INTERNATIONAL POLICY CENTER Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy University of Michigan IPC Policy Briefs Series Number 3 An Assessment of the Economic Effects of the Menu of U.S. Trade Policies Kozo Kiyota Robert M. Stern Global Economy Journal Volume 5, Issue 4 2005 Article 22 P ERSPECTIVES ON THE WTO D OHA D EVELOPMENT AGENDA M ULTILATERAL T RADE N EGOTIATIONS An Assessment of the Economic Effects of the Menu of U.S. Trade Policies Kozo Kiyota∗ ∗ † Robert M. Stern† Yokohama National University, kiyota@ynu.ac.jp University of Michigan, rmstern@umich.edu c Copyright 2005 by the authors. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of the publisher, bepress, which has been given certain exclusive rights by the author. Global Economy Journal is produced by Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress). http://www.bepress.com/gej An Assessment of the Economic Effects of the Menu of U.S. Trade Policies Kozo Kiyota and Robert M. Stern Abstract The Michigan Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Model of World Production and Trade is used to calculate the aggregate welfare and sectoral employment effects of the menu of U.S. trade policies. The menu of policies encompasses the various preferential U.S. bilateral and regional free trade agreements (FTAs) negotiated and in process, unilateral removal of existing trade barriers, and global (multilateral) free trade. The welfare impacts of the FTAs on the United States are shown to be rather small in absolute and relative terms. The sectoral employment effects are also generally small but vary across the individual sectors depending on the patterns of the bilateral liberalization. The welfare effects on the FTA partner countries are mostly positive though generally small, but there are some indications of potentially disruptive employment shifts in some partner countries. There are indications of trade diversion and detrimental welfare effects on nonmember countries for some of the FTAs analyzed. In comparison to the welfare gains from the U.S. FTAs, the gains from both unilateral trade liberalization by the United States and the FTA partners and from global (multilateral) free trade are shown to be rather substantial and more uniformly positive for all countries in the global trading system. The U.S. FTAs are based on “hub” and “spoke” arrangements. It is shown that the spokes emanate out in different and often overlapping directions, suggesting that the complex of bilateral FTAs may create distortions of the global trading system, which could be avoided if multilateral liberalization in the context of the Doha Round were to be carried out. Kozo Kiyota is Associate Professor of International Economics in the Faculty of Business Administration, Yokohama National University. He is also a Research Fellow at the Manufacturing Management Research Center (MMRC), the University of Tokyo and a Faculty Fellow at the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). He received his Ph.D. from Keio University, Tokyo, Japan. His research focuses on empirical microeconomics. He has published articles in the International Journal of Industrial Organization, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, and The World Economy. Robert M. Stern is Professor of Economics and Public Policy (Emeritus) in the Department of Economics and Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy, University of Michigan. KEYWORDS: WTO, Doha, trade policy Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies INTRODUCTION In this article, we present a computational analysis of the economic effects of the menu of U.S. trade policies. The menu encompasses the various U.S. bilateral and regional free trade agreements (FTAs) that have been negotiated in recent years and the negotiations currently in process, unilateral removal of existing trade barriers by the United States and its FTA partner countries, and global (multilateral) free trade. The analysis is based on the Michigan Model of World Production and Trade. The Michigan Model is a multi-country/multisector computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of the global trading system that has been used for over three decades to analyze the economic effects of multilateral, regional, and bilateral trade negotiations and a variety of other changes in trade and related policies. In Section II following, we present a brief description of the main features and data of the Michigan Model. The results of the computational analysis of the U.S. FTAs are presented in Section III. In Section IV, we consider the crosscountry patterns of the welfare effects of the various FTAs. In Section V, we provide a broader perspective on the FTAs that takes into account the effects of the unilateral and multilateral removal of trade barriers by the United States and its FTA partner countries, and other countries/regions in the global trading system. Section VI provides a summary and concluding remarks. THE MICHIGAN MODEL OF WORLD PRODUCTION AND TRADE OVERVIEW OF THE MICHIGAN MODEL The version of the Michigan Model that we use in this article covers 18 economic sectors, including agriculture, manufactures, and services, in each of 22 countries/regions. The distinguishing feature of the Michigan Model is that it incorporates some aspects of trade with imperfect competition, including increasing returns to scale, monopolistic competition, and product variety. A complete description of the formal structure and equations of the model can be found on line at www.Fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/model/. INTERPRETING THE MODELING RESULTS To help the reader interpret the modeling results, it is useful to review the features of the model that serve to identify the various economic effects to be reflected in the different applications of the model. Although the model includes the aforementioned features of imperfect competition, it remains the case that markets respond to trade liberalization in much the same way that they would Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 1 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 with perfect competition. That is, when tariffs or other trade barriers are reduced in a sector, domestic buyers (both final and intermediate) substitute toward imports and the domestic competing industry contracts production while foreign exporters expand. Thus, in the case of multilateral liberalization that reduces tariffs and other trade barriers simultaneously in most sectors and countries, each country’s industries share in both of these effects, expanding or contracting depending primarily on whether their protection is reduced more or less than in other sectors and countries. Worldwide, these changes cause increased international demand for all sectors. World prices increase most for those sectors where trade barriers fall the most. This in turn causes changes in countries’ terms of trade that can be positive or negative. Those countries that are net exporters of goods with the greatest degree of liberalization will experience increases in their terms of trade, as the world prices of their exports rise relative to their imports. The reverse occurs for net exporters in industries where liberalization is slight—perhaps because it may already have taken place in previous trade rounds. The effects on the welfare of countries arise from a mixture of these terms-of-trade effects, together with the standard efficiency gains from trade and also from additional benefits due to the realization of economies of scale. Thus, we expect on average that the world will gain from multilateral liberalization, as resources are reallocated to those sectors in each country where there is a comparative advantage. In the absence of terms-of-trade effects, these efficiency gains should raise national welfare measured by the equivalent variation for every country,1 although some factor owners within a country may lose, as will be noted below. However, it is possible for a particular country whose net imports are concentrated in sectors with the greatest liberalization to lose overall, if the worsening of its terms of trade swamps these efficiency gains. On the other hand, although trade with imperfect competition is perhaps best known for introducing reasons why countries may lose from trade, actually its greatest contribution is to expand the list of reasons for gains from trade. Thus, in the Michigan Model, trade liberalization permits all countries to expand their export sectors at the same time that all sectors compete more closely with a larger number of competing varieties from abroad. As a result, countries as a whole gain from lower costs due to increasing returns to scale, lower monopoly distortions due to greater competition, and reduced costs and/or increased utility due to greater product variety. All of these effects make it more likely that 1 The equivalent variation is a measure of the amount of income that would have to be given or taken away from an economy before a change in policy in order to leave the economy as well off as it would be after the policy change has taken place. If the equivalent variation is positive, it is indicative of an improvement in economic welfare resulting from the policy change. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 2 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies countries will gain from liberalization in ways that are shared across the entire population.2 The various effects just described in the context of multilateral trade liberalization will also take place when there is unilateral trade liberalization, although these effects will depend on the magnitudes of the liberalization in relation to the patterns of trade and the price and output responses involved between the liberalizing country and its trading partners. Similarly, many of the effects described will take place with the formation of bilateral or regional FTAs. But in these cases, there may be trade creation and positive effects on the economic welfare of FTA-member countries together with trade diversion and negative effects on the economic welfare of non-member countries. The net effects on economic welfare for individual countries and globally will thus depend on the economic circumstances and policy changes implemented. In the real world, all of the various effects occur over time, some of them more quickly than others. However, the Michigan Model is static in the sense that it is based upon a single set of equilibrium conditions rather than relationships that vary over time. The model results therefore refer to a time horizon that depends on the assumptions made about which variables do and do not adjust to changing market conditions, and on the short- or long-run nature of these adjustments. Because the supply and demand elasticities used in the model reflect relatively long-run adjustments and it is assumed that markets for both labor and capital clear within countries,3 the modeling results are appropriate for a relatively long time horizon of several years—perhaps two or three at a minimum. On the other hand, the model does not allow for the very long-run adjustments that could occur through capital accumulation, population growth, and technological change. The modeling results should therefore be interpreted as being superimposed upon longer-run growth paths of the economies involved. To the extent that these growth paths themselves may be influenced by trade liberalization, therefore, the model does not capture such effects. 2 In perfectly competitive trade models such as the Heckscher-Ohlin Model, one expects countries as a whole to gain from trade, but the owners of one factor—the “scarce factor”—to lose through the mechanism first explored by Stolper and Samuelson (1941). The additional sources of gain from trade due to increasing returns to scale, competition, and product variety, however, are shared across factors, and we routinely find in our CGE modeling that both labor and capital gain from multilateral trade liberalization. 3 The analysis in the model assumes throughout that the aggregate, economy-wide, level of employment is held constant in each country. The effects of trade liberalization are therefore not permitted to change any country's overall rates of employment or unemployment. This assumption is made because overall employment is determined by macroeconomic forces and policies that are not contained in the model and would not themselves be included in a negotiated trade agreement. The focus instead is on the composition of employment across sectors as determined by the microeconomic interactions of supply and demand resulting from the liberalization of trade. Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 3 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 BENCHMARK DATA Needless to say, the data needs of this model are immense. Apart from numerous share parameters, the model requires various types of elasticity measures. Like other CGE models, most of our data come from published sources. The main data source used in the model is “The GTAP-6.0 Database” of the Purdue University Center for Global Trade Analysis Project, as adapted from Dimaranan and McDougall (2005). The reference year for this GTAP database is 2001. From this source, we have extracted the following data, aggregated to our sectors and countries/regions:4 • Bilateral trade flows among 22 countries/regions, decomposed into 18 sectors. Trade with the rest-of-world (ROW) is included to close the model. • Input-output tables for the 22 countries/regions, excluding ROW • Components of final demand along with sectoral contributions for the 22 countries/regions, excluding ROW • Gross value of output and value added at the sectoral level for the 22 countries/regions, excluding ROW • Bilateral import tariffs by sector among the 22 countries/regions • Elasticity of substitution between capital and labor by sector • Bilateral export-tax equivalents among the 22 countries/regions, decomposed into 18 sectors The monopolistically competitive market structure in the nonagricultural sectors of the model imposes an additional data requirement of the numbers of firms at the sectoral level, and there is need also for estimates of sectoral employment.5 The employment data, which have been adapted from a variety of published sources, will be noted in tables below. The GTAP-6.0 database has been projected to the year 2005, which is when the Uruguay Round liberalization will have been fully implemented. In this connection, we extrapolated the labor availability in different countries/regions by an average weighted population growth rate of 1.2 percent per annum. All other major variables have been projected, using an average weighted growth rate of GDP of 2.5 percent.6 The 2005 data have been adjusted to take into account two major developments that have occurred in the global trading system since the mid-1990s. These include: (1) implementation of the Uruguay Round 4 Details on the sectoral and country/region aggregation are available from the authors on request. Notes on the construction of the data on the number of firms and for employment are available from the authors on request. 6 The underlying data are drawn from World Bank sources and are available on request. For a more elaborate and detailed procedure for calculating year 2005 projections, see Hertel and Martin (2000) and Hertel (2000). 5 http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 4 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies negotiations that were completed in 1993-94 and were to be phased in over the following decade; and (2) the accession of Mainland China and Taiwan to the WTO in 2001.7 We have made allowance for the foregoing developments by readjusting the 2005 scaled-up database for benchmarking purposes to obtain an approximate picture of what the world may be expected to look like in 2005.8 In the computational scenarios to be presented below, we use these re-adjusted data as the starting point to carry out our liberalization scenarios for the U.S. bilateral FTAs and for the accompanying unilateral and global free trade scenarios. The GTAP 6.0 (2001) base data for tariffs and the estimated tariff equivalents of services barriers are broken down by sector on a global basis and bilaterally for existing and prospective FTA partners of the United States in Table 1. The post-Uruguay Round tariff rates on agriculture, mining, and manufactures are applied rates and are calculated in GTAP by dividing tariff revenues by the value of imports by sector. The services barriers are based on financial data on average gross (pricecost) margins constructed initially by Hoekman (2000) and adapted for modeling purposes in Brown, Deardorff, and Stern (2002). The gross operating margins are calculated as the differences between total revenues and total operating costs. Some of these differences are presumably attributable to fixed costs. Given that the gross operating margins vary across countries, a portion of the margin can also be attributed to barriers to FDI. For this purpose, a benchmark is set for each sector in relation to the country with the smallest gross operating margin, on the assumption that operations in the benchmark country can be considered to be freely open to foreign firms. The excess in any other country above this lowest benchmark is then taken to be due to barriers to establishment by foreign firms. That is, the barrier is modeled as the cost-increase attributable to an increase in fixed cost borne by multinational corporations attempting to establish an enterprise locally in a host country. This abstracts from the possibility that fixed costs may differ among firms because of variations in market size, distance from headquarters, and other factors. It is further assumed that this cost increase can be 7 The tariff data for the WTO accession of China and Taiwan have been adapted from Ianchovichina and Martin (2004). In addition to benchmarking the effects of the Uruguay Round and China/Taiwan accession to the WTO, Francois et al. (2005) benchmark their GTAP dataset to take into account the enlargement of the European Union (EU) in 2004 to include ten new member countries from Central and Eastern Europe and some changes in the EU Common Agricultural Policies that were introduced in 2000. Our EU and EFTA regional aggregate includes the 25member EU, but the benchmark data were not adjusted to take into account the adoption of the EU common external tariffs by the new members. Because of data constraints, we have not made allowance for the Information Technology Agreement and agreements for liberalization of financial and telecommunication services following conclusion of the Uruguay Round. 