When You Have a Hammer, Everything Looks Like a Nail: Medicaid Bed-hold Policy and Medicare SNF Re-hospitalizations David C. Grabowski, Harvard Zhanlian Feng, Brown Orna Intrator, Brown Vincent Mor, Brown Funded by: Robert Wood Johnson HCFO; P01 AG27296 (PI: Mor); R01 AG20557(PI: Mor); R01 AG23622 (PI: Mor); NIA R01 AG30079 (PI: Grabowski); Data Use Agreement: #12432 Background • NH market consists of two distinct patient populations – Chronically ill, long-stay residents, mainly financed by Medicaid – Post-acute, short-stay residents mainly financed by Medicare • Although there is specialization, majority of Medicare (87%) residents are cared for alongside Medicaid recipients (and vice versa) Commonality in NH Care? • There may be care “spillovers” across Medicaid and Medicare NH residents due to: – Federal laws prohibiting discrimination by payer type – Economies of joint production – Cost shifting – Professional norms Previous NH Literature • • • • • Using 1983 Texas Medicaid cost report data, McKay (1989) found that the mix of Medicaid and private-pay residents did not affect a facility’s marginal, average or total costs Troyer (2004) found similar mortality across Medicaid and privatepayers within facilities Grabowski, Gruber, Angelelli (2008) found 12 QMs to be relatively common within facilities and within persons following spend-down Konetzka et al. (2006a; 2006b) found that Medicare SNF PPS affected QMs for long-stay residents No empirical work to date on Medicaid policy and Medicare outcomes State Medicaid Policy • State Medicaid programs have much discretion in setting payment methods and rates • Large literature showing Medicaid payment policies matter for Medicaid quality – Bed-hold policies pay NHs to hold empty bed while Medicaid recipient is hospitalized • Good news: promote continuity of care (Intrator et al., 2009) • Bad news: presence of bed-hold policy associated with 36% higher odds of hospitalization among long-stay (~Medicaid) residents (Intrator et al., 2007) • Does Medicaid bed-hold matter for short-stay SNF re-hospitalizations? Data and Cohort • Minimum Data Set (MDS) to identify first-time admissions over the period 2000 thru 2005 (N=3,307,263 in 15,506 facilities) • Facility data from CMS Online Survey Certification and Reporting (OSCAR) system. • Medicare claims of all re-hospitalizations within 30 days of discharge • Medicaid payment data from surveys of state Medicaid office (Grabowski et al 2004; 2007) General Empirical Approach Yijt = β1BEDHOLDjt + γXijt + ηj + νt + εijt Where: Yijt is 30-day re-hospitalization for person i in SNF j at time t BED_HOLDjt is coded using two different schemes Xijt is a vector of person, NH level and policy control variables ηj = facility fixed effects t = quarter fixed effects εijt is a randomly distributed error term Coding State Bed-hold Policies • Scheme I: Dichotomous • 1=Policy in place, 0=Policy not in place • Scheme II: Equivalent Reimbursement Days (ERD) • ERD = (% Rate) * (Annualized max # days) Methods • Estimated using linear probability model • Clustered standard errors by facility Unadjusted 30-day re-hospitalization rate, by state bed-hold policy (Y/N) 30-Day Re-hospitalization Results Bed-Hold ERD Other covariates Facility FE Quarter fixed effects N Model 1 0.0028+ Model 2 --- --- 0.0002** Y Y Y 3,307,263 Y Y Y 3,307,263 ** p<.01, * p<.05, + p<.10 Magnitude of Estimates • Using the bed-hold “dummy” specification, the introduction of a bed hold increases Medicare rehospitalizations by 1.5% of average, which represents… – ~10,000 hospitalizations over 2000-2005 period at a total cost of $84 million • Using the ERD specification, one SD (21-day) increase in ERD raises Medicare re-hospitalizations by 2.2% of average, which represents… – ~15,000 hospitalizations over 2000-2005 period at a total cost of $124 million Summary of Results • Across both specifications, results suggest modest relationship between bed-hold and re-hospitalizations • Supports the idea that Medicare NH outcomes are related to Medicaid NH policies Implications • There are benefits to bed-hold in terms of continuity of care (Intrator et al., 2009) • However, the increased risk of hospitalization outweigh these benefits – Direct risks to long-stayers (Intrator et al., 2007) – Indirect risks to short-stayers (this paper) • Bed-hold is a lose-lose-lose for beneficiary, Medicare, Medicaid – Only potential winners are providers Implications (cont.) • There are often externalities to Medicaid/Medicare policy decisions • Medicare and Medicaid rarely consider welfare of other program’s beneficiaries – Even though beneficiaries are often dually eligible! • There would be efficiency gains if both programs would internalize these costs and benefits as they pertain to the other program – Collaboration of States & Feds • Medicare-only solutions like bundling won’t solve this issue.