Patient Welfare and Selective Contracting in Kidney Transplantation …patients should be free to seek out the providers with the best track records given their unique circumstances. In the current environment, where patients' treatments are determined by the networks they are in, network providers are all but guaranteed. David H. Howard Department of Health Policy and Management Emory University Michael E. Porter and Elizabeth Olmsted Teisberg Harvard Business Review Funding by NIDDK/NIH 1 2 CIGNA LIFESOURCE Transplant NetworkMS The nation's leading transplant program Why lies at the core of consumers’ complaints about managed care? To my mind, the answer is clear. Today’s well-educated, assertive consumers want choice and control. Each facility in our network is carefully chosen and must continue to meet our stringent quality standards. We assess several factors, including: Regina Herzlinger, J Health Politics Policy and Law 1999 •patient outcomes; •staff training and experience; •number of transplants performed; •waiting periods; •availability of housing arrangements and transportation for patients' families; •geographic location and accessibility; and •availability of transplant organs in the geographic area of the facility. In health care there is increasing control over access to medical services. Insurance companies disallow patient free choice of physicians, clinics and hospitals outside their approved network. If there is a solution to this problem, it will take the form of changing the incentive structure: empowering the consumer by channeling third-party payment allowances through the patients or students who are choosing and consuming the service. Vernon Smith, Wall St. Journal 2006 3 What is the Blue Quality Centers for Transplant (BQCT) Program? 4 Humana has authorized the National Transplant Network (NTN) Site Selection Committee to establish guidelines by which the NTN is to be developed and maintained. The Blue Quality Centers for Transplant (BQCT) is a centers of excellence bone marrow and organ transplant program offered through participating Blue Cross Blue Shield Plans. All institutions selected as BQCT centers of excellence must meet stringent Program criteria. BQCT includes for covered transplants seven individual networks: heart; lung; heart/lung; liver, lung, simultaneous kidney-pancreas; pancreas and bone marrow (autologous and allogeneic). •Transplant programs must be in continuous operation for a minimum of one year, and ideally, for four years from the date of the first transplant. •Transplant team members should be in place and working together for a minimum of one year. •Transplant programs must meet volume guidelines for the previous year or average of previous two years. (see below) •Outcomes for a solid organ transplant program will be compared to United Network for Organ Sharing (UNOS) or US Transplant, whichever is most current, and must not be significantly below the expected patient and graft survival at one year or three years. Transplant programs must meet Medicare minimum patient survival outcomes, as defined in the Federal Register for a specific solid organ transplant. How do you select and credential facilities? Institutions are selected for the Blue Quality Centers for Transplant (BQCT) Program based on their ability to meet defined clinical criteria that are unique for each type of transplant. Panels of transplant surgeons and physicians advise the Blue Cross and Blue Shield Association on selection criteria, which are updated in response to medical advances. 5 6 1 Direct method - Overview Three approaches to studying the role of quality in selective contracting: • Direct method: Compare quality between in- and out-of-network providers (Gaskin et al. 2002; Mukamel et al. 2002, Lindrooth et al. 2002). • Obtain network lists from for Beechstreet, Aetna, Humana, United Health, Cigna • Merge with a list of all hospitals offering kidney transplant services w/ outcome data for each center • Indirect method: Infer the role of quality in contracting decisions from patient flows. (Escarce et al. 1999; Chernew et al. 1998; Feldman and Sharfstein 2000). • Compare outcomes between in-network and out-of-network facilities • Very indirect method: Examine how the impact of hospital competition on quality varies by payer type. (Kessler and McClellan 2000; Gowrisankaran and Town 2003). 