8 See Anderson and Martin (2005), who use a model developed at the World Bank that benchmarks their GTAP 6.0 data to 2015 for computational purposes. Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 5 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 interpreted as an ad valorem equivalent tariff on services transactions generally. It can be seen in Table 1 that the constructed services barriers are considerably higher than the import barriers on manufactures. While possibly subject to overstatement, it is generally acknowledged that many services sectors are highly regulated and thus restrain international services transactions. For the United States, the highest import tariffs for manufactures are recorded for textiles, wearing apparel, and leather products & footwear, both globally and bilaterally. The values and shares of U.S. exports and imports are broken down by sector according to origin and destination in Tables 2-3 on a global basis as well as for FTA partners. Employment by sector is indicated for the United States and its FTA partners in Table 4. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 6 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies Table 1. Post-Uruguay Round Tariff Rates by Sector for the United States (Percent) Global Singapore Australia Morocco SACU Thailand Korea Canada FTAA Chile South America Agriculture 0.9 0.1 1.2 0.1 1.2 0.4 0.4 0.0 0.4 0.9 0.0 2.2 Mining 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Food, Beverages & Tobacco 2.0 1.2 1.7 3.2 3.8 1.4 4.7 0.0 3.0 1.4 0.0 2.1 Textiles 5.5 9.3 6.6 7.1 6.3 8.7 10.6 0.0 6.8 11.4 0.0 7.7 Wearing Apparel 10.0 13.8 10.8 10.5 12.1 13.6 13.8 0.0 10.7 11.5 0.0 12.7 Leather Products & Footwear 7.3 5.6 4.1 3.6 0.2 7.7 8.4 0.0 4.1 6.7 0.0 6.6 Wood & Wood Products 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.3 Chemicals 1.6 3.2 1.0 0.0 0.2 1.1 3.0 0.0 0.8 0.1 0.0 0.9 Non-metallic Min. Products 3.1 5.2 2.9 0.9 0.0 1.4 2.1 0.0 0.0 0.6 0.0 2.6 Metal Products 1.0 1.9 0.3 0.7 0.1 0.5 1.9 0.0 0.0 0.5 0.0 0.6 Transportation Equipment 1.1 0.5 1.4 0.1 0.0 0.0 2.3 0.0 0.0 1.1 0.0 0.1 Machinery & Equipment 0.6 0.2 1.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.7 Other Manufactures 1.2 1.3 0.9 0.0 0.1 0.3 4.1 0.0 0.4 0.1 0.0 1.3 Elec., Gas & Water 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Construction 9.0 9.0 9.0 9.0 9.0 9.0 9.0 0.0 9.0 9.0 0.0 9.0 Trade & Transport 27.0 27.0 27.0 27.0 27.0 27.0 27.0 0.0 27.0 27.0 0.0 27.0 Other Private Services 31.0 31.0 31.0 31.0 31.0 31.0 31.0 0.0 31.0 31.0 0.0 31.0 Government Services 25.0 25.0 25.0 25.0 25.0 25.0 25.0 0.0 25.0 25.0 0.0 25.0 Note: Central America and Caribbean (CAC) members include Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, and Nicaragua, and are to be included in the FTAA. Sources: Adapted from Francois and Strutt (1999); Brown, Deardorff and Stern (2002); and Diamaranan and McDougall (2005). Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 CAC Mexico 7 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 COMPUTATIONAL ANALYSIS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS As already noted, the United States has signed or is currently in the process of negotiating a number of bilateral FTAs. These include the agreements with Chile and Singapore approved by the U.S. Congress in 2003, agreements with Central America and the Dominican Republic (CAFTA), Australia, Morocco, and Bahrain approved in 2005, and ongoing negotiations with the Southern African Customs Union (SACU), Andean Countries (Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, and Peru), Panama, Thailand, Korea, and the Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA).9 As we note in Brown, Kiyota, and Stern (2004, 2005a,b), the United States has a myriad of objectives in pursuing FTAs, including increased market access and shaping the regulatory and political environment in FTA partner countries to conform to U.S. principles and institutions. By the same token, the FTA partners are attracted by the preferential margins for U.S. market access and opportunities to improve their economic efficiency and to design and implement more effective domestic institutions and policies. We present below some results of the analysis of the following FTAs, which are denoted as: USCHFTA U.S.-Chile FTA USSGFTA U.S.-Singapore FTA USCAFTA U.S.-Central America FTA USAUSFTA U.S.-Australia FTA USMORFTA U.S.-Morocco FTA USSACUFTA U.S.-Southern African Customs Union FTA USTHFTA U.S.-Thailand FTA USKORFTA U.S.-Korea FTA FTAA Free Trade Area of the Americas 9 See the USTR website [www.ustr.gov] for more information on the variety of U.S. FTAs completed or in process. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 8 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies Table 2. Value of U.S. Sectoral Exports by Destination and Origin, 2001 (Millions of U.S. Dollars) Global Value Agriculture Mining Food, Beverages & Tobacco Textiles Wearing Apparel Leather Products & Footwear Wood & Wood Products Chemicals Non-metallic Min. Products Metal Products Transportation Equipment Machinery & Equipment Other Manufactures Elec., Gas & Water Construction Trade & Transport Other Private Services Government Services Total 31,488 6,435 29,107 12,625 5,116 1,930 28,076 102,913 13,890 33,490 110,075 279,309 14,710 732 2,739 62,203 109,632 44,252 888,720 Global Singapore 79 35 199 64 25 16 188 3,247 157 317 3,858 10,311 182 12 1 771 1,496 409 21,367 Singapore Australia 85 35 266 94 27 14 458 2,109 322 219 1,888 4,628 236 6 2 1,145 1,063 571 13,167 Australia Percent Agriculture 100.0 0.3 0.3 Mining 100.0 0.5 0.5 Food, Beverages & Tobacco 100.0 0.7 0.9 Textiles 100.0 0.5 0.7 Wearing Apparel 100.0 0.5 0.5 Leather Products & Footwear 100.0 0.9 0.7 Wood & Wood Products 100.0 0.7 1.6 Chemicals 100.0 3.2 2.0 Non-metallic Min. Products 100.0 1.1 2.3 Metal Products 100.0 0.9 0.7 Transportation Equipment 100.0 3.5 1.7 Machinery & Equipment 100.0 3.7 1.7 Other Manufactures 100.0 1.2 1.6 Elec., Gas & Water 100.0 1.6 0.8 Construction 100.0 0.1 0.1 Trade & Transport 100.0 1.2 1.8 Other Private Services 100.0 1.4 1.0 Government Services 100.0 0.9 1.3 Total 100.0 2.4 1.5 Source: GTAP 6.0 adapted from Dimaranan and McDougall (2005). Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 Morocco 103 22 43 18 4 0 17 30 16 5 31 79 2 0 0 59 90 255 777 Morocco 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.6 0.1 SACU 43 26 63 25 7 4 112 522 101 88 1,083 963 63 2 2 343 339 225 4,013 SACU 0.1 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.7 0.3 1.0 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.6 0.3 0.5 0.5 Thailand 390 30 185 53 11 30 146 779 88 166 1,095 1,918 134 4 12 403 701 276 6,421 Thailand 1.2 0.5 0.6 0.4 0.2 1.6 0.5 0.8 0.6 0.5 1.0 0.7 0.9 0.5 0.4 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.7 Korea 1,883 246 1,150 165 34 96 560 2,771 461 1,013 3,029 12,131 245 16 4 2,057 2,793 780 29,435 Korea 6.0 3.8 4.0 1.3 0.7 4.9 2.0 2.7 3.3 3.0 2.8 4.3 1.7 2.2 0.2 3.3 2.5 1.8 3.3 Canada CAC 3,542 1,370 4,624 2,529 389 148 8,759 19,864 3,269 10,604 35,001 45,107 1,769 245 14 1,783 4,170 1,094 144,281 684 15 789 1,578 1,135 48 632 1,827 119 261 496 2,618 394 2 17 366 519 238 11,736 Canada CAC 11.3 21.3 15.9 20.0 7.6 7.7 31.2 19.3 23.5 31.7 31.8 16.1 12.0 33.4 0.5 2.9 3.8 2.5 16.2 2.2 0.2 2.7 12.5 22.2 2.5 2.2 1.8 0.9 0.8 0.5 0.9 2.7 0.3 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.5 1.3 FTAA Chile 23 10 94 45 12 5 93 486 78 69 372 1,408 59 1 0 350 188 141 3,435 FTAA Chile 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.6 0.2 0.3 0.5 0.4 0.1 0.0 0.6 0.2 0.3 0.4 Mexico 4,032 281 3,518 3,724 1,290 342 4,365 14,607 1,349 6,239 12,154 34,627 1,028 16 1 756 1,147 715 90,191 Mexico 12.8 4.4 12.1 29.5 25.2 17.7 15.5 14.2 9.7 18.6 11.0 12.4 7.0 2.2 0.1 1.2 1.0 1.6 10.1 South America 1,475 505 1,361 1,183 803 168 1,469 7,948 999 1,357 4,217 16,995 654 41 19 1,999 2,909 1,951 46,054 South America 4.7 7.9 4.7 9.4 15.7 8.7 5.2 7.7 7.2 4.1 3.8 6.1 4.4 5.6 0.7 3.2 2.7 4.4 5.2 9 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 Table 3. Value of U.S. Sectoral Imports by Destination and Origin, 1997 (Millions of U.S. Dollars) Global Value Agriculture Mining Food, Beverages & Tobacco Textiles Wearing Apparel Leather Products & Footwear Wood & Wood Products Chemicals Non-metallic Min. Products Metal Products Transportation Equipment Machinery & Equipment Other Manufactures Elec., Gas & Water Construction Trade & Transport Other Private Services Government Services Total 20,644 69,789 34,790 30,961 50,788 22,480 63,362 108,578 20,054 64,781 191,656 373,201 57,287 2,104 764 82,987 69,873 20,736 1,284,834 Global Singapore 35 0 58 154 213 8 185 1,192 3 75 183 13,336 67 2 2 791 1,761 196 18,261 Singapore Australia 207 322 1,771 66 44 27 103 422 65 1,108 709 932 182 13 2 1,758 762 426 8,917 Australia Percent Agriculture 100.0 0.2 1.0 Mining 100.0 0.0 0.5 Food, Beverages & Tobacco 100.0 0.2 5.1 Textiles 100.0 0.5 0.2 Wearing Apparel 100.0 0.4 0.1 Leather Products & Footwear 100.0 0.0 0.1 Wood & Wood Products 100.0 0.3 0.2 Chemicals 100.0 1.1 0.4 Non-metallic Min. Products 