUYDOWNS Although there has been no strong analytical framework for government policy relating to subsidies for technology commercialization, much experience has been accumulated as to the efficacy and efficiency of alternative instruments that can be used to subsidize energy technology commercialization. To illustrate the utility of this experience, a brief discussion of how a Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS) or Green Certificate Market (GCM) as it is known in Europe, might be modified and used in the power sector as a buydown instrument…only one of many possible alternative instruments that might be adapted to technology cost buydown support. The RPS or GCM is emerging as an instrument of choice in many parts of the world for encouraging the commercialization of new renewable energy technologies (see Box A). One of the main attractions of this instrument is its use of market forces to allocate subsidy resources for qualifying technologies. Another is that by specifying the quantity of supply to be subsidized over time, renewable-energy developers are given the confidence to launch projects—assuring them stable revenue streams and facilitating access to low-cost financing. Specifying the quantity of the technology to be subsidized would also be helpful in a climate-mitigation policy framed around an atmospheric CO2 stabilization target (e.g., 500 ppmv). A concern about subsidy programs that fix the quantity of technology to be subsidized is that a priori the cost is very uncertain—a concern that has led many to favor subsidy programs that specify instead the magnitude of the subsidy…but with this approach the quantity of the technology subsidized is very uncertain. In the embryonic Texas RPS, which is regarded as one of the best formulated RPS programs (Wiser, 2001), the two approaches are combined in that a 5 cents/kWh noncompliance penalty caps the cost of the program. 8 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. Box A: Renewable Portfolio Standard An RPS or GCM requires that each electricity provider include in its supply mix a small but growing fraction of renewables. Companies can either produce renewable electricity or purchase renewable energy credits (RECs or, in Europe, "green certificates") in a credit-trading market. Several industrialized countries have introduced or are developing national RPS/GCM initiatives. China intends to explore the implementation of an RPS under its 10th Five-Year Plan (Jacard, Chen, and Li, 2001). Ten U.S. states have implemented an RPS, often in conjunction with electricity-market-restructuring initiatives, and, in recent years, a federal RPS has been considered in various Congressional bills. If it is to be used as a technology cost buydown instrument it would be desirable to redesign an RPS to support a portfolio of qualifying technologies—perhaps by establishing separate tranches for the different qualifying technologies. Those who are apprehensive about entrusting the government to “pick winners” insist that an RPS should be technologically blind except for the “renewables” requirement and that the market should determine which technologies win the largess of the subsidy. But there are serious problems with this approach as a buydown instrument. At the most fundamental level, different technologies are at different stages on their development paths at any one time. Less mature technologies can often make significant nearterm contributions in niche markets [rooftop PV systems for new houses will soon be competitive at the retail level (Payne, Duke, and Williams, 2000), for example]. A technologically blind policy would tend to neglect such opportunities and give all or most of the available subsidy to the technology (wind, for example) that has advanced furthest along its experience curve. In effect, a “technology blind” policy might end up picking a single winner. Also, some technologies that might be competitive under a technology-blind policy have limited overall potential (biogas and landfill gas come to mind), so that the leveraging effect of the subsidy would be modest. An RPS might eventually be extended to cover technological options other than renewables that satisfy the selection criteria—e.g., an extension to fossil fuel power generating systems with CO2 capture and storage, after underground CO2 storage has been sufficiently demonstrated to be viable as a major clean energy option. TOWARD EARLY ACTION FOR BUYDOWNS Although radical technological change for energy technology is required to address effectively the major environmental and energy supply insecurity posed by conventional energy, laboratory advances are not needed before