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 Quality at in-network and out-of-network transplant centers for five health plans Quality: O-E graft survival Health plan % In-network BeechStreet United Cigna Humana Aetna 21% 33% 29% 35% 38% In-network Out-of-network 0.90 1.39 0.50 1.40 0.74 -0.58 -1.19 -0.92 -1.14 -1.28 Diff. T-stat 1.47 2.58 1.42 2.54 2.02 1.66 4.00 1.96 3.69 3.16 13 14 Sample construction Indirect method - Overview • Use data on registrations for patients added to the kidney transplant waiting list • 28,364 non-elderly adult (age 18-64) kidney transplant registrants. • Registered on the wait list between January 1, 2000 and October 31, 2002. • With private insurance or Medicare (no Medicaid). • Note that the choice of transplant center is made at the time of registration, not the time of transplant. • The database includes the universe of candidates for deceased donor transplants in the United States and 30 percent of living-donor transplant recipients. • Choice sets were constructed using distance and historical registration patterns. • Create patient-level choice sets • Merge with data on transplant center location and outcomes • Compare impact of outcomes on choice between patients with private insurance and Medicare 15 Statistical analysis Statistical analysis Conditional logit model: fully interact transplant center attributes -quality -distance 16 Conditional logit model: fully interact patient characteristics -age -sex -race -health status -education -insurance transplant center attributes -quality -distance patient characteristics -age -sex -race -health status -education -insurance U ij = β 01q j + β 02 q j AGEi + β 03 q j MALEi + ... + β12 q j PRIVi + β13 d ij + β14 d ij AGEi + β15 d ij MALEi + ... + β 26 d ij PRIVi + ε ij 17 18 3 Differences between privately-insured registrants and Medicare beneficiaries Statistical analysis Conditional logit model: fully interact Insurance Private Medicare transplant center attributes -quality -distance patient characteristics -age -sex -race -health status -education -insurance Age Male White On dialysis Diabetic Cardiac condition ADL limitation Education: HS degree Education: College degree Education: Unknown Employed U ij = β 01q j + β 02 q j AGEi + β 03 q j MALEi + ... + β12 q j PRIVi + β13 d ij + β14 d ij AGEi + β15 d ij MALEi + ... + β 26 d ij PRIVi + ε ij N 48 59% 57% 70% 35% 15% 12% 56% 20% 22% 55% 47 59% 38% 95% 41% 19% 17% 62% 8% 21% 21% 15,906 12,458 19 Estimates from the conditional logit model 20 Estimates from the conditional logit model Center attributes Center attributes Variable Quality Variable Distance Quality Distance 1.6671 (1.2792) -0.9509 (0.0152)* 0.0000 (0.0000) Level ×Age -0.0161 (0.0165) 0.0000 (0.0000) 0.0017 (0.0005)* ×Male 0.0417 (0.3444) 0.0017 (0.0005)* 1.3929 (0.3596)* -0.0011 (0.0005)* ×White 1.3929 (0.3596)* -0.0011 (0.0005)* 0.0646 (0.4932) 0.0010 (0.0006) ×On dialysis 0.0646 (0.4932) 0.0010 (0.0006) -0.2809 (0.3753) -0.0021 (0.0005)* ×Diabetic -0.2809 (0.3753) -0.0021 (0.0005)* -0.2267 (0.4314) -0.0013 (0.0006)* Level ×Age 1.6671 (1.2792) -0.9509 (0.0152)* -0.0161 (0.0165) ×Male 0.0417 (0.3444) ×White ×On dialysis ×Diabetic -0.0013 (0.0006)* ×Cardiac condition ×ADL limitation 1.7232 (0.5084)* 0.0061 (0.0008)* ×ADL limitation 1.7232 (0.5084)* 0.0061 (0.0008)* ×Education: HS degree -1.3803 (0.8673) 0.0026 (0.0008)* ×Education: HS degree -1.3803 (0.8673) 0.0026 (0.0008)* ×Education: College degree 1.0463 (0.9872) 0.0033 (0.0010)* ×Education: College degree 1.0463 (0.9872) 0.0033 (0.0010)* ×Education: Unknown -1.2771 (0.8987) 0.0022 (0.0009)* ×Education: Unknown -1.2771 (0.8987) 0.0022 (0.0009)* -0.5976 (0.3913) -0.0026 (0.0005)* 3.0534 (0.3822)* 0.0035 (0.0005)* ×Cardiac condition -0.2267 (0.4314) ×Employed -0.5976 (0.3913) -0.0026 (0.0005)* ×Employed ×Private insurance 3.0534 (0.3822)* 0.0035 (0.0005)* ×Private insurance *P < 0.05 Standard errors are in parentheses. 