100.0 0.0 0.3 Metal Products 100.0 0.1 1.7 Transportation Equipment 100.0 0.1 0.4 Machinery & Equipment 100.0 3.6 0.2 Other Manufactures 100.0 0.1 0.3 Elec., Gas & Water 100.0 0.1 0.6 Construction 100.0 0.2 0.3 Trade & Transport 100.0 1.0 2.1 Other Private Services 100.0 2.5 1.1 Government Services 100.0 0.9 2.1 Total 100.0 1.4 0.7 Source: GTAP 6.0 adapted from Dimaranan and McDougall (2005). http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 Morocco 32 81 29 5 104 7 6 36 3 5 2 95 5 1 3 365 102 256 1,136 Morocco 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.4 0.1 1.2 0.1 SACU 80 170 125 249 302 24 97 383 52 2,291 428 371 592 11 1 578 139 125 6,019 SACU 0.4 0.2 0.4 0.8 0.6 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.3 3.5 0.2 0.1 1.0 0.5 0.1 0.7 0.2 0.6 0.5 Thailand 432 28 2,185 874 1,689 770 609 992 461 490 173 5,881 1,491 4 6 1,427 492 77 18,080 Thailand 2.1 0.0 6.3 2.8 3.3 3.4 1.0 0.9 2.3 0.8 0.1 1.6 2.6 0.2 0.8 1.7 0.7 0.4 1.4 Korea 53 2 245 1,607 1,805 211 516 2,026 191 2,138 7,403 17,704 972 5 3 1,333 1,304 739 38,257 Korea 0.3 0.0 0.7 5.2 3.6 0.9 0.8 1.9 1.0 3.3 3.9 4.7 1.7 0.2 0.4 1.6 1.9 3.6 3.0 Canada CAC 4,582 16,971 7,860 2,376 1,438 169 30,720 20,041 2,860 16,056 53,987 39,869 1,633 1,563 5 2,221 2,394 582 205,326 1,792 108 962 2,436 4,374 27 215 1,118 68 171 70 1,149 184 6 9 810 512 230 14,242 Canada CAC 22.2 24.3 22.6 7.7 2.8 0.8 48.5 18.5 14.3 24.8 28.2 10.7 2.9 74.3 0.7 2.7 3.4 2.8 16.0 8.7 0.2 2.8 7.9 8.6 0.1 0.3 1.0 0.3 0.3 0.0 0.3 0.3 0.3 1.2 1.0 0.7 1.1 1.1 FTAA Chile 887 196 828 6 17 2 698 317 22 949 17 29 9 1 0 261 137 44 4,420 FTAA Chile 4.3 0.3 2.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.1 0.3 0.1 1.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.3 Mexico 3,750 8,285 2,841 3,932 6,122 526 4,513 3,719 2,012 4,841 23,094 65,698 1,802 17 4 1,086 602 120 132,964 Mexico 18.2 11.9 8.2 12.7 12.1 2.3 7.1 3.4 10.0 7.5 12.0 17.6 3.1 0.8 0.6 1.3 0.9 0.6 10.3 South America 2,977 12,109 2,561 1,175 3,136 1,883 2,205 5,024 1,700 4,398 4,176 3,949 845 55 5 1,897 1,941 899 50,937 South America 14.4 17.4 7.4 3.8 6.2 8.4 3.5 4.6 8.5 6.8 2.2 1.1 1.5 2.6 0.6 2.3 2.8 4.3 4.0 10 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies Table 4. Employment by Sector, 2001: United States and FTA Partners (Number of Workers and Percent of Employment) United Singapore Australia Morocco SACU Thailand States Workers (thousand) Agriculture 3,559 0.1 478 5,228 5,011 19,659 Mining 616 1 73 63 329 46 Food, Beverages & Tobacco 2,155 21 219 309 215 118 Textiles 845 2 44 189 73 134 Wearing Apparel 616 12 47 372 126 235 Leather Products & Footwear 92 1 13 41 32 15 Wood & Wood Products 2,236 38 226 80 215 44 Chemicals 2,717 56 119 127 173 52 Non-metallic Min. Products 724 8 50 123 78 39 Metal Products 3,120 55 199 84 216 69 Transportation Equipment 2,246 52 102 55 90 26 Machinery & Equipment 5,335 221 158 74 187 58 Other Manufactures 519 4 17 1 26 23 Elec., Gas & Water 1,529 13 74 46 140 118 Construction 10,406 153 730 804 1,457 2,016 Trade & Transport 39,104 810 3,090 2,333 3,234 9,571 Other Private Services 18,105 431 1,557 143 1,448 948 Government Services 52,786 164 2,706 1,706 6,741 3,987 Total 146,711 2,043 9,901 11,779 19,791 37,157 United Singapore Australia Morocco SACU Thailand States Percent Agriculture 2.4 0.0 4.8 44.4 25.3 52.9 Mining 0.4 0.0 0.7 0.5 1.7 0.1 Food, Beverages & Tobacco 1.5 1.0 2.2 2.6 1.1 0.3 Textiles 0.6 0.1 0.4 1.6 0.4 0.4 Wearing Apparel 0.4 0.6 0.5 3.2 0.6 0.6 Leather Products & Footwear 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.0 Wood & Wood Products 1.5 1.9 2.3 0.7 1.1 0.1 Chemicals 1.9 2.8 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.1 Non-metallic Min. Products 0.5 0.4 0.5 1.0 0.4 0.1 Metal Products 2.1 2.7 2.0 0.7 1.1 0.2 Transportation Equipment 1.5 2.5 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.1 Machinery & Equipment 3.6 10.8 1.6 0.6 0.9 0.2 Other Manufactures 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.1 Elec., Gas & Water 1.0 0.6 0.7 0.4 0.7 0.3 Construction 7.1 7.5 7.4 6.8 7.4 5.4 Trade & Transport 26.7 39.6 31.2 19.8 16.3 25.8 Other Private Services 12.3 21.1 15.7 1.2 7.3 2.6 Government Services 36.0 8.0 27.3 14.5 34.1 10.7 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Sources: ILO webiste (2005); Taiwan government website (2005); UNIDO (2005); and World Bank Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 Korea Canada 2,421 20 333 425 262 95 364 559 162 520 539 1,468 81 65 1,786 8,109 2,581 4,520 24,311 Korea 481 207 295 79 86 13 520 291 66 324 322 480 42 136 929 5,301 2,670 4,448 16,691 Canada 10.0 0.1 1.4 1.7 1.1 0.4 1.5 2.3 0.7 2.1 2.2 6.0 0.3 0.3 7.3 33.4 10.6 18.6 100.0 (2005). 2.9 1.2 1.8 0.5 0.5 0.1 3.1 1.7 0.4 1.9 1.9 2.9 0.2 0.8 5.6 31.8 16.0 26.6 100.0 CAC 6,891 48 1,597 229 1,029 119 585 666 211 264 92 590 102 290 2,381 6,792 1,296 6,754 29,937 CAC 23.0 0.2 5.3 0.8 3.4 0.4 2.0 2.2 0.7 0.9 0.3 2.0 0.3 1.0 8.0 22.7 4.3 22.6 100.0 FTAA Chile 863 83 299 39 29 25 144 150 34 109 27 47 3 38 491 1,700 480 1,785 6,347 FTAA Chile 13.6 1.3 4.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 2.3 2.4 0.5 1.7 0.4 0.7 0.0 0.6 7.7 26.8 7.6 28.1 100.0 Mexico 7,518 135 1,923 603 207 195 710 1,269 398 607 824 1,030 70 207 2,547 13,389 1,599 8,070 41,301 Mexico 18.2 0.3 4.7 1.5 0.5 0.5 1.7 3.1 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 0.2 0.5 6.2 32.4 3.9 19.5 100.0 South America 29,303 1,583 4,713 1,603 2,303 623 2,349 2,855 1,027 996 445 1,130 376 212 9,247 32,627 3,890 52,560 147,841 South America 19.8 1.1 3.2 1.1 1.6 0.4 1.6 1.9 0.7 0.7 0.3 0.8 0.3 0.1 6.3 22.1 2.6 35.6 100.0 11 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 Data constraints do not permit the analysis of the U.S. FTAs with the Andean countries, Bahrain and other countries in the Middle East, and Panama. Our reference point is the post-Uruguay Round 2005 database together with the post-Uruguay Round tariff rates on agricultural products and manufactures and the specially constructed measures of services barriers described above. Four scenarios have been carried out for each FTA: (A) removal of agricultural tariffs10; (M) removal of manufactures tariffs; (S) removal of services barriers; and (C) combined removal of agricultural and manufactures tariffs and services barriers. Because of space constraints, we report only the results of the combined removal of agricultural and manufactures tariffs and services barriers, denoted by USCHFTA-C, etc. The results for the separate removal of the agricultural, manufactures, and services barriers and for the sectoral effects on exports, imports, and gross output are available on request. We should emphasize that our computational analysis does not take into account other features of the various FTAs, which do not lend themselves readily to quantification. These other features cover E-commerce, intellectual property, labor and environmental standards, foreign direct investment, government procurement, trade remedies, dispute settlement, and the development of new institutional and cooperative measures. By the same token, because of data constraints, we have not made allowance for rules of origin and special preferences that may be negotiated as part of each FTA and that could be designed for protectionist reasons to limit trade. USCHFTA-C: U.S.-Chile Free Trade Agreement — The U.S.-Chile FTA was approved by the U.S. Congress in 2003. The estimated global welfare effects are indicated in Table 5. Global welfare increases by $7.6 billion, with U.S. welfare increasing by $6.3 billion (0.1% of GNP) and Chile’s welfare by $1.4 billion (1.7% of GNP).11 The sectoral results for the United States are shown in Table 6 and indicate small absolute and percent changes in employment across the U.S. sectors. The sectoral employment effects for Chile are indicated in Table 7 and show relatively large employment increases in agriculture, wood & wood products, metal products, trade & transport, and other private services, and relatively large employment declines in machinery & equipment and government services. These employment changes for Chile suggest the extent of labor market adjustments that may occur as a result of the FTA. 10 The bilateral FTA scenarios in this section make no allowance for reductions in agricultural export subsidies and agricultural production subsidies, which are excluded from bilateral negotiations and fall within the scope of the multilateral negotiations. 11 The estimated effects on aggregate exports/imports, terms of trade, and real returns to capital and labor for this and all other FTAs to be analyzed in what follows are available from the authors on request. Changes in bilateral trade flows by country/region of origin and destination are also available. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 12 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies T a b le 5 . G lo b a l W e lfa r e E ff e c ts o f B ila te r a l N e g o tia tin g O p tio n s f o r th e U n ite d S ta te s (B illio n s o f D o lla rs a n d P e rc e n t o f G N P ) U S -C h ile USU S -C A C USS in g a p o re A u s tra lia B illio n s o f D o lla rs Japan 0 .0 0 .5 -0 .5 - 0 .6 U n ite d S ta te s 6 .3 1 7 .0 1 1 .8 1 8 .6 C anada 0 .0 0 .1 -0 .3 - 0 .1 A u s tra lia -0 .0 0 .0 -0 .1 5 .1 N e w Z e a la n d -0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 E U and E F T A -0 .1 1 .7 - 2 .5 - 0 .5 H ong K ong -0 .0 -0 .0 - 0 .1 - 0 .0 C h in a -0 .0 0 .1 - 0 .4 - 0 .2 K o rea -0 .0 0 .1 - 0 .1 - 0 .2 S in g a p o re 0 .0 2 .5 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 T a iw a n 0 .0 -0 .0 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 In d o n e s ia -0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .1 0 .0 M a la ysia -0 .0 -0 .4 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 P h ilip p in e s 0 .0 -0 .0 - 0 .1 - 0 .0 T h a ila n d -0 .0 -0 .1 - 0 .1 - 0 .0 R e s t o f A s ia 0 .0 0 .1 - 0 .5 - 0 .1 C h ile 1 .4 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 M e x ic o 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .2 - 0 .1 C e n tra l A m e ric a a n d th e C a rrib e a n (C A C ) 0 .0 -0 .0 5 .1 - 0 .0 S o u th A m e ric a -0 .1 0 .1 0 .3 - 0 .0 M o ro c c o -0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 S o u th e rn A fric a n C u s to m s U n io n (S A C U ) -0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 T o ta l 7 .6 2 1 .6 1 2 .1 2 1 .8 U S -C h ile USU S -C A C USP erc e n t S in g a p o re A u s tra lia Japan 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 U n ite d S ta te s 0 .1 0 .1 0 .1 0 .1 C anada 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 A u s tra lia 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 1 .1 N e w Z e a la n d 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 E U and E F T A 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 H ong K ong 0 .0 - 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 C h in a 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 K o rea 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 S in g a p o re 0 .0 2 .4 -0 .0 -0 .0 T a iw a n 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 In d o n e s ia 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .1 0 .0 M a la ysia 0 .0 - 0 .4 -0 .0 -0 .0 P h ilip p in e s 0 .0 - 0 .1 -0 .1 -0 .0 T h a ila n d 0 .0 - 0 .0 -0 .1 -0 .0 R e s t o f A s ia 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .1 -0 .0 C h ile 1 .7 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 M e x ic o 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 C e n tra l A m e ric a a n d th e C a rrib e a n (C A C ) 0 .0 0 .0 3 .9 -0 .0 S o u th A m e ric a 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 M o ro c c o 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 S o u th e rn A fric a n C u s to m s U n io n (S A C U ) 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 USU S -S A C U M o ro c co 0 .1 - 0 .0 8 .2 9 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .3 - 0 .1 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 1 .2 - 0 .0 0 .0 1 .6 9 .9 1 0 .5 USU S -S A C U M o ro c co 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 2 .8 0 .0 0 .0 1 .0 U SU S -K T h a ila n d - 0 .1 1 5 .2 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .2 - 0 .0 - 0 .2 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 - 0 .0 5 .2 - 0 .1 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 1 9 .8 U SU S -K T h a ila n d 0 .0 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .1 - 0 .0 3 .6 - 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 o re a FTA A 0 .5 2 9 .1 0 .4 0 .2 0 .0 1 .5 0 .1 1 .2 1 3 .1 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .0 0 .2 0 .1 0 .4 0 .0 0 .0 4 7 .3 o re a - 1 .0 6 2 .4 5 .3 - 0 .1 -0 .0 -5 .3 -0 .0 -0 .3 -0 .3 -0 .0 -0 .2 -0 .2 -0 .1 -0 .1 -0 .1 -0 .6 3 .4 8 .4 7 .4 3 6 .2 -0 .0 -0 .1 1 1 4 .6 FTA A 0 .0 0 .2 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .1 2 .5 0 .1 0 .0 0 .1 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 - 0 .0 0 .5 0 .6 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .1 - 0 .0 - 0 .0 - 0 .1 0 .0 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 - 0 .1 4 .1 1 .1 5 .6 2 .3 - 0 .0 - 0 .1 13 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 T a b le 6 . S e cto r al E m p lo ym en t E ffe cts o f B ila te ra l N eg o tiatin g O p tio n s fo r th e U n ited S ta tes (N u m b er o f W o rk e rs an d P erc en t o f E m p lo ym en t) U S -C h ile USU S -C A C USUSU S -S A C U S in gap o re A u stra lia M o ro cc o N u m be r o f W o rk ers A g ric u ltu re (28 7 ) 531 6 ,0 23 (8 5 ) 9 88 284 M inin g (45 ) 196 2 64 405 91 51 F o o d, B ev era ges & T o b ac co (14 4 ) (7 7 ) 6 64 (9 2 0) 1 27 45 T e x tiles (15 ) (1 3 7 ) (6 ,91 7 ) 403 1 18 (4 9 0) W e arin g A p p are l (5 7 ) (1 4 5) (7 ,1 9 6 ) 298 (3 3 ) (2 9 8) L ea th er p ro d u cts & F o o tw e ar (7 ) 63 26 6 75 4 34 W o o d & W o o d P ro d u cts (14 8 ) 142 57 7 302 78 116 C h em ica ls 8 316 59 3 1 ,1 6 7 131 210 N o n -m etallic M in . P ro du c ts 29 145 21 7 370 96 84 M etal P ro du c ts (27 7 ) 1 ,0 1 5 1 ,07 7 1 ,1 5 8 87 467 T ran sp o rtation E q u ipm en t 14 914 61 9 1 ,6 1 6 77 915 M ac hin ery & E q u ipm en t 82 5 4 ,5 2 4 3 ,11 3 3 ,7 2 8 177 482 O th er M a n ufactu res 26 335 55 7 567 28 106 E lec ., G as & W a te r (1 7 ) (2 5) 93 26 14 20 C o nstru ctio n (3 9 ) (3 5 1) (6 0 ) (1 6 6) (1 7 ) 36 T rad e & T ran spo rt (23 7 ) (3 ,1 1 1) (37 6 ) (8 ,4 7 2) (1 ,7 1 1 ) (1 ,8 4 7) O th er P riv ate S erv ice s (10 0 ) (3 ,3 4 1) 79 2 (1 ,4 0 4) (9 ) 306 G o v ernm en t S e rv ic es 46 9 (9 9 4) (30 5 ) 931 (24 7 ) (5 2 0) U S -C h ile USU S -C A C USUSU S -S A C U P erc en t S in gap o re A u stra lia M o ro cc o A g ric u ltu re -0 .0 0 .0 0 .2 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 M inin g -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 F o o d, B ev era ges & T o b ac co -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 T e x tiles 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .8 0 .1 0 .0 -0 .1 W e arin g A p p are l -0 .0 -0 .0 -1 .2 0 .1 -0 .0 -0 .1 L ea th er p ro d u cts & F o o tw e ar -0 .0 0 .1 0 .3 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 W o o d & W o o d P ro d u cts -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 C h em ica ls 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 N o n -m etallic M in . P ro du c ts 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 M etal P ro du c ts -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 T ran sp o rtation E q u ipm en t 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 M ac hin ery & E q u ipm en t 0 .0 0 .1 0 .1 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 O th er M a n ufactu res 0 .0 0 .1 0 .1 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 E lec ., G as & W a te r 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 C o nstru ctio n 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 T rad e & T ran spo rt 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 O th er P riv ate S erv ice s 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 G o v ernm en t S e rv ic es 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 USU S -K o re a T h ailan d 3 2 ,7 8 2 2 ,1 91 1 70 (3 3 8) 2 ,2 4 3 1 28 (1 ,90 5 ) (4 ,2 6 4) (2 ,0 8 9 ) (3 ,7 5 6) (5 7 7 ) (2 3 2) 216 (6 6 4) 669 (6 9 8) 241 24 806 (2 ,5 3 7) 1 ,0 2 1 (3 ,1 9 5) 1 ,7 9 1 (4 ,1 8 0) 433 2 70 44 1 11 (5 4 ) (8 5 0) (5 ,0 7 9 ) (7 ,5 9 6) 567 (8 9 9) 1 ,4 2 7 (6 ,2 1 8) USU S -K o re a T h ailan d 0 .1 0 .9 0 .0 -0 .1 0 .0 0 .1 -0 .2 -0 .5 -0 .3 -0 .6 -0 .7 -0 .3 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .1 0 .1 -0 .1 0 .0 -0 .1 0 .1 0 .1 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 0 .0 -0 .0 14 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies T a b le 7 . S e c to r a l E m p lo y m e n t E ff e c ts fo r th e U S F T A (N u m b e r o f U S -C h ile N u m b e r o f W o rk ers A g ric u ltu re 3 ,1 1 4 M in in g 315 F o o d , B e v e ra g e s & T o b a c c o 244 T e x tile s 20 W e a rin g A p p are l 112 L e ath e r p ro d u c ts & F o o tw e a r (2 ) W o o d & W o o d P ro d u c ts 1 ,3 7 8 C h e m ic a ls 232 N o n -m e ta llic M in . P ro d u c ts (3 4 ) M etal P ro d u c ts 959 T ra n sp o rta tio n E q u ip m en t (1 2 7 ) M ac h in e ry & E q u ip m e n t (1 ,4 2 1 ) O th er M a n u fac tu res (1 4 ) E lec ., G a s & W a te r 147 C o n stru c tio n 413 T ra d e & T ran sp o rt 960 O th er P riv a te S erv ice s 1 ,2 1 2 G o v ern m e n t S e rv ice s (7 ,5 0 8 ) U S -C h ile P e rc e n t A g ric u ltu re 0 .4 M in in g 0 .4 F o o d , B e v e ra g e s & T o b a c c o 0 .1 T e x tile s 0 .1 W e a rin g A p p are l 0 .4 L e ath e r p ro d u c ts & F o o tw e a r -0 .0 W o o d & W o o d P ro d u c ts 1 .0 C h e m ic a ls 0 .2 N o n -m e ta llic M in . P ro d u c ts -0 .1 M etal P ro d u c ts 0 .9 T ra n sp o rta tio n E q u ip m en t -0 .5 M ac h in e ry & E q u ip m e n t -3 .0 O th er M a n u fac tu res -0 .5 E lec ., G a s & W a te r 0 .4 C o n stru c tio n 0 .1 T ra d e & T ran sp o rt 0 .1 O th er P riv a te S erv ice s 0 .3 G o v ern m e n t S e rv ice s -0 .4 Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 P a rtn er C o u n tr ie s W o rk e rs an d P e rc e n t o f E m p lo ym e n t) USU S -C A C U SU SU S -S A C U S in g a p o re A u stralia M o ro c co (1 ) (2 0 7 ,0 1 2 ) 200 (2 8 ,6 1 0 ) (5 ,2 0 4 ) (2 2 ) (5 ,9 4 0 ) (1 ,2 1 1 ) (8 8 9 ) (1 ,4 0 6 ) (5 5 7 ) (3 6 ,9 7 7 ) 1 ,6 7 7 (2 ,8 7 2 ) (9 0 4 ) 112 9 7 ,6 4 4 (1 1 2 ) (4 ,1 8 5 ) 3 ,3 0 3 1 ,7 5 8 3 9 2 ,2 1 3 (1 2 3 ) (2 ,6 8 6 ) 