moving ahead with major new efforts. Much can be accomplished with commercially ready new technologies that are too costly to make major inroads in the energy economy today but are strong candidates for technology cost buydown support—e.g., in the case of renewables: intermittent wind power, baseload wind power (e.g., via wind/compressed air energy storage hybrids), and PV for residential rooftop applications (Cavallo, 1995; Payne, Duke, and Williams, 2001; Williams, 2002); and, in the case of fossil fuels: integrated gasification combined cycle technology, which is a key stepping stone to lowcost CO2 capture and storage technology for coal (Williams, 2003; Foster Wheeler, 2003). Also, experience to date has highlighted promising policy instruments that might be used for 9 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. buydown, although experimentation with alternative approaches is desirable to find out what works best with different classes of technologies and perhaps in different regions as well. Such buydown activity should go hand in hand with a reinvigoration of the energy R&D enterprise, and the two activities would be mutually reinforcing: increased R&D would facilitate sustaining high learning rates, and market growth as a result of buydown success would catalyze increased R&D investments by the firms involved. Early buydown action offers the potential for increasing social welfare as a result of speeding up the approach to the ultimate floor prices for the technologies supported (Duke, 2002), while generating substantial and energy security and environmental benefits—not the least of which would be a significant increase in the chances of realizing the goal set forth in the Article 2 of the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change: “to…achieve stabilization of greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere at a level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system…” REFERENCES Argote, L. and D. Epple (1990). “Learning curves in manufacturing.” Science 247: 920-924. Arrow, K., 1962: The economic implications of learning by doing, Review of Economic Studies, 29: 166-170. Baumol, W., 1995: Environmental industries with substantial start-up costs as contributors to trade competitiveness, Annual Review of Energy and Environment, 20: 71–81, 1995. Boston Consulting Group, 1972: Perspectives on Experience, Boston. Cody, G. D. and T. Tiedje, 1992: The potential for utility scale photovoltaic technology in the developed world: 1990-2010, Energy and the Environment, B. Abeles, A. J. Jacobson and P. Sheng. Singapore, World Scientific. Cohen, L. R. and R. G. Noll, 1991: The Technology Pork Barrel, The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC. Cowan, R., 1999: Learning curves and technology policy: on technology competitions, lock-in and entrenchment, in Experience Curves for Policy Making: the case of energy technologies, C.O. Wene, A. VoB and T. Fired, eds., Proceedings of the IEA International Workshop at Stuttgart, Germany, 10-11 May, 1999, International Energy Agency. David, J., and H. Herzog, 2000: The cost of carbon capture. In Proceedings of the Fifth International Conference on Greenhouse Gas Control Technologies, D.J. Williams, R.A. Durie, P. McMullan, C.A.J. Paulson, and A.Y. Smith, eds., CSIRO Publishing, Collingwood, Victoria, Australia, pp. 985-990. 10 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. Dooley, J.J., and P.J. Runci, 1999: Adopting A Long View to Energy R&D and Global Climate Change, PNNL-12115, Battelle Northwest National Laboratory Report Prepared for the Panel on International Cooperation in Energy Research, Development, Demonstration, and Deployment, of the President’s Committee of Advisors on Science and Technology, Office of Science and Technology Policy, The White House, Washington, DC, February. Foster Wheeler Energy Ltd., 2003: Potential for Improvement in Gasification Combined Cycle Power Generation with CO2 Capture, IEA Greenhouse Gas R&D Programme, UK. Duke, R. D. and D. M. Kammen, 1999: The Economics of energy mrket transformation initiatives, The Energy Journal, 4: 15-64. Duke, R.D., 2002: Clean Energy Technology Buydowns: Economic Theory, Analytic Tools, and the Photovoltaics Case, PhD. dissertation, Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs, Princeton University, November. Dutton, J. M. and A. Thomas, 1984: Treating progress functions as a managerial opportunity, Academy of Management Review, 9(2): 235-247. Fisher, J.C., 1994: Energy Crises in Perspective, Wiley, New York. Girard, P. (Commissariat à l’Energie Atomique), Marignac, Y. (WISE-Paris), and Tassart, J. (La Commission Française du Développment