Do Workers Bear the Cost of Rising Health Insurance Premiums through Lower Wage Raises? Bradley Herring, Ph.D. Johns Hopkins University M. Kate Bundorf, Ph.D. Stanford University Mark V. Pauly, Ph.D. University of Pennsylvania AcademyHealth’s ARM: June 28, 2009 Funding Source: RWJF’s HCFO Initiative Overview • Policy and Economic Motivation • Empirical Methods: – Effect of changes in premiums on changes in wages – Sample of insured workers in 2004-2007 SIPP – Average premiums for state/industry from MEPS-IC • Preview of Results: – 70% of premium growth passed on to wages in short term – Smaller effect for workers with low wages (“stickiness”) – No difference between low and high spending workers Health Policy Motivation • Who pays the cost in employment-based insurance? – Employer profit margins and/or prices? Employee wages? • Some claim that U.S. competitiveness in the global economy is hampered by high healthcare spending • What are the distributional effects of impending healthcare reform? – Who will benefit from reductions in medical spending? – Effect of “play or pay” employer mandates? – Effect of firms changing coverage after Medicaid expansion, subsidies to Exchange, tax reform, and public plan option? Taken from: Kaiser Family Foundation, 2008, Costs/Insurance Fast Facts. Economic Motivation • Economic theory on the tradeoffs between benefits costs and wages is pretty straightforward: – productivity = total compensation = wages + benefits • But the supporting empirical evidence is limited: – – – – – Many studies document positive correlation or no effect Gender: Gruber, 1994 Age: Sheiner, 1999; Pauly and Herring, 1999; Adams, 2007 Obesity: Bhattacharya and Bundorf, 2005 Changes: Goldman et al., 2005; Baicker and Chandra, 2006 Common Approach Workers at firm offering insurance: Worker at firm not offering insurance: Low Spending Worker High Spending Worker Difference: WOL WOH WOH – WOL WNL WNH WNH – WNL Net Effect on Wages: (WOH – WOL) – (WNH – WNL) Concerns With This Approach • Are jobs at employers that don’t offer health benefits really a good control for those that do? – Couldn’t the proxy for high spending have a different relationship in “good” jobs versus “bad” jobs? • This approach assumes that premiums affect wages differentially by spending level, rather than testing for differential effects empirically – If there is only “average incidence” across all workers, this difference-in-difference approach won’t observe an effect. Our Approach Firm facing high growth in premiums: Firm facing low growth in premiums: Worker i Last Year Worker i This Year Difference: WH1 WH2 WH2 – WH1 a smaller raise? WL1 WL2 WL2 – WL1 a larger raise? Net Effect On Wages: (WH2 – WH1) – (WL2 – WL1) Methods • Sample: Longitudinal sample of workers from 2004 SIPP merged with average premiums from MEPS-IC • OLS regression model for wages, w: w2 = a + w1 + b (p2 – p1) + c x + e • Hypothesize that b = -1 with full incidence on wages • Test for differences in b across different subsamples: – Lower wage vs. higher wage, if wages constrained for former – Lower vs. higher covered spending, based on age and gender Methods: SIPP Data • Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP): – Large, rich nationally-representative household survey data – 2004 Panel for years 2004 through 2007 (Waves 1, 4, 7, & 10) • Sample: – Full-time, private-sector ESI policyholders staying in job – Yields three one-year changes in wages (January to January) – N = 24,133 (representing over 8,000 workers) • Control variables, x: – Age, gender, marital status, race/ethnicity, education, union status, firm size, industry indicators (18), region, and time Methods: MEPS-IC Data • Medical Expenditure Panel Survey’s Insurance Component’s (MEPS-IC): – Large nationally-representative employer survey data – Tables with average premiums by state posted online • Data Used: – Premium changes: 2003 to 2004, 2005 to 2006, 2006 to 2007 – Five groupings of industry classifications within each state – Employer share of the premium, single/family pooled • Merge the MEPS-IC’s average premiums to the SIPP sample of workers by worker i’s state-industry. Main Results • OLS coefficient for the one-year change in premiums: – Wage regression using a sample of covered workers; the control variables behave as expected (r-square = 0.72) – Standard errors clustered by worker and by state/industry Sample: All insured workers Coefficient for p2 – p1 -0.712 Robust Standard Error 0.344** • Implication: About 70% of premium increase passed onto wages in the short term Results By Wage Level • A binding constraint of non-negative nominal wage increases for lower-wage workers? – At $35K: 10% family premium growth = 3% wage growth Sample: Below $35K Above $35K Coefficient for p2 – p1 -0.180 -1.051 Robust Standard Error 0.173 0.576* • Implications: consistent with “stickiness” at low wages, and full incidence for the others where applicable Results By Low vs. High Spending • Is this wage tradeoff larger for high-spending workers? – If so, expect the coefficient b to be larger for that sample • Spending for covered unit, by age/gender (MEPS-HC) – Low Spending: $3,675 (average age of 36, 39% female) – High spending: $5,882 (average age of 49, 25% female) Sample: Low Spending, Above $35K High Spending, Above $35K Coefficient for p2 – p1 -0.918 -1.042 Robust Standard Error 0.901 0.750 Conclusions and Implications • Examine the tradeoff between wages and premiums: – 70% of premium growth passed on to wages in short term – Nominal wage constraints at low end; full incidence for rest – No support for differential incidence by expected spending • Implications for Reform: Workers pay most of the costs – Workers will benefit from efforts to reduce medical spending – Workers will ultimately “pay” under reforms geared to incentivize or require employers to start offering coverage – Workers won’t necessarily “lose” in transitions away from employment-based coverage (i.e., they’d get wage raises)