2 5 ,8 2 3 (4 5 ) (3 ,0 1 1 ) (1 0 7 ) (7 4 7 ) (1 9 7 ) (8 8 0 ) (1 5 ,5 2 6 ) (7 6 7 ) (1 2 4 ) (9 0 7 ) (1 ,7 2 1 ) (1 5 ,7 2 6 ) (1 ,5 7 1 ) (6 3 9 ) (9 1 2 ) (2 4 7 ) (9 ,4 5 1 ) (5 1 6 ) (7 9 1 ) (5 4 6 ) (2 ,6 2 7 ) (1 9 ,9 2 3 ) (2 ,7 8 8 ) 150 (2 ,4 7 1 ) (1 ,5 8 2 ) (8 ,1 4 3 ) (1 ,4 9 1 ) (1 9 5 ) (1 ,7 6 5 ) (1 0 ,1 3 4 ) (6 6 ,6 0 1 ) (2 ,9 9 5 ) (6 6 ) (2 ,1 7 2 ) (9 7 ) (5 ,5 3 9 ) (1 8 2 ) (3 ) (3 2 6 ) (1 6 ) 1 ,7 6 7 (1 4 6 ) 58 (5 1 0 ) 64 (7 ,3 3 4 ) (5 0 3 ) 482 (2 ,2 1 8 ) 4 ,4 7 9 (4 8 ,4 9 2 ) 9 ,9 8 8 4 0 ,6 1 3 382 1 1 ,9 9 8 (1 0 ,8 1 8 ) 2 ,8 6 7 388 (5 ,0 7 4 ) (4 8 2 ) (3 1 ,1 3 2 ) (2 ,2 1 9 ) 115 (4 ,8 9 7 ) USU S -C A C U SU SU S -S A C U S in g a p o re A u stralia M o ro c co -1 .3 -3 .0 0 .0 -0 .6 -0 .1 -2 .9 -1 2 .2 -1 .7 -1 .4 -0 .4 -2 .9 -2 .3 0 .8 -1 .0 -0 .4 5 .5 4 3 .7 -0 .3 -2 .2 4 .7 1 5 .6 3 7 .8 -0 .3 -0 .7 2 1 .6 -3 .7 -2 .5 -0 .8 -1 .9 -0 .7 -2 .3 -2 .6 -0 .3 -0 .2 -0 .4 -3 .0 -2 .3 -1 .3 -0 .5 -0 .5 -2 .9 -4 .5 -1 .0 -0 .7 -0 .7 -4 .8 -7 .6 -1 .4 0 .2 -1 .1 -3 .0 -9 .2 -1 .5 -0 .4 -1 .9 -4 .6 -1 1 .4 -1 .9 -0 .1 -1 .2 -2 .4 -5 .3 -1 .1 -0 .2 -1 .2 -0 .1 0 .6 -0 .2 0 .1 -0 .4 0 .0 -0 .3 -0 .1 0 .1 -0 .2 0 .6 -0 .7 0 .3 1 .7 0 .0 2 .8 -0 .8 0 .2 0 .3 -0 .4 -0 .3 -0 .5 -0 .1 0 .0 -0 .1 U SU S -K o re a T h a ila n d (1 6 6 ,2 1 7 ) (1 0 5 ,5 6 8 ) (1 ,4 1 7 ) 100 (1 ,6 0 1 ) (4 ,4 1 9 ) 1 0 ,9 1 6 3 4 ,3 4 9 2 2 ,1 1 2 3 7 ,0 5 0 1 ,9 0 5 5 ,9 2 9 (7 7 8 ) 868 (8 2 3 ) 2 ,0 8 7 (8 1 0 ) (5 4 9 ) (2 ,2 7 8 ) 3 ,7 9 8 (4 0 6 ) 8 ,1 3 9 (1 ,1 5 4 ) 3 ,4 1 5 (1 9 5 ) 1 ,1 2 3 382 263 4 ,8 3 1 (3 9 4 ) 1 6 1 ,1 3 5 1 0 ,5 8 6 (1 ,8 6 0 ) (2 ,3 0 4 ) (2 3 ,7 4 6 ) 5 ,5 2 7 U SU S -K o re a T h a ila n d -0 .9 -4 .4 -3 .0 0 .5 -1 .4 -1 .3 8 .3 7 .6 9 .5 1 4 .1 1 2 .7 6 .1 -1 .7 0 .2 -1 .5 0 .4 -2 .1 -0 .3 -3 .3 0 .7 -1 .6 1 .5 -2 .0 0 .2 -0 .9 1 .4 0 .3 0 .4 0 .2 -0 .0 1 .7 0 .1 -0 .2 -0 .1 -0 .6 0 .1 15 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 USSGFTA-C: U.S.-Singapore Free Trade Agreement — The welfare effects of a U.S.-Singapore FTA, which was approved by the U.S. Congress in 2003, noted in Table 5, indicate an increase in global welfare of $21.6 billion, with U.S. welfare rising by $17.0 billion (0.1% of GNP) and Singapore’s welfare by $2.5 billion (2.4% of GNP). In Table 6, the sectoral employment effects for the United States are relatively small, whereas in Table 7, for Singapore, there are relatively large sectoral employment increases in textiles, wearing apparel, and services, and declines in most other sectors. These sectoral changes suggest sizable employment adjustments for Singapore that may occur in the FTA with the United States. USCAFTA-C: U.S.-Central America Free Trade Agreement — The U.S.CAFTA was approved by the U.S. Congress in 2005. The estimated global welfare effects of the CAFTA shown in Table 5 indicate a rise of $12.1 billion, U.S. welfare increases by $11.8 billion (0.1% of GNP) and the welfare of the aggregate of Central American and the Caribbean (CAC) increases by $5.1 (3.9% of GNP).12 It can also be seen that the CAFTA is apparently trade diverting for most of the non-member countries/regions shown. The sectoral employment effects for the United States, noted in Table 6, indicate that the employment declines are concentrated in textiles and wearing apparel and are comparatively small as a percent of employment in these sectors, -0.8% and -1.2%, respectively. The sectoral employment changes for the CAC are shown in Table 7. The increases are quite large in textiles and wearing apparel, and there are employment declines in most of the other sectors, as the expansion of the relatively labor-intensive industries attracts workers from the rest of the economy. These results thus suggest that the CAFTA may result in significant worker displacement in the process of adjustment brought about by elimination of the import barriers. USAUSFTA-C: U.S.-Australia FTA — The U.S.-Australia FTA was approved in late 2004 and took effect at the beginning of 2005. It can be seen in Table 5 that global welfare rises by $21.8 billion, U.S. welfare by $18.6 billion (0.1% of GNP), and Australian welfare by 5.1 billion (1.1% of GNP). There are many instances of trade diversion for non-partner countries. The sectoral effects for the United States in Table 6 show small employment changes, while the positive employment changes for Australia in Table 7 are concentrated in food, beverages & tobacco, trade & transport, and other private services, and there are negative effects across all the other sectors ranging from -0.3 to -1.9% of sectoral employment. 12 The GTAP 6.0 data refer to a CAC aggregate and do not provide separate data for the five Central American countries and the Dominican Republic that comprise the CAFTA. It is noted in Brown, Kiyota, and Stern (2005b) that the CAFTA countries account for a substantial proportion of CAC trade so that using CAC data may be a reasonable approximation for modeling purposes. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 16 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies USMORFTA-C: U.S.-Morocco FTA — The U.S.-Morocco FTA was approved in 2005. As noted in Tables 2-3 above, U.S. trade in goods and services with Morocco is rather small. By far the largest proportions of Morocco’s trade are with the EU and EFTA. The global welfare increase from the U.S.-Morocco FTA indicated in Table 5 is $9.9 billion, Welfare increases by $8.2 billion (0.1% of GNP) for the United States, and $1.2 billion (2.8% of GNP) for Morocco. The U.S. sectoral employment changes noted in Table 6 are negligible. For Morocco, in Table 7, the largest employment increases are in trade & transport, and the largest declines in agriculture, food, beverages & tobacco, textiles, and apparel. The welfare and employment effects of the U.S.-Morocco FTA are thus seen to be fairly small. USSACUFTA-C: U.S.-Southern African Customs Union — The effects of the U.S.-SACU FTA, which is currently being negotiated, are indicated in Table 5, and show an increase of $10.5 billion in global welfare, $9.0 billion (0.1% of GNP) for the United States, and $1.6 billion (1.0% of GNP) for the SACU members combined. In Table 6, there are indications of negligible sectoral employment impacts for the United States. In Table 7, the employment increases for SACU are concentrated in textiles and wearing apparel and are negative across the remaining sectors as labor is attracted towards the labor-intensive sectors. US-THFTA-C: U.S.-Thailand FTA — The U.S.-Thailand FTA is currently being negotiated. In Table 5, the global welfare increase is $19.8 billion, a $15.2 billion (0.1% of GNP) increase for the United States, and a $5.2 billion (3.6% of GNP) increase for Thailand. There is evidence of pervasive trade diversion. The sectoral employment changes for the United States noted in Table 6 are negligible. For Thailand, in Table 7, the largest employment increases are concentrated in textiles and wearing apparel, construction, and trade & transport, and there are employment declines especially in agriculture, mining, food, beverages & tobacco, several capital-intensive manufactures, other private services, and government services. Some of the percentage employment effects are relatively large. US-KORFTA-C: U.S.-Korea FTA — The negotiation of a U.S.-Korea FTA is currently in process. In Table 5, global welfare is shown to increase by $47.3 billion, $29.1 billion (0.2% of GNP), U.S. welfare by $29.1 billion (0.2% of GNP), and Korea’s welfare by $13.1 billion (2.5% of GNP) for Korea. The sectoral employment effects on the United States are small, whereas some of the employment effects are substantial in absolute terms although rather small in percentage terms. FTAA-C: Free Trade Area of the Americas — Discussions have been ongoing for several years to create a Free Trade Area for the Americas (FTAA).13 13 For details on the FTAA negotiations, see the website of the Office of the United States Trade Representative [www.ustr.gov]. Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 17 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 Since the country detail in our model does not include the individual members of the FTAA, we have chosen to approximate it by combining the United States, Canada, Mexico, and Chile with an aggregate of Central American and Caribbean (CAC) and an aggregate of other South American nations. The welfare effects of the FTAA are indicated in Table 5 and amount to $114.6 billion globally, $62.4 billion (0.5% of GNP) for the United States, $5.3 billion (0.6% of GNP) for Canada, $8.4 billion (1.1% of GNP) for Mexico, $3.4 billion (4.1% of GNP) for Chile, $7.4 billion (5.6% of GNP) for the CAC, and $36.2 billion (2.3% of GNP) for the aggregate of other South American countries. There is some evidence of trade diversion, in particular for Japan and the EU/EFTA. The sectoral employment effects for the United States, indicated in Table 8, show relatively small employment declines in mining, textiles and wearing apparel, transportation equipment, and trade & transport, and increases in all other sectors. The sectoral employment effects for Canada are also small, whereas the employment changes for Mexico, Chile, the CAC, and other South America are noteworthy. This suggests that the developing countries covered in the FTAA would experience more employment adjustments than the United States and Canada. HUB AND SPOKE EFFECTS OF THE U.S. FTAS In the discussion of the U.S. bilateral FTAs in the preceding section, it was noted that there were indications of negative welfare effects for a number of nonmember countries/regions. It is well known theoretically that preferential trading arrangements may result in both trade creation, which is welfare enhancing, and trade diversion, which will reduce welfare as trade is shifted from lower to higher cost sources of supply. But there is another consideration, which is that bilateral FTAs are based on the “hub-and-spoke” arrangement, with the United States representing the hub and with separate spokes connecting the bilateral FTA partners to the hub. In negotiating these bilateral FTAs, no account is taken of the effects that they may have on non-members, even though there may be a bilateral FTA with one or more of the non-members. As more and more bilateral FTAs are negotiated, the spokes of the FTAs may thus emanate out in many different and overlapping directions, with resulting distortions of global trade patterns. That is, this combination of varying preferences among different and overlapping FTAs may lead to greatly increased transactions costs for firms and the undermining of the most-favored-nation (MFN) principle of non-discrimination that is at the heart of the multilateral trading system. These effects of the proliferation of FTAs are what Bhagwati and Panagariya (2002) refer to as “spaghetti-bowl” effects. An indication of the trade diversion associated with the U.S. FTAs and the overlapping of the spokes involved is shown in the left-hand side of Table 9, which has shaded cells indicating cases of positive welfare effects and white cells http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 18 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies T a b le 8 . S e c to r a l E m p lo y m e n t E ffe c ts f o r th e F T A A M e m b e r C o u n tr ie s (N u m b e r o f W o rk e rs a n d P e rc e n t o f E m p lo ym e n t) U n ite d C anada C h ile M e x ic o CAC S ta te s N u m b e r o f W o rk e rs A g ric u ltu re 9 ,6 7 5 2 ,7 1 7 1 2 ,2 6 4 (1 8 ,3 9 5 ) (2 4 1 ,5 5 4 ) M in in g (9 7 9 ) (6 6 4 ) (2 ,8 1 9 ) (1 1 6 ) (5 ,7 5 3 ) F o o d , B e v e ra g e s & T o b a c c o 10 441 720 (4 ,4 0 1 ) (4 9 ,2 3 1 ) T e x tile s (1 0 ,0 5 6 ) (1 ,2 9 9 ) 359 (1 ,5 1 3 ) 1 0 2 ,3 3 4 W e a rin g A p p a re l (9 ,3 4 3 ) (8 1 5 ) (8 6 ) (1 ,9 9 5 ) 4 1 0 ,4 9 1 L e a th e r p ro d u c ts & F o o tw e a r (4 8 6 ) (1 3 0 ) (3 3 ) (1 ,7 3 8 ) 1 ,3 8 8 W o o d & W o o d P ro d u c ts 1 ,2 9 2 653 2 ,7 7 9 968 (1 9 ,1 6 9 ) C h e m ic a ls 2 ,8 5 7 (4 0 1 ) 196 6 ,9 8 8 (1 1 ,3 6 4 ) N o n -m e ta llic M in . P ro d u c ts 788 (8 9 ) (2 0 6 ) 778 (1 2 ,3 4 1 ) M e ta l P ro d u c ts 26 (8 0 7 ) 1 ,7 6 9 2 ,0 7 7 (2 1 ,1 5 1 ) T ra n s p o rta tio n E q u ip m e n t (1 ,6 6 7 ) (3 9 7 ) (7 5 ) 7 ,3 0 7 (9 ,8 8 5 ) M a c h in e ry & E q u ip m e n t 9 ,9 1 6 (4 2 6 ) 2 ,4 5 2 3 ,5 8 0 (5 6 ,6 5 2 ) O th e r M a n u fa c tu re s 2 ,0 7 3 (6 7 ) 35 (3 2 ) (3 ,3 5 0 ) E le c ., G a s & W a te r 52 (4 7 ) 303 127 1 ,9 6 8 C o n s tru c tio n (3 7 2 ) (5 9 ) (1 6 5 ) 267 (7 ,7 2 9 ) T ra d e & T ra n s p o rt (5 ,3 6 8 ) 2 ,2 1 7 (7 ,6 0 0 ) 9 ,1 1 7 (3 3 ,8 2 6 ) O th e r P riv a te S e rv ic e s 739 (5 5 6 ) 716 (8 1 1 ) (6 ,8 5 5 ) G o v e rn m e n t S e rv ic e s 842 (2 7 2 ) (1 0 ,6 0 9 ) (2 ,2 0 9 ) (3 7 ,3 2 0 ) U n ite d C anada C h ile M e x ic o CAC P e rc e n t S ta te s A g ric u ltu re 0 .3 0 .6 1 .4 -0 .3 -3 .5 M in in g -0 .2 -0 .3 -3 .4 -0 .1 -1 1 .8 F o o d , B e v e ra g e s & T o b a c c o 0 .0 0 .2 0 .2 -0 .2 -3 .1 T e x tile s -1 .2 -1 .7 0 .9 -0 .3 4 5 .8 W e a rin g A p p a re l -1 .5 -1 .0 -0 .3 -1 .0 3 9 .6 L e a th e r p ro d u c ts & F o o tw e a r -0 .6 -1 .0 -0 .1 -0 .9 1 .2 W o o d & W o o d P ro d u c ts 0 .1 0 .1 1 .9 0 .1 -3 .3 C h e m ic a ls 0 .1 -0 .1 0 .1 0 .6 -1 .7 N o n -m e ta llic M in . P ro d u c ts 0 .1 -0 .1 -0 .6 0 .2 -5 .8 M e ta l P ro d u c ts 0 .0 -0 .3 1 .6 0 .3 -8 .0 T ra n s p o rta tio n E q u ip m e n t -0 .1 -0 .1 -0 .3 0 .9 -1 1 .2 M a c h in e ry & E q u ip m e n t 0 .2 -0 .1 5 .2 0 .3 -9 .7 O th e r M a n u fa c tu re s 0 .4 -0 .2 1 .2 -0 .1 -3 .2 E le c ., G a s & W a te r 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .8 0 .1 0 .7 C o n s tru c tio n 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .0 0 .0 -0 .3 T ra d e & T ra n s p o rt -0 .0 0 .0 -0 .5 0 .1 -0 .5 O th e r P riv a te S e rv ic e s 0 .0 -0 .0 0 .2 -0 .1 -0 .5 G o v e rn m e n t S e rv ic e s 0 .0 -0 .0 -0 .6 -0 .0 -0 .6 Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 S o u th A m e ric a 1 5 8 ,7 3 4 2 5 ,8 3 6 8 ,7 6 5 4 8 ,3 9 7 6 6 ,4 7 1 3 2 ,3 1 4 (2 2 ,6 2 6 ) (1 8 ,6 8 5 ) (2 ,3 1 5 ) 3 ,3 9 5 7 ,2 8 2 (1 4 ,8 7 5 ) (3 ,1 7 3 ) 264 (2 2 ,1 5 1 ) (4 8 ,2 7 5 ) (5 ,0 6 0 ) (2 1 4 ,2 9 9 ) S o u th A m e ric a 0 .5 1 .6 0 .2 3 .0 2 .9 5 .3 -1 .0 -0 .7 -0 .2 0 .3 1 .6 -1 .3 -0 .9 0 .1 -0 .2 -0 .2 -0 .1 -0 .4 19 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 Table 9. Welfare Effects of Bilateral FTAs and Unilateral and Global Free Trade Bilateral FTAs 1 USCHL 2 USSGP 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 3 USCAC 4 5 6 7 8 9 US- US- US- US- US- FTAA AUS MOR SACU THA KOR Unilateral Free Trade 10 US 11 SGP 12 13 14 15 16 AUS MCC SACU THA KOR Japan US X X X X X X X X X X Canada X Australia X X New Zealand EU and EFTA Hong Kong China Korea X Singapore X X Taiwan Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Thailand X Rest of Asia Chile X X Mexico X CAC X X South America X Morocco X X SACU X X No. of Positive Effects 10 16 3 5 22 9 8 22 6 20 22 22 22 22 Notes: 1) Shaded cells indicate countries with positive welfare effects while white cells indicate countries with negative welfare effects. 2) "X" indicates unilateral free trade countries. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 Global FT 17 CHL 18 CAC X X X X 22 21 22 22 X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X 22 20 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies indicating cases of negative welfare effects. Altogether, 9 FTAs are shown, although there is some double counting insofar as the U.S.-CAC and U.S.-Chile bilateral FTAs are encompassed in the FTAA. In any event, it seems evident from Table 9 that trade diversion and negative welfare effects are pervasive. Thus, while partner-FTA countries may gain directly from their FTAs, as indicated by “X” in the table, they may be adversely affected by other FTAs that have been negotiated. The global results of the bilateral FTAs in Table 5 suggest that the negative welfare effects on non-members may be rather small in both absolute terms and as a percent of GNP. But, as mentioned in our earlier discussion, because of data limitations, our results do not reflect the potential welfare declines due to rules of origin and other discriminatory arrangements built into the bilateral FTAs. On the other hand, we do not allow for increased inflows of foreign direct investment into the partner countries or the effects of improvements in productivity and increased capital formation. Unfortunately, we are not in a position to assess these potential benefits. But it seems clear from our computational results that the welfare increases from the FTA removal of trade barriers are fairly small on the whole. Pending further analysis, we therefore conclude that there is reason to be concerned about the trade diversion and overlapping spoke effects of bilateral FTAs. WELFARE EFFECTS OF UNILATERAL FREE TRADE AND GLOBAL FREE TRADE In this section, we ask how the welfare of the United States, its FTA partners, and other countries/regions in the global trading system would be affected if it were feasible to adopt unilateral free trade or global free trade on a non-discriminatory (MFN) basis as compared to the adoption of discriminatory bilateral FTAs. The detailed results by country/region are indicated in Table 10, and the results for the U.S. bilateral FTAs and the FTAA, unilateral liberalization, and global free trade are summarized for the United States and its FTA partner countries/regions in Table 11. Unilateral free trade adopted by the United States would increase U.S. welfare by $368.8 billion (2.9% of GNP), which is more than three times greater than the U.S. welfare gains from the bilateral FTAs combined. If there were global (multilateral) free trade, U.S. welfare would be increased by $591.0 billion (4.6% of GNP). There are also clear indications that, except for Singapore and Australia, the FTA partner countries would generally gain more from the adoption of unilateral free trade by the United States as compared to the partner-country gains from their bilateral FTAs. Furthermore, the FTA partner countries would generally gain even more if they adopted unilateral free trade and especially if there were global free trade. These benefits are clearly reflected in Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 21 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 T able 10. W elfare E ffects of U nilateral an d G lobal Free T rade B illions of D ollars Japan U nited States C anada A ustralia N ew Zealand EU and EFTA H ong K ong C hina K orea Singapore Taiw an Indonesia M alaysia Philippines Thailand R est of A sia C hile M exico C entral A m erica and the C arribean (C A C ) South A m erica M orocco Southern A frican C ustom s U nion (SA C U ) Total U nited States Singapore 11.0 0.7 368.8 1.6 -9.8 0.2 4.5 0.1 1.1 0.0 133.5 3.4 9.3 0.2 3.0 0.2 4.3 0.1 2.1 1.1 3.9 0.1 2.3 0.1 4.3 0.7 0.8 0.1 2.0 0.2 8.9 0.2 0.8 0.0 -8.5 0.1 3.4 0.0 5.2 0.3 0.7 0.0 0.8 0.0 552.3 9.5 A ustralia 4.6 1.8 0.2 4.3 0.7 3.6 0.1 1.1 1.0 0.1 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.7 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 20.1 Percent Japan U nited States C anada A ustralia N ew Zealand EU and EFTA H ong K ong C hina K orea Singapore Taiw an Indonesia M alaysia Philippines Thailand R est of A sia C hile M exico C entral A m erica and the C arribean (C A C ) South A m erica M orocco Southern A frican C ustom s U nion (SA C U ) U nited States Singapore 0.2 0.0 2.9 0.0 -1.1 0.0 1.0 0.0 1.7 0.0 1.2 0.0 4.7 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.8 0.0 2.1 1.1 1.1 0.0 1.3 0.1 4.0 0.6 0.9 0.1 1.3 0.1 0.9 0.0 1.0 0.0 -1.1 0.0 2.6 0.0 0.3 0.0 1.7 0.0 0.5 0.0 A ustralia 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.9 1.