The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 WhatfollowsisatranscriptoftheEighthAnnualHansLandsbergMemorialLecture“ThePorter HypothesisAfter20Years:HowCanEnvironmentalRegulationEnhanceInnovationand Competitiveness?”heldatResourcesfortheFutureonJanuary19,2011.Ithasbeenlightlyeditedand willnotcorrelateverbatimwiththevideorecording. Phil Sharp: My name is Phil Sharp, and I’m delighted to be president of Resources for the Future (RFF). I welcome you today to our eighth annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture, a lecture series that honors the pioneering work that Hans Landsberg did in energy and mineral economics and his many years of service to Resources for the Future—and some of the key issues that this nation has faced. We’re very pleased again this year to have with us his daughter, Ann, and her husband, Tim Baehr. Welcome back. Let me just say one word briefly about today’s topic on which many words will be said by people who are very significant in this field, in particular our very distinguished speaker. The impact of regulation on innovation and competition in this country is, of course, an issue that has intensified in the last couple of years and even the last couple of weeks in this country. There’s no doubt about the importance of trying to understand the relationship of the various forces involved between government, corporations, business, and community at large; indeed, as the new Congress has just met, the new Republican leadership in the House of Representatives has made it clear that one of their strong focuses is going to be on examination of the regulatory systems in our government today. This week the president of the United States, in a letter to the editor of the Wall Street Journal, made it very clear that this has become a prominent issue on his agenda for his administration and issued the Executive Order calling for government-wide review of regulations. This issue has been important for many years, and we at RFF have been deeply involved—our scholars have—in a variety of facets. Our scholars, including Hans Landsberg, have been pioneers in the development of analytical tools by which to measure and judge various regulatory systems. They have been pioneers in creating designs that hopefully are more cost-effective ways for us to approach the issues that society has decided to regulate. They have been deeply involved in how to evaluate policies that we’ve had in place as well as determine their value to our society and whether or not they are meeting the goals that were established. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 1 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 In the last couple of years, our folks have been deeply involved especially on climate issues, but on others as well around these issues. We saw our folks being asked to consult on these kinds of questions with the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative of the New England states and the California government as it decides how to create a carbon market to regulate carbon dioxide. And certainly our folks have been engaged at the White House and on Capitol Hill over the last several years on a host of these issues, especially surrounding competitiveness and how to design effective policy. We certainly intend for that to be a continuing focus for a good deal of our research as well. Today we’re delighted to have—in addition to our highly talented speakers—a number of folks in our audience that I’d like to recognize. I want to be very clear that we consider everybody here a distinguished guest at RFF, but I do want to recognize a couple of people in that process. We’re very delighted to have with us the former director of the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), Bill Reilly, who is currently cochair of the Oil Spill Commission, which has just produced a very significant report. We’re delighted to have with us Frank Loy. Frank Loy is a former assistant secretary of state who was very much involved in climate negotiations among others on behalf of the United States, and he’s been chairman and vice chairman of our Board of Directors. We’re very pleased to have with us former Congressman Sherry Boehlert. Sherry was chairman of the House Science Committee. We also have with us the former governor of Alaska, Tony Knowles. Tony is also president of the recently founded National Energy Policy Institute that has worked very closely with our scholars on a major report on trying to assess various policy choices in the field of energy. Our program today is being cosponsored by the Sustainable Prosperity Organization, which is a new policy research network in Canada, and we’re very delighted to have with us its founder and chair, Stewart Elgie, to make a couple remarks. He is a law professor at the University of Ottawa. Stewart Elgie: Thanks, Phil. As Phil said, I’m the chair of Sustainable Prosperity, which is a horrible name. No one can pronounce it. But it’s a green economy think tank in Canada, and we’re very pleased to be cohosting this event Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 2 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 with RFF. And not just because it got me out of Ottawa, where it was –25º yesterday, although I’d be lying if I said that wasn’t a factor. This is my first visit to RFF, and I have to say, I’m blown away. I’ve heard people call this a mecca for environmental economics and policy, and I now know why they say that. We don’t have anything like this in Canada, although we’re trying to change that, as I’ll explain in a minute. Let me disclose quickly a national secret for Canada, which is that a major part of our national identity is obsessing over ways that we’re better than the United States. It’s a long list, of course, starting with hockey and beer. But I have to confess to some envy over the wealth of good think tanks that you have here, and RFF for me is at the top of that list. So it’s a real privilege to be here today. I can’t think of any more important or timely topic to be discussing than the Porter Hypothesis. From its origins 20 years ago, it’s had a truly profound impact on the way in which we think about the relationship between regulation, environment, and economy around the world. I can say a lot about that impact. For example, “Porter Hypothesis” has 452,000 hits on a Google Scholar search. You can drop that tip at a dinner party some night. But I’d like to say a little bit about its impact on me and my life—so, the Oprah approach, the speaker introduction. I’m a recovering environmental lawyer. I spent 15 years of my original career founding and then running Canada’s major public-interest environmental law firm, taking the bad guys to court. And at some point, I came to realize that most of them weren’t actually bad guys. I’ve never met a CEO who woke up one morning thinking, how do I mess up the planet today? They woke up thinking, how do I make a profit? It turned out that largely because we operate an economic system, it doesn’t count environmental costs. It encourages them, and all of us, to behave in unsustainable ways. That breakthrough insight as a lawyer led me to change careers, go back to Yale about eight years ago, and do a doctorate environmental law and economics with Dan Esty, shifting from the most hated profession to the most dismal profession. One of the first articles I read there, in Nat Keohane’s course, was an article by Michael Porter, and the last paragraph said this: countries need an entirely new way of thinking about the relationship between environment and competitiveness. No lasting success can come from policies that promise environmentalism will triumph over industry or vice Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 3 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 versa. Success must involve innovative-based solutions that promote both environmentalism and industrial competitiveness. It was one of those moments