Durable), Le Parc Nucléaire Actuel, Mission d’évaluation économique de la filière nucléaire, March. Foster Wheeler, 2003: Potential for improvement in gasification combined cycle power generation with CO2 capture, IEA Greenhouse Gas R&D Programme. Agency. Goldemberg, J., 1996: The evolution of ethanol costs in Brazil, Energy Policy, 24(12): 1127 -1128. Hoffert, M.I., K. Caldeira, A.K. Jain, E.F. Haites, L.D.D. Harvey, S.D. Potter, M.E. Schlessinger, S.H. Schneider, R.G. Watts, T.M.L. Wigley, and D.J. Wuebbles, 1998: Energy implications of future stabilization of atmospheric CO2 content, Nature, 395, 881-884. Jacard, M., H. Chen, and J. Li, 2001: Renewable portfolio standard: A tool for environmental policy in the Chinese electricity sector, Energy for Sustainable Development, V (4): 111–119. Jelen, F. C. and J. H. Black, 1983: Cost and Optimization Engineering. New York, Mc-GrawHill Book Company. Nakicenovic, N. (Coordinating Lead Author) et al., 2000: Special Report on Emissions Scenarios, prepared by Working Group III of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. 11 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. Lipman,T.E., and D. Sperling, 2000: Forecasting the costs of automotive PEM fuel cell systems—using bounded manufacturing progress functions, in Experience Curves for Policy Making: the Case of Energy Technologies, Proceedings of the IEA International Workshop at Stuttgart, Germany, 10-11 May, 1999, Wene, C.-O., A. Voß, and T. Fried, eds., International Energy Agency, April, ISSN 0938-1228. Margolis, R., and D.M. Kammen, 1999: Evidence of under-investment in energy R&D in the United States and the impact of federal policy, Science, 285: 690-692, 30 July. Mattson, N. and C.-O. Wene, 1997: Assessing new energy technologies using an energy system model with endogenized experience curves, International Journal of Energy Research, 21: 385-393. McDonald, A. and L. Schrattenholzer, 2001: Learning rates for energy technologies, Energy Policy, 29: 255-261. Nakicenovic, N., A. Grübler, and A. MacDonald, 1998: Global Energy Perspectives, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K. Ogden, J.M., R.H. Williams, and E.D. Larson, 2003: Societal lifecycle costs of cars with alternative fuels/engines, Energy Policy (in press). O’Neill, B.C., and M. Oppenheimer, 2002: Dangerous climate impacts and the Kyoto Protocol. Science, 296, 1971-1972. Payne, A., R. Duke, and R.H. Williams, 2001: “Accelerating Residential PV Expansion: Supply Analysis for Competitive Electricity Markets,” Energy Policy, 29: 787-800. PCAST Energy R&D Panel, 1997: Federal Energy Research & Development for the Challenges of the 21st Century Report of the Energy R&D Panel, The President’s Committee of Advisors on Science and Technology, November 1997. Available on the World-Wide Web at http://www.whitehouse.gov/WH/EOP/OSTP/html/ISTP_Home.html. PCAST Panel on International Cooperation in ERD3, 1999: Powerful Partnerships: the Federal Energy Research & Development for the Challenges of the 21st Century Report of the Panel on International Cooperation in Energy Research, Development, Demonstration, and Deployment of the President’s Committee of Advisors on Science and Technology, June 1999. Available on the World-Wide Web at http://www.whitehouse.gov/WH/EOP/OSTP/html/ISTP_Home.html. Pope, C., et al., 1995: Particulate air pollution as a predictor of mortality in a prospective study of U.S. adults, American Journal of Respiratory and Critical Care Medicine, 151(3): 669-674. Rabl, A. and J. V. Spadaro, 2000: Public health impact of air pollution and implications for the energy system, Annual Review of Energy and the Environment, 25: 601-627. 12 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. Riahi, K., E.S. Rubin, M. Taylor, L. Schtrattenholzer, and D. Hounshell, 2003: Technological learning for carbon capture and sequestration technologies, Energy Economics (in press). Wiser, R., and O. Langniss, 2001: The Renewables Portfolio Standard in Texas: An Early Assessment, a Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory report prepared for the Office of Power Technologies of the U.S. Department of Energy, LBNL-49107, November 2001. Rubin, S.S., M.R. Taylor, S. Yeh, and S.A. Hounshell, 2003: Learning curves for environmental technologies and their importance for climate policy analysis, Energy, the International Journal (in press). UNDP (United Nations Development Programme), UN DESA (United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs), and WEC (World Energy Council), 2000: World Energy Assessment: Energy the Challenge of Sustainability, (a study sponsored jointly by the United Nations Development Programme, the United Nations Department of Social and Economic Affairs, and the World Energy Council), published by the Bureau for Development Policy, United Nations Development Programme, New York, 508 pp. Wene, C.