21 *P < 0.05 Standard errors are in parentheses. 22 Quality-choice elasticity estimates Estimates from the conditional logit model Center attributes Actual: 0.14 [95% CI: -0.21,- 0.07]. Variable Quality Distance Level ×Age 1.6671 (1.2792) -0.9509 (0.0152)* -0.0161 (0.0165) 0.0000 (0.0000) ×Male 0.0417 (0.3444) 0.0017 (0.0005)* ×White 1.3929 (0.3596)* -0.0011 (0.0005)* ×On dialysis 0.0646 (0.4932) 0.0010 (0.0006) ×Diabetic -0.2809 (0.3753) -0.0021 (0.0005)* ×Cardiac condition -0.2267 (0.4314) -0.0013 (0.0006)* ×ADL limitation 1.7232 (0.5084)* 0.0061 (0.0008)* ×Education: HS degree -1.3803 (0.8673) 0.0026 (0.0008)* ×Education: College degree 1.0463 (0.9872) 0.0033 (0.0010)* ×Education: Unknown -1.2771 (0.8987) 0.0022 (0.0009)* ×Employed -0.5976 (0.3913) -0.0026 (0.0005)* ×Private insurance 3.0534 (0.3822)* 0.0035 (0.0005)* *P < 0.05 Standard errors are in parentheses. One-standard deviation increase in graft failure rate for a hospital ⇒ 7% decline in registrations If all registrants were privately insured: -0.22 [95% CI: -0.29, -0.15]. One-standard deviation increase in graft failure rate ⇒ 11% decline in registrations If all registrants were in Medicare: -0.03 [95% CI: -0.10, 0.04]. One-standard deviation increase in graft failure rate ⇒ 2% decline in registrations 23 24 4 Porter & Teisberg’s Ingredients for Change To sum up: evidence is consistent with plans’ claims. No Restrictions to Competition and Choice • No preapprovals for referrals or treatments • No network restrictions • Strict antitrust enforcement against collusion, excessive concentration, and unfair practices • Meaningful co-payments and medical savings accounts with high deductibles, all of which will give consumers incentives to seek good value Caveats No data on prices Endogeneity? Only observe static effects-dynamic effects may be more important 25 Accessible Information • Appropriate information on treatments and alternatives is formally collected and widely disseminated. • Information about providers‘ experience in treating particular diseases and conditions is made available immediately. • Risk-adjusted outcome data are developed and continually enhanced. • Some information is standardized nationally to enable comparisons. Porter & Teisberg’s Ingredients for Change Porter & Teisberg’s Ingredients for Change No Restrictions to Competition and Choice • No preapprovals for referrals or treatments • No network restrictions • Strict antitrust enforcement against collusion, excessive concentration, and unfair practices • Meaningful co-payments and medical savings accounts with high deductibles, all of which will give consumers incentives to seek good value No Restrictions to Competition and Choice • No preapprovals for referrals or treatments • No network restrictions • Strict antitrust enforcement against collusion, excessive concentration, and unfair practices • Meaningful co-payments and medical savings accounts with high deductibles, all of which will give consumers incentives to seek good value Accessible Information • Appropriate information on treatments and alternatives is formally collected and widely disseminated. • Information about providers‘ experience in treating particular diseases and conditions is made available immediately. • Risk-adjusted outcome data are developed and continually enhanced. • Some information is standardized nationally to enable comparisons. Accessible Information • Appropriate information on treatments and alternatives is formally collected and widely disseminated. • Information about providers‘ experience in treating particular diseases and conditions is made available immediately. • Risk-adjusted outcome data are developed and continually enhanced. • Some information is standardized nationally to enable comparisons. 27 26 28 5