where someone wrote exactly what you were thinking, but 10 years earlier, showing you that your ideas weren’t really that original. But they were ideas that were ahead of their time. Porter’s words and the spirit behind them inspired me when I came back to Canada to create Sustainable Prosperity. The simplest way to describe Sustainable Prosperity is that it’s the closest thing we have to RFF in Canada, although we have a long way to go before we can really compare ourselves. It’s both a green economy think tank and a network of economy scholars from across Canada, with a few from outside Canada as well, focusing on market-based approaches for both a stronger and a greener economy. It also links in business and policy leaders so good ideas can form policy development. So in some ways, Michael, you played a role in the creation of Sustainable Prosperity, unwittingly perhaps. Six months ago, we did round one of this event in Montreal. We hosted an event that brought together more than 70 scholars from four continents who had done research on the Porter Hypothesis and spent the whole day exploring its various branches, trying to pull together what we’d learned over 20 years of research. If you’re interested, you can go to http://www.sustainableprosperity.ca, click on events, and you can see the PowerPoint presentations from a variety of people breaking out the different branches of the Porter Hypothesis. And just a little plug, by the way, tomorrow night four of the world’s top economists will be debating the future of economic growth. Two have written books saying that economic growth has to end if we’re going to live sustainably. Two have said we can transform the nature of economic growth by dematerializing economic growth, sort of the Porter Hypothesis. They’re live webcasts, so if you want to go to the website, you can also whittle your evening away tomorrow. Back to the Porter Hypothesis conference: in addition to these presentations, Mark Cohen and I and two other authors pulled together a state-of-knowledge synthesis, trying to tie together all the research on the Porter Hypothesis over 20 years in 20 pages or less. That’s available out front if you haven’t picked it up. Again, it may be worth having a look at. And Mark managed to somehow convince the Review of Environmental Economics and Policy to do a special issue on the Porter Hypothesis at 20, which will run this year, presumably, and Michael will be contributing a Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 4 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 piece to that. So it really has spurred a lot of good thinking on an issue that needs it. One of the real benefits for me of this has been getting to know Mark Cohen. Mark and I share a passion for bridging the world of research and policy in business, and translating good ideas into real change. So it’s my pleasure to turn it over to Mark now. Mark is not only the vice president for research at Resources for the Future, but also a professor at Vanderbilt University. He has the daunting task of explaining the Porter Hypothesis before Michael Porter speaks. Mark Cohen: That is quite a task. Thank you. It’s a pleasure to be here and to once again work with Sustainable Prosperity on this very timely and important topic. My thanks particularly to Michael Porter for coming, and to Dan Esty and Chad Holliday, who we’ll introduce later to be on a panel. While some of this audience is intimately familiar with the Porter Hypothesis, we’re not all on the same page. To some of you, it might be a new concept. To get us on the same page, Professor Porter asked me to briefly introduce the Porter Hypothesis and give you some background. As Stewart said, outside there is a paper that this introduction is based on, and you’ll have access to that paper. I’ll go through it very quickly because you didn’t come to hear me—you came to hear Professor Porter. The best way to introduce the Porter Hypothesis is to start with what we all learned in Economics 101 about environmental regulation: that it’s costly. It costs us hundreds of billions of dollars to comply. It takes up a big percentage of GNP. It costs us jobs. You know the story. Well, that was the story, and that’s the story I think a lot of us grew up on. In 1991 an article by Michael Porter in Scientific American— that’s on your seats—titled “America’s Green Strategy,” questioned this conventional wisdom. Now what did the Porter Hypothesis say? First it said that strict but flexible environmental regulation leads to innovation. Now people have analyzed this, and we now call that the weak version of the Porter Hypothesis, partly because it’s not that difficult to buy into. Innovation, new technologies, new ways of doing business: that’s what you expect to happen. Of course, the point of regulation is to improve environmental performance. So there’s no surprise over the next link—that is, if you have Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 5 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 more innovation, you expect better environmental performance. That’s not controversial. The controversial part is at what cost. The surprising and controversial part of the Porter Hypothesis goes further and states that innovation then often may lead to improved business performance and, in fact, national competitiveness. That’s what’s often called the strong version of the Porter Hypothesis. The initial reaction to the Porter Hypothesis was swift and largely negative, mostly by the economics profession—not surprising. The traditional economic response was that if there’s such low-hanging fruit, why don’t firms know about it? Why is $20 on the ground, and they’re not picking it up? And I think the second reaction was, where’s the empirical evidence? Like good economists, they said, “Show us the money. Where’s the evidence?” I should note very quickly that like most famous theories—and it has become famous—the Porter Hypothesis is often misquoted. Often you’ll hear this: all regulation leads to innovation. No, it doesn’t say that. It says that well-designed regulation does. So there’s a distinction between any kind of regulation and well-designed regulation. That’s very important. And the second thing the Porter Hypothesis does not say is that innovation always offsets the cost of regulation. It says that it often does, and may well. And that’s the empirical question. Over the past 20 years, the impact, as Stewart alluded to, has been profound. There have literally been hundreds of studies testing, explaining, and trying to understand from a theoretical standpoint why this could be. On a personal note, the Porter Hypothesis had a strong influence on my own research in the early and mid-nineties. I did a lot of empirical work looking at those issues. And as a business school professor at Vanderbilt—I started teaching courses on environmental management in 1993—the first thing that you would do was read the Porter piece. Not surprisingly, the Porter Hypothesis has strong links to research at RFF, where our researchers have published dozens of studies on topics such as the impact of environmental regulation on productivity, innovation, and competitiveness, and we continue to work in that area. In terms of management education, thousands of MBA students have been taught the Porter Hypothesis and the potential value of the sustainable enterprise. It’s had a rather important impact in the business school Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 6 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 community. And of course, it’s had a very big impact in the public policy arena. I’m going to say a few things about that very briefly. Dan Esty, who I will introduce later, will most likely spend a little time talking about that. Its most profound effect is probably on the business practice itself. We have a very great representative of the business community, Chad Holliday, who will also be up to say a few remarks later