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 U nilateral Free T rade M orocco SA C U T hailand 1.1 1.2 6.7 2.8 2.5 6.3 0.3 0.2 0.6 0.2 0.1 0.7 0.0 0.0 0.1 7.6 6.5 10.9 0.1 0.1 0.9 0.2 0.4 1.4 0.2 0.3 0.8 0.1 0.1 0.9 0.1 0.3 1.0 0.0 0.1 0.5 0.1 0.1 1.9 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.1 0.2 14.3 0.1 0.4 0.9 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.5 0.4 1.0 2.4 0.0 0.0 0.2 8.9 0.2 16.3 22.2 50.1 U nilateral Free T rade M orocco SA C U T hailand 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.9 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.1 1.8 0.0 0.1 0.5 0.1 0.1 9.8 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 5.4 0.1 0.1 0.1 5.7 0.1 K orea 6.0 12.1 1.4 1.3 0.2 22.4 1.3 -2.3 37.1 0.7 0.7 0.9 1.2 0.3 0.3 1.4 0.3 0.9 0.6 1.7 0.1 0.2 88.5 C hile K orea 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.6 -0.2 7.0 0.7 0.2 0.5 1.1 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.1 0.4 0.1 0.2 0.1 C hile 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.5 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 1.0 1.5 0.2 0.0 0.0 2.5 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 4.6 0.1 0.1 1.0 0.0 0.0 12.1 CAC 3.0 4.5 0.4 0.2 0.1 6.7 0.3 0.5 0.9 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.4 6.3 0.8 0.0 0.1 25.1 CAC 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 4.8 0.1 0.1 0.1 G lobal Free Trade 312.0 591.0 46.8 28.5 8.6 840.0 47.7 145.6 78.4 17.6 56.3 25.0 38.0 11.4 25.8 66.7 9.0 54.4 16.4 106.7 5.0 11.3 2,542.1 G lobal Free Trade 5.9 4.6 5.1 6.3 13.5 7.6 24.0 9.9 14.8 17.3 15.7 13.5 34.8 12.6 17.7 6.8 10.9 6.9 12.3 6.9 11.6 7.2 22 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies Table 11. Summary Results: Welfare Effects Bilateral FTA US Hub Bill. $ % of GNP Bilateral FTA/Unilateral free trade United States Chile Singapore Australia CAC Morocco SACU Thailand Korea Regional free trade FTAA Global free trade United States Chile Singapore Australia CAC Morocco SACU Thailand Korea Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 Spokes Bill. $ 115.30 6.3 17.0 11.8 18.6 8.2 9.0 15.2 29.1 0.89 0.05 0.13 0.09 0.14 0.06 0.07 0.12 0.23 1.4 2.5 5.1 5.1 1.2 1.6 5.2 13.1 62.4 0.48 60.7 World % of GNP Bill. $ 1.7 2.4 1.1 3.9 2.8 1.0 3.6 2.5 7.6 21.6 12.1 21.8 9.9 10.5 19.8 47.3 Unilateral/Global free trade Country World Bill. $ % of GNP Bill. $ 368.8 4.6 1.1 4.3 6.3 2.4 8.9 14.3 37.1 2.9 5.5 1.1 0.9 4.8 5.4 5.7 9.8 7.0 552.3 12.1 9.5 20.1 25.1 16.3 22.2 50.1 88.5 591.0 9.0 17.6 28.5 16.4 5.0 11.3 25.8 78.4 4.6 10.9 17.3 6.3 12.3 11.6 7.2 17.7 14.8 2542.1 114.6 23 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 the predominance of the shaded cells in the right-hand side of Table 9. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS In this article, we have used the Michigan Model of World Production and Trade to calculate the aggregate welfare and sectoral employment effects of the menu of U.S. trade policies. The menu of policies encompasses the various preferential U.S. bilateral and regional FTAs negotiated and in process, unilateral removal of existing trade barriers by the United States, its FTA partner countries, and global (multilateral) free trade. The welfare impacts of the FTAs on the United States are shown to be rather small in absolute and relative terms. The sectoral employment effects are also generally small, but vary across the individual sectors depending on the patterns of bilateral liberalization. The welfare effects on the FTA partner countries are shown to be mostly positive though generally small, but there are some indications of potentially disruptive employment shifts in some partner countries. The results further suggest that there would be trade diversion and detrimental welfare effects in some non-member countries/regions. It also appears that, while FTA partners may gain from the bilateral FTAs, they may be adversely affected because of overlapping “hub-and-spoke” arrangements due to other discriminatory FTAs that have been negotiated. The welfare gains from both unilateral trade liberalization by the United States and from global (multilateral) trade liberalization are shown to be rather substantial and more uniformly positive for all countries/regions in the global trading system as compared to the welfare gains from the bilateral FTAs analyzed.14 The issue then is whether the WTO member countries will be able to overcome their divisiveness and indecisions and bring the Doha Round multilateral negotiations to a successful conclusion. Our computational results suggest that the menu choice of policy options is clearly in favor of multilateral liberalization. REFERENCES Anderson, K., Martin, W. 2005. Agricultural Trade Reform and the Doha Development Agenda. The World Economy. 28(9):1301-1328. Bhagwati, J., Panagariya, A. 1996. Preferential Trading Areas and Multilateralism—Strangers, Friends, or Foes? in The Economics of Preferential 14 See Brown, Kiyota, and Stern (2005b) for sensitivity analysis of introducing alternative parameters in the model and the resulting welfare impacts of global free trade. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 24 Kiyota and Stern: Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Policies Trade Agreements, ed. J. Bhagwati and A. Panagariya. American Enterprise Institute. Washington, DC: Brown, D. K., Deardorff, A. V., Stern, R. M. 2002. CGE Modeling and Analysis of Multilateral and Regional Negotiating Options, in Issues and Options for U.S.Japan Trade Policies, ed. R. M. Stern. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Brown, D. K., Kiyota, K., Stern, R. M. 2004. Computational Analysis of the U.S. FTA with the Southern African Customs Union (SACU), Research Seminar in International Economics, University of Michigan, Working Paper No. 508 (July). Brown, D. K., Kiyota, K., Stern, R. M. 2005a. Computational Analysis of the Free Trade Agreement of the Americas (FTAA). North American Journal of Economics and Finance. 23:153-185. Brown, D. K., Kiyota, K.. Stern, R. M. 2005b. Computational Analysis of the U.S. FTAs with Central America, Australia, and Morocco. The World Economy. 28(10):1441-1490.. Dimaranan, B. V., McDougall, R. A. 2005. Global Trade, Assistance, and Protection: The GTAP 6r Data Base. West Lafayette, IN: Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University, forthcoming. Francois, J., Strutt, A. 1999. Post Uruguay Round Tariff Vectors for GTAP Version 4, Erasmus University, manuscript. Francois, J., van Meijl, H., van Tongeren, F. 2005. Trade Liberalization in the Doha Development Round. Economic Policy. 20:349-391. Hertel, T. W., Martin, W. 2000. Liberalizing Agriculture and Manufactures in a Millennium Round: Implications for Developing Countries. The World Economy. 23(4):455-469. Hertel, T. W. 2000. Potential Gains from Reducing Trade Barriers in Manufacturing, Services and Agriculture. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review. 82:77-99. Hoekman, B. 2000. The Next Round of Services Negotiations: Identifying Priorities and Options. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review. 82:31-47. International Labor Organization (http://laborsta.ilo.org/cgi-bin/ brokerv8.exe). Published by Berkeley Electronic Press, 2005 (ILO). 2005. LABORSTA 25 Global Economy Journal, Vol. 5 [2005], Iss. 4, Art. 22 Ianchovichina, E., Martin, W. 2004. Economic Impacts of China’s Accession to the WTO, in China and the WTO: Accession, Policy Reform, and Poverty Reduction Strategies, ed. D. Bhattasali, S. Li, and W. Martin. Washington, DC: Oxford University Press and the World Bank. Stolper, W., Samuelson, P. A. 1941. Protection and Real Wages. Review of Economic Studies. 9:58-73. Taiwan Government. 2005. (www.stat.gov.tai/bs2/2005YearBook.pdf). United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO). 2005. UNIDO Industrial Statistics Database 2005 at the 3-digit Level of ISIC (Revision 2) on CD-ROM Geneva: UNIDO. World Bank 2005. World Development Indicators on CD-ROM. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://www.bepress.com/gej/vol5/iss4/22 DOI: 10.2202/1524-5861.1157 26