-O., 2000: Experience Curves for Technology Policy, International Energy Agency, OECD, Paris. Wene, C.-O., A. Voß, and T. Fried, eds., 2000: Experience Curves for Policy Making: the Case of Energy Technologies, eds., Proceedings of the IEA International Workshop at Stuttgart, Germany, 10-11 May, 1999, International Energy Agency, April, ISSN 0938-1228. Williams, R. and G. Terzian, 1993: A benefit/cost analysis of accelerated development of photovoltaic technology, CEES/PU Report No. 281, Center for Energy and Environmental Studies, Princeton University, October. Williams, R.H., 2001a: Addressing challenges to sustainable development with innovative energy technologies in a competitive electric industry, Energy for Sustainable Development, V (2): 48-73, June. Willams, R.H., 2001b: Toward zero emissions from coal in China, Energy for Sustainable Development, V(4): 39-65, December. Williams, R.H., 2002: Facilitating widespread deployment of wind and photovoltaic technologies, pp. 19-30, 2001 Annual Report of the Energy Foundation (available at www.ef.org). Williams, R.H., 2003: Decarbonized fossil energy carriers and their energy technological competitors, pp. 119-135, in Proceedings of the Workshop on Carbon Capture and Storage of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Regina, Saskatchewan, Canada, 18-21 November 2002. Wright, P., 1936: Factors affecting the cost of airplanes, Journal of Aeronautical Science, 1: 122128, February. 13 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. 20000 1983 RD&D phase 1981 Photovoltaics (learning rate ~ 20%) Commercialization phase 10000 US(1990)$/kW 5000 2000 USA Japan 1992 1995 Windmills (USA) (learning rate ~ 20%) 1982 1000 1987 500 1963 Gas turbines (USA) 1980 (learning rate ~ 20%, ~10%) 200 100 10 100 1000 10000 100000 Cumulative MW installed Figure 1: Experience curves for photovoltaics, wind generators, and gas turbines These curves illustrate the well-established phenomenon that, for new technological products amenable to the economies of mass production, prices tend to decline with cumulative production. Source: Nakicenovic, Grübler, and MacDonald (1998). 14 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. 100 All-PV Retail Price 1976-2000 Learning Rate = 20% 2003: 2.3 GWp, $3.90/Wp $70 billion buydown 2000$/W p 10 Thin-film only Learning rate = 20% 0.23 GWp & $3.90/Wp in 2003 $7 billion buydown 1 0.1 00.1 1 10 100 1,000 10,000 100,000 1,000,000 cumulative MWp Figure 2: Costs of buying down crystalline silicon and a-Si:H modules to $1.0/Wp, from equal price levels in 2003 This figure shows projections of retail PV module prices based on both the historical PV experience curve for all PV technologies (dominated by experience with crystalline PV technologies) and a postulated a-Si:H curve assumed to have the same progress ratio and initial module price in 2003. Buy-down is defined here as the total incremental expenditure required to reduce module prices from their initial values to the $1.0/Wp target price, without taking credit for niche market opportunities that would reduce the buy-down cost considerably. The module prices in the historical PV experience curve are the wholesale prices augmented by a 20 percent retail mark-up. Source: Williams (2002), based on analysis in Payne, Duke, and Williams (2001). Other PV experience curve analyses can be found in Cody and Tiedje (1992), Williams and Terzian (1993), and Duke (2002). 15 R.H. Williams, “Toward cost buydown via learning-by-doing for environmental energy technologies.” Do not cite without author’s permission. S pe cific inv estm ent c ost (19 98 FF /k W) 11000 65.7 GW , 2000 10000 9000 25.5 GW , 1983 1.8 GW , 1977 43.7 G W , 1986 8000 7000 1 10 100 Installed nuclear capacity (G W) Figure 3: Specific investment cost for nuclear power in France vs cumulative installed nuclear capacity Calculations (preliminary) carried out by Arnulf Grübler (International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria) based on data presented in Girard, Marignac, and Tassart (2000). Cost data for nuclear power plants are total investment costs at project completion (including interest during construction. Individual project completion data have been smoothed with 3-year running averages. Note that the specific investment cost in 2000 = FF1998 10,570/kWe = $1998 1790/kWe (@ 1998 average exchange rate) = $2002 1920/kWe (using US GDP deflator). Source: Private communication from Arnulf Grübler, June 2003. 16