on how this relates to business. Why would properly crafted regulation lead to a positive outcome? There are many ideas behind this, but let me just touch upon three of them very quickly. One is that firm managers might not act in the best interest of shareholders. They may have short-term focus, may be risk adverse, may be shirking, et cetera. Regulation might force top managers to do things that are in shareholders’ interest but might not be in their own interest. It also might reduce uncertainty of investments in environmental protection. It’s very important for business to have certain regulations as opposed to uncertainty. Regulation also will raise corporate awareness and provide external pressure on a topic that might otherwise be lost in the shuffle. There are so many things that businesses have to deal with on a day-to-day basis. But I don’t want to go into all of this right now. I just want to give you a flavor of how we got here. So what is the empirical evidence? Not surprisingly, there is plenty of evidence for the weak version that regulation spurs innovation. Oftentimes it’s measured by patents, but others have looked at it in a different way. So the evidence is pretty strong that, yes, regulation spurs innovation. In terms of the strong version, if we look at regulation and business performance and productivity, the evidence is mixed but growing. The earlier studies—many of which were looking at 1970s and early 1980s data—found a negative relationship between productivity and regulation. More recent data and studies that are looking across a longer timeframe longitudinally are finding evidence of a positive relationship. So there’s very interesting movement in terms of the academic research and the literature in this area. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 7 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 The previous slide spoke about the business-level performance, but as I said, the strong version also has this nation-level performance. What about the impact of regulation on a nation’s competitiveness? Here, there’s some evidence. It’s not fully resolved. Let me tell you, as somebody who’s been in this area trying to do research, it’s extremely difficult. The best thing I think we can say right now is there’s no evidence that countries with strict environmental regulations lose competitiveness. And there’s some evidence suggesting the relationship may be, in fact, positive. There’s a lot more to it than that, but I just wanted to give you a very quick flavor. I want to end with policy implications. One is very clear: regarding environmental policies, performance and market-based policies are preferred. That’s something near and dear to the heart of RFF. Second, there are direct implications for industrial patent policy. If you want to spur innovation, that’s obviously one thing you want to look at. And the third big category is a reminder of the importance of organizational and governance conditions, such as transparency and makeup of the board of directors. The bottom line is aligning shareholders’ interests with the board of directors can often be important if we believe that that’s part of the issue. It’s my great pleasure to introduce Michael Porter. He’s the Bishop William Lawrence University Professor of Harvard Business School and founder of the Harvard’s Institute for Strategy and Competitiveness. Professor Porter is the father of the field of modern corporate strategy. Porter’s Five Forces and other theories of strategy are rooted in his training as an economist. Like RFF researchers though, who are mostly economists, Professor Porter is grounded in both economic theory and reality—in his case, the reality of the modern business organization. Every business school student in the world since the 1980s knows who Michael Porter is and has read his work. I can attest to that—my daughter has as well. It’s not an exaggeration to say that he is the world’s most influential thinker on management and competitiveness. With that, I introduce you to Michael Porter. Michael Porter: Well, Mark, that was just a tiny bit embarrassing, but I thank you, and I feel very, very welcome here at RFF. I feel very much at home, and I’m extremely grateful for the opportunity to be here today to deliver this distinguished lecture. And I want to thank RFF, Phil, Mark, and others, for Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 8 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 their tremendous interest in this work, and the tremendous work that this organization is doing. As you’ll see later, I think this is the kind of think tank and NGO we need. There are others that I wouldn’t say that about in this field, that I don’t think are helping, but I think this organization is making a phenomenal impact. I want to recognize Dan Esty and Bill Reilly. I wouldn’t be here or even have known about this topic if it weren’t for getting to know Dan and Bill quite some years ago. It was the collaboration with them that led to this work and this paper. Also, a little known fact is that the research assistant on the article in which I introduce the Porter Hypothesis was Ben Esty, Dan’s brother. He is now a full professor at Harvard Business School and was my student at the time. So there’s a tremendous sense of family and kinship in this work with these two here sitting in the front row and others at EPA in those days who were really looking for new and innovative ways of thinking about regulation and how to do regulation. I want to recognize and thank Stewart Elgie, first of all for being one of the coauthors of this marvelous survey paper. You’re never happy with everything in a survey paper, but this is a great survey paper, and I think it’s extraordinarily useful in pulling together a very large string of literature that I’m very proud has come out of my one-page article. And by the way, I had to write another, longer article to deal with all the incoming missiles that were being fired. But ultimately, I think Stewart, Mark, and their colleagues have done a great job, and I commend this to you: that for all of us who are interested in this topic of environmental regulation, the article has just a wealth of insight about this question. It’s more than a review article. It’s a value-added review article that adds a lot of new ideas, at least for me as I think about this. Finally, Chad Holliday is somebody I know well and I’ve worked with in the past. What an honor, Chad, for you to be here. I’m really appreciative of that. As was said by Mark, I think this topic is—the reason we’re here probably mostly is because the original article was written in 1991, so this is the 20year anniversary. But I think the timing is not just about the twentieth anniversary. I think this whole question of American competitiveness and the role of regulation in American competitiveness has really risen again Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 9 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 to the top—or very near the top—of the radar screen in the debate in this country. At the same time there’s a tremendous angst and even tension between business and government—the private sector and the public sector—and how those two parties can either work collaboratively or competitively in addressing some of the most important challenges facing America and our society. So I think this question of the Porter Hypothesis is in a sense an issue that won’t quit, and it’s also a metaphor, as we’ll see later, for a lot of other issues and how we are tackling those issues from a governmental and policy point of view. What I’d like to do very briefly in this session—and hopefully not take too much time—is cover four topics. One you might be interested in—because I think it will be somewhat educational for today’s issues—is how this hypothesis emerged. Why would I be crazy enough to put out this idea? I’m a card-carrying economist. I have a PhD from Harvard in economics. How could I possibly have put out this idea? Where did it come from? I think the answer is it came from a number of threads and bodies of thinking and research that were quite different from the mainstream work that was going on in economics that had led people to conclude the opposite of the hypothesis. Going through that will be helpful because it lays some important groundwork that we can build upon. Secondly, I’d like to reflect a little bit on what’s changed since the original article was written. I can be very brief there because I think both Mark and Stewart have done a good job of capturing a little bit of the empirical evidence and what’s happened since. I’d like to summarize some of the implications that this body of work has today for the way we’re thinking about regulation in general and for the way we’re thinking about environmental regulation. I’d like to use, in addition to some general principles, a case study. Dan Esty and I have written an op-ed that hopefully will appear shortly about climate change and how we think about regulation in the area of climate change. We’ve had sort of checkered history in America over the last few years. And the question is, if we applied the thinking in this work—thinking, by the way, that Dan and I have written about over the subsequent years—how would we approach the regulation around the Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 10 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 issue of climate change? I think it’s a very telling and a very immediate example of how perhaps we could have done this better if we could have broader consensus about this basic approach. Then if we have time—and I’ll calibrate the time as we get there— I’d also like to suggest that this Porter Hypothesis, this basic idea that addressing a societal issue in the right way with the right regulatory environment, can actually enhance competitiveness of the company—and can be applied to many more societal issues. Since I wrote this little paper, I’ve worked on a whole variety of other topics, like health, healthcare, safety, and economically distressed communities. What comes to the forward time and time again is some of the same underlying principles. Out of that conviction and that body of work has come another article that you hopefully will pick up called “Creating Shared Value,” which is in the current issue of the Harvard Business Review. I think copies are available to pick up if anybody’s interested. It talks a little bit about how the same philosophy embedded in the Porter Hypothesis applies to all manner of the corporation’s impacts or touch points with society. I’d like to give you some of the highlights of that thought, and then, of course, we’ll have time for hopefully some discussion. So where did the Porter Hypothesis emerge from? First and foremost, it emerged from an empirical observation. After an arduous five-year process, I had written a book called The Competitive Advantage of Nations. In that book I had looked at 10 major industrial countries from many continents, and I’d really been trying to get at the question of why some countries are competitive in certain fields. Why is America so dominant in software? Why are the Japanese so phenomenally strong in consumer electronics? Why are the Germans so good in machinery and automobiles? What explains the origins of competitiveness? To really understand competitiveness, we couldn’t look at the nation as a whole. We had to look at the specific fields within the nation in which the nation had emerged and become an innovator and a leader. In the course of writing that book, I had looked at hundreds of different industries across many, many different countries, and I kept noticing something. I kept noticing that there were often very strict standards and regulations in a particular country in a particular field, yet that country was competitive in that field. I kept noticing that over and over again. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 11 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Out of that came this notion that we could see not a conflict between strict environmental regulation and competitiveness, but we could see a complimentary—that these things could actually reinforce each other. But what became clear from looking at all this country experience was that there was a critical piece to make that connection work, and that was designing the regulation, the regulatory process, and the regulatory standards themselves in the right way. The right way meant stimulating an ambition rather than simply imposing cost that the firm could do nothing but bear. That empirical observation led to the Porter Hypothesis. Actually this article was solicited by the editor of Scientific American, who had read the book and noticed this observation that had been made a number of times in the book. The editor said, “Gee, would you write a little article on it?” So this turned into a one-page article. And little did I know that here we would be today. But I’m extremely proud of this work. I’m also extremely proud of the literature that’s grown out of that article because, as I hope you picked up from Mark’s summary, this is a literature that’s focused on the facts. It’s focused on empirical evidence, and the nuance and richness of the understanding of the issues and the theory has simply grown, and grown, and grown over time. If more of the research in economics was like this, we’d be a lot better off because it’s targeted at real issues. It’s dealing with very practical on-the-ground problems of great importance for our society. So I’m very proud of the literature that grew out of this work. Now why might I have taken those empirical observations seriously? Why might I believe that every firm wasn’t optimizing its environmental performance already, which was what the theory said? Why might I believe that innovation and the use of resources, like minimizing environmental impacts, might actually enhance competitiveness? Why might I think that the regulatory environment could be a profound driver of innovation? Well, all these things were coming at me from a body of work that I had been doing over a number of years, and so let’s just talk about some of the key points. When economists think about firms—at least historically—they think of a firm as a very simple thing. A firm is a production function. It takes labor and capital and converts it into output. The conception of a firm is as an optimizing vehicle with full information. The firm knows pretty much everything out there. The firm as a production function optimizes the output at every moment in time and maximizes profit. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 12 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 But as we were studying firms and trying to understand competitive advantage, we came to understand that firms are anything but simple. Firms are incredibly complex, and this concept of the value chain was one of the core frameworks that I introduced in the strategy work that I’d been doing in the 1980s largely. The value chain just is a representation that the firm is a complex set of activities, that firms are involved in doing business in hundreds of different activities and processes: procurement, operations, marketing, customer service, information technology (IT), technology development—hundreds and hundreds of activities. These activities and the choices that the company makes ultimately result in the competitive advantage of the firm. All competitive advantage in a firm grows out of the ability to perform some of these activities in a unique and distinctive way. All of a sudden, the idea that every firm would know everything about all the choices that it could possibly make in that value chain and had thought of all the opportunities to improve environmental performance simply became unrealistic. Every firm makes mistakes every day. Economists have a hard time dealing with this. They think of the firm as optimizing— and maybe it does in some sense of optimizing with limited information— but firms have too many things to do. There are too many issues to worry about. There are many complex choices to be made. There are hundreds of investment projects, hundreds of different places where you could put capital. It is very hard to measure the return on many of those things. In a world where firms are like this, it became very plausible that by riveting the attention of the firm on important issues like energy use and emissions, regulation would potentially have a profound impact on where the firm put its energy in terms of innovation and where it put its capital in terms of investment. So part of the story here in the Porter Hypothesis is a much more complex view of what firms are really like. If we want to be successful in regulation, we have to embody and embrace this view of what firms are actually like, the complexity and the multitude of choices, the lack of information, and the limited bandwidth that firms have. That has profound effects on how regulators need to do their job, which we’ll talk about later. In addition to developing a conception of the firm that was quite different than the traditional neoclassical view of the firm in economics, we also were in a period where we were starting to develop a very different conception of competitiveness. The traditional conception of Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 13 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 competitiveness that I encountered when I came into the field was that competitiveness is about cost minimization. People would say you’re competitive if you have low wages. You’re competitive if your currency is low. You’re competitive if your costs are low. What became clear is that actually that’s not necessarily true; moreover, it’s a very bad way of thinking about competitiveness from the point of view of social progress. We don’t want low wages. We want to create an environment where we can support high wages. Therefore, as we came to understand the countries that are prosperous, we realized the countries that are competitive are the countries that are productive, can utilize resources productively, and can drive productivity growth over time. This conception of competitiveness put a very different light on the question of environmental regulation because if you have a very shortterm narrow cost perspective about competitiveness, then you’re much more likely to think that environmental regulation is an unambiguous negative. But if you have a productivity growth perspective of competitiveness and realize that the environment involves the use of many resources, then all of a sudden the idea isn’t so crazy that if regulation somehow stimulated innovation, that could improve competitiveness. This was the sensibility with which I was thinking during this period, and I have continued to work in this area since. The third piece here was, what’s the role of location in competitiveness and productivity growth? What we came to understand is that location matters a lot. Where the company is based and the environment surrounding the company can have a profound effect on how competitive and productive it could be. In particular, as I’ve highlighted here, the work we did on competitiveness was really suggesting the profound impact of what we call demand conditions: the signals that the company is getting from the customer, from the marketplace, about the standards, quality, or the features that the company needs to meet. Let me tell you one funny story. You all probably know this, but the Japanese are the world’s leader in global positioning systems (GPS). All the leading innovators and the dominant players in that area are Japanese. Now you might say, “Why aren’t the Americans the innovators in GPS?” because, of course, we were the ones that put up these satellites and had all the IT that would seem to make us the natural player. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 14 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 The answer is demand conditions. In Japan, addresses are not consecutive. So if you go on a street, it’s not house number one, house number three, house number four. Addresses are kind of random. If you don’t know exactly where the house is, you can’t find it in any simple process. So the Japanese have this incredible need for GPS, just like they had an incredible need for fax machines because the typewriters and telexes of the day didn’t work with Japanese characters. In that case, they had to have a way of transmitting handwritten documents because most documents in Japan were handwritten. Those are cases where the demand conditions—the nature of the local needs—have a profound effect on innovation. In America, we thought of the fax machine and the GPS as curiosities, toys for people who had everything. In Japan, the fax machine was a business necessity. In Japan, the GPS was critical. That was even before you added the legendary traffic jams in Tokyo. In Japan when you tune onto your GPS, it’ll tell you exactly where the traffic jams are. They’re way ahead of us. They already embodied that technology into the GPS system. Why? Because there was an incredible demand. There was an incredible need. What we came to understand is that environmental regulation is one of those demand conditions. By setting environmental standards in the right way, by setting them relatively high, you really stimulate innovation or can stimulate innovation. We see that over and over and over again in industry after industry. So again, if one has a narrow view of the firm as maximizing profits every moment in time and a narrow view that competitiveness is about lowering short-term costs, that person would think the Porter Hypothesis was complete lunacy. But if one has this perspective described above on the firm and competitiveness, all of a sudden one’s mind is opened to a broader approach. One corollary of the concept of competitiveness and the role of location is the notion of clusters—that competitiveness doesn’t arise in isolated firms. Competitiveness arises in critical masses of firms in a particular location that feed off each other. This slide is a pictorial of the life sciences cluster in Massachusetts, which is probably the strongest life sciences concentration of firms and institutions in the world. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 15 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 There are a lot of synergies where you have all these companies in the same location and you get a lot of efficiencies, opportunities for dynamism and innovation, and new business formation. We have increasing data on that. We see clusters in every industry all over the world. Here’s a representation of the wind power cluster in Spain. Spain is doing really well in international competition in the area of wind power. Part of that has to do with some demand conditions, some ways of regulating and supporting that industry. But the point is that in the modern conception of competitiveness, progress is collaborative. In the old top-down view of competitiveness and government policy, government drives competitiveness. Government sets the rules. Firms are passive actors. In a world of innovation and productivity, in a world where firms have many different choices about how to create unique strategies and how to develop unique products and processes, all of a sudden any economic progress is collaborative. We know from studying many, many countries and successes in competitiveness and economic development that successful progress is going to require us to not see the various actors or stakeholders in society as competing with each other, but finding areas where they can be aligned to actually drive more rapid progress. Again, all of these ideas start to give us a broader basis on which to think that the role of environmental regulation can be very different than it was historically believed to be. What’s happened since? I would say that there’s been extraordinary uptake in business about the potential of environmental improvement to lower costs, improve processes, and ultimately drive, in many cases, competitiveness. Many companies have embraced this more rapidly than I could have expected. I think the original impetus for this uptake was really corporate social responsibility (CSR). Initially companies felt, “We need to do this to be good citizens.” But I think increasingly as every year goes by, the uptake in business is much more around the notion that this actually is good for the company: “This is good for business. This will make us more competitive. This will improve our efficiency. This will improve our resource utilization. And this will improve our products and their acceptance by the customer.” So I think the biggest success has been probably in the business community. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 16 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 There certainly has been some uptake of these ideas in the regulatory world outside the United States quite broadly. In the United States, I think it’s been a bit of a mixed bag. In some areas, we see this thinking about regulation really deployed and in other areas not. So I would call this a mixed picture. In the NGO community, again, there’s a mixed picture. I think now more and more of the leading NGOs are starting to want to work collaboratively with business and understand that working around this notion of win–win is the best way to actually make progress rather than using the old-style NGO model of embarrass, litigate, and shame the private sector. I think there’s progress there, but again, it’s not complete yet. Probably in many ways, the most important thing that’s happened is the shift in societal values. I think values in society have moved dramatically pro-environment, particularly among the younger people. I think that has fueled the greater focus and shifting thinking about the environment in the business community, in particular, because I think they perceived that the reward for the societal values attached to that kind of activity have been enhanced. I think this is one of the great opportunities we have right now, that we have a younger cohort in our society that believes deeply in the environment. They believe deeply in dealing with some of the most important problems we’re facing in society: the problems of poverty, economic opportunity, and nutrition. I certainly know my daughters who are college-age just think very differently about this set of issues, and I’m sure your children and grandchildren do as well. I think that’s a tremendous asset we have because if that’s true, they’re going to be the employees of the companies in the future, and they’re going to be the consumers who are buying products and valuing different products in terms of their attributes. They’re also hopefully going to be enlightened NGO and government leaders, and we hopefully can capitalize on that new energy and caring about some of these issues. That said, I want to be absolutely clear: there are still a lot of people—and I will say that there are still a lot of people in this town—who believe that the relationship between environmental improvement and the corporation is inherently adversarial. And there are lots of political obstacles still to fully embracing the thinking underlying the Porter Hypothesis—all kinds Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 17 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 of political obstacles that have to do with ideological positions that have been difficult to shed. I think there has been a curious flip of the Republican Party. I’m a Massachusetts Republican. I just want to be honest about that. In Massachusetts, Republicans are a very rare species. We are quite liberal on all social issues and quite conservative on economic issues. The Republican Party once was the champion of pro-innovation through market-oriented regulatory approaches. Now we have this curious flip where the Republican Party or at least some parts of the party have become in many ways an obstacle. So I think we have some real challenges. We can’t move on from this issue yet. We’re still in the middle of it. In the environmental arena in particular, it’s a very important question to be talking about today. That’s why I think this session is so timely, and that’s why I’m so pleased that all of you are here. What are the implications of the Porter Hypothesis for policy? Let me just expand a little bit on some of the points that Mark made. Basically the one-liner is “look for the win–win solution.” This says that there could be and can be often a win–win solution where we can improve environmental performance at the same time as we are making the company more productive, making it more innovative, improving the value of its products, and making it more competitive. We need to do everything we can to widen the circumstances where that can happen. That’s the oneliner—that therefore regulators need to see businesses as not an adversary. They need to see businesses as entities that hopefully they can understand well enough to engage and interact with in a way that allows these win– win opportunities. How would we translate that more specifically into regulatory choices? As has already been said, the Porter Hypothesis suggests that you set performance standards for environmental improvement, not specify how to achieve those standards. If you specify how to achieve those standards, you guarantee that there’ll be no innovation, and you cut off your nose to spite your face. And we still do that time and time and time again. A corollary to this is that we don’t subsidize particular technological solutions. We want to encourage investment, have investment tax credits, or have research and development tax credits that are neutral across technology—that might be a good thing. But we don’t want to try to have Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 18 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 somebody decide which technology is going to be the best way to innovate to deal with this environmental problem and make things better. That’s a real mistake. We’re working at cross-purposes to our fundamental goals when we do things like that. Number two, we want to utilize phase-in periods when we are incorporating or promulgating environmental standards. We want phase-in periods that are aligned with the time constant in the industries that we’re regulating and the new product cycles. Because if we try to force things at a pace that’s not aligned with the investment cycle in the industry, we will force firms to either reject or try to roll back the regulation, or we will actually drive up costs. But if we can get the regulatory timeline aligned with the business timeline, we’ll have a much higher opportunity to get that innovation solution than will the compliance or end-of-pipe type solution. Number three, we need to ensure as much as we possibly can a predictable evolution of standards over time. Ideally we’d like to know what those standards are going to look like over the next 20 years because many of these require long-term investments in technology and new operating methods, processes, and product designs. We want companies to have some predictability about where things are going because if they have that predictability, they’re more likely to get it right. They’re more likely to make that investment in trying to drive that innovation rather than either trying to reject the whole idea and take us to court or do some short-term and ultimately costly thing. Where appropriate, of course, we need to set prices on some of the underlying resources—whether it’s water or another resource that we’re concerned about—that reflect the true cost. Getting that true cost is often a complicated analytical question, but we at least need to start moving those resource prices toward the real cost rather than unwittingly subsidizing environmental inefficiency, which we do in many areas. We know that the right kind of regulation is regulation where there’s national and international harmonization of standards, where the United States isn’t doing it in a different way than everybody else. Ideally there’s a syncing-up of the states, and there’s a syncing-up of countries. Because the more we sync up the various jurisdictions, the greater the incentive to do the innovation, and the greater the disincentive to just do the short-term thing that drives up the cost. This is a very important issue in the area of climate change. We would ideally like to have a climate change regime Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 19 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 that’s relatively consistent around the world because that gives everybody incentive to innovate and ultimately improve their competitiveness. We also want to simplify the actual processes of regulation as much as we possibly can, rather than complicate it and make it time consuming. We want to make those processes more transparent if we possibly can. Ideally we would prefer to have very open reporting of how well the company is doing or what the company is actually achieving in terms of performance. We’d like a lot of transparency on performance standards and auditing of people who seem to be, for whatever reason, worth auditing, rather than forcing everybody through the same cumbersome, repetitive process over and over and over again, which is what we tend to do here. There’s no conflict between high standards and very efficient implementation of those standards. That’s the ideal world. We’re not talking about reducing the standards. We’re talking about how to actually enforce and achieve compliance with those standards, and there are a lot of different ways of doing that. For various legal and other reasons in America, we have made it truly an arduous process. And I think it works against our interests in the process. We also know Porter-Hypothesis thinking would suggest that there are at least a few other steps that we should also take. Regulation is not the whole strategy. We have to get the regulation right, but we also have to, number one, focus on measurement. The more we can measure and require measurement of performance by everybody in a consistent way, the more every company has to put out its performance on water, on energy, on emissions, on this, on that. The more those measurements are consistent and comparable, the more energy we’re going to get, and the more innovation we’re going to stimulate because companies are going to be comparing themselves; they’re going to be talking to the companies that are doing better. Their competitive juices are going to be flowing. So mandatory measurement becomes critical. Again, we do some of that, but we can do a lot more. Collaborative activity can often be a very effective way of stimulating more rapid progress on innovation. You have an industry or an industry cluster do some collaborative activity around particular environmental problems and technologies. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 20 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Also important are research and fusion of learning. There are all kinds of examples in the papers that are summarized in the survey paper where simply training people in how to deal with certain environmental problems in corporations can have a tremendous impact on speeding up the fusion of new technology and the rate of learning. Again, don’t assume that companies know everything. Don’t assume that they get everything right. That’s a bad assumption. Supporting research as part of the regulatory strategy, supporting training, and getting industry groups together to train each other all become really fundamental core strategies if what we’re really trying to achieve is an innovation solution and not a cost-increasing solution. In terms of corporate practice, we have to move beyond thinking of environmental issues as CSR. Corporate social responsibility is about philanthropy. It’s about image. It’s about giving. It’s about volunteering. It’s about being a good guy or a good lady: “Look at how we’re being good.” Those are great sentiments, and I don’t want to be negative about them, but if we want to really be effective in the corporation at this, we have to start treating it as a real business issue. We have to start looking at it not as CSR, but as a way of actually enhancing our productivity and our competitiveness. The companies that are making the most progress on environmental performance are the ones that have made that mentality shift: “This is not about being a good guy. This is not about dealing with the critics and the NGOs. This is really about a core business activity.” Environmental issues are becoming increasingly a strategic differentiator. More and more companies are finding that their ability to excel in this area is allowing them to get a competitive advantage against their competitors. It’s not just an operational matter; it’s a way of distinguishing the organization from its competitors. Let me take the last few minutes and try to widen this discussion a little bit. I think the fundamental idea of the Porter Hypothesis is that if we think about innovation and we think of the world in terms of dynamism and change, we can have environmental improvement while enhancing competitiveness. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 21 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 But what I’ve come to believe is that the same kind of mindset and the same kind of outcomes are possible in a variety of other areas of societal concern. This little schematic diagram just gives a few examples. Environmental impact as of 1991 was more about pollution than it is today. Today I think we’re seeing environmental impact as more also about energy use, water use, and a broader set of issues that are more extensively related to the use of natural resources. The Porter-Hypothesis thinking applies equally to all these broader definitions of environmental performance. It also applies to other corporate issues as well, like health, for example. I’ve been working extensively in the area of healthcare for the last six or seven years. Employers used to think of healthcare benefit costs as a cost to be minimized, and many companies tried very hard to even get out of the healthcare business altogether. But sometime over the last five or six years, most of the leading companies have had an epiphany, and you’re going to smile when you hear what that epiphany is. What they’ve learned by doing the math is that the health benefit costs are not the big cost. The big cost is the cost of poor health, absenteeism, people being at work but not really being productive, and the inability to retain staff. The current estimates are that the cost of poor health is about three or four times the cost of the health benefits. So all of a sudden, it doesn’t seem so smart to minimize the cost of the health benefits. What you want to do is spend the right amount on health benefits in the right way to maximize the health of your employee population—to control their diabetes, help with weight control, and implement health and wellness programs. There’s been a tremendous revolution in many corporations about the whole attitude toward health, healthcare, and health benefits. That’s an example of how it’s not just the environment; if you look at the issue from a deeper perspective, you all of a sudden see that it’s not a conflict between health benefits and competitiveness. You can actually align those to create an advantage. You can align those to help you improve your competitiveness; health benefits are not inevitably a drag. That same thinking can apply to areas like safety, skill building in the employer base, and a whole variety of other areas. That’s what this new article, “Creating Shared Value,” is all about. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 22 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 The basic idea in this article is that we can in many areas, by the way we go about addressing them in the corporation, actually enhance our competitiveness as a company while addressing some of the most important societal issues. The environment is exhibit A. We can have shared value. We can benefit the corporation. We can benefit the societal issue. The traditional view of the role of business in society has been what’s good for business is enough to be good for society: if it’s good for General Motors, it’s good for the country. I think what we’re starting to understand is that we need to turn that inside out: what’s good for the community and for citizens is good for business. Businesses now are starting to learn that issues like nutrition and health and environmental performance are actually some of the core tools to drive business performance and competitiveness, and to differentiate the company from its rivals. This is an opportunity to take the next step beyond CSR thinking. CSR thinking says, “Look, let’s run our business, but then on the side, we’ll have a corporate responsibility program to prove that we really care about the community, to comply, and to avoid doing harm.” This new philosophy says, “No, we have to go from CSR to CSV, creating shared value. We have to think about how to compete in a way that also creates value for society. And by the way, if we can identify and tackle some of these very important and pressing societal needs, that gives us a profound opportunity to actually improve our competitiveness.” It’s this kind of reversal of the thinking about the connection between the company and its society that I think we are starting to see the beginnings of. In the process, what we’re seeing also is a very interesting blurring between the boundaries of for-profit and nonprofit. In the old world, you were either a for-profit or you worked on social issues, because those twain never met. Dealing with social issues was about social issues, and that was different than running a business. Now what we’re seeing is organization after organization creating profitable business models to actually address very profound social issues, whether it’s nutrition, poverty, microfinance, or many others. I think we’re at the beginning of what I believe will be a decades-long process of rethinking and reconceiving how the role of the corporation fits within broader societal needs. I think that will be very good not only for the environmental movement, but for many other issues as well. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 23 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Time does not allow me to go into the details of creating shared value, but what are some of the key highlights? What we understand is that many products that companies sell don’t just meet economic needs or traditional consumer needs, but they also meet social needs. Food companies that had been used to getting people to consume too much and get fat are learning that they can differentiate themselves by helping people consume what they should consume and be healthy. This mindset could have happened decades ago, but I think we are now at a moment where this kind of different sort of thinking is emerging. There are many other examples of that. We are now starting to understand that productivity in the value chain is maybe not what we originally thought in the use of energy, in the role of logistics in the corporation, in the use of all kinds of natural resources, and in thinking about employee productivity and location, where we locate stuff. We’re seeing a profound revolution in our understanding about what’s really productive: is it really productive to ship a part from one continent to another in order to assemble it in a different location if we actually do the real math? We’re discovering that with the heightened awareness of environmental issues, the use of resources, emissions, and so forth, we are in the process of realigning value chains and redefining the supply chain in the global economy. I think that will be a very positive set of developments as well. We’re also understanding more and more that the surrounding community around the company can have a profound effect on that company’s productivity. Therefore, the company has a role in developing the cluster in the communities in which it’s operating rather than seeing that as somebody else’s job. Nestlé is an excellent example of a company that’s moving this direction, and there are some examples here that you can look at if you’re interested. This is just a case of espresso, one of the most wonderful strategy cases that I know of over the last decade or so, where Nestlé built a whole new coffee business in this giant corporation with a very different strategy than before. One of the keys to espresso success has been this notion of creating shared value: a whole new way of working with farmers, a whole new way of sourcing coffee beans, a whole new way that not only improves the supply Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 24 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 chain and improves the quality of the beans that it gets, which is critical to its strategy, but also has dramatic effects on environmental performance in the coffee-growing regions that creates shared value. All profit is not equal. Profit that accompanies shared value is a higher role for the corporation, and that’s the role that corporations today must strive for. Increasingly we’re going to see that the best strategies have a social dimension. They’re not just narrow economic strategies. They’re going to involve and embody these broader needs and issues that we’ve been talking about. Again, thank you all for the chance to talk about this. Those of you here who are in the business of regulation, I think that we have learned a lot about how to approach this question, and we’ve learned the tremendous power that can be achieved if we can find a way to create these opportunities for shared value, these opportunities for innovation. So hopefully as we approach issues like climate change and others, we can embody these principles. I look forward to the discussion following this to flesh out some of these ideas. Thank you very much for being here. Mark Cohen: Thank you so much, and we’re going to have questions in just a few minutes. But first I want to introduce our panel, and we’ll have a few remarks by Dan Esty. Full bios are in front of you. Dan is Hillhouse Professor of Environmental Law and Policy at Yale. He’s written extensively on environmental policy and corporate strategy, competitiveness, trade, et cetera, and most importantly was at EPA—I think he’ll talk a little bit about that—so he also has the government experience. I should say most importantly, he is a member of our Board of Directors at RFF. Chad Holliday is currently chairman of the Board of Bank of America. We probably all know him best as former CEO and chairman of the Board of DuPont, and he has numerous, numerous other affiliations: World Business Council, Business Roundtable. He’s been very much a business leader in the area of environment and sustainability, and transformed it in many, many ways. I want to turn it over to Dan for a few comments, then Chad, and then Phil will entertain questions with us. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 25 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Dan Esty: Mark, thank you very much. Phil, thank you, and really thanks to all of you for taking time out of busy days and schedules to be here and to reflect on 20 years of thinking about this Porter Hypothesis. I’m especially grateful to Mike Porter for coming today but even more for his intellectual leadership. Many in this room have thought about and some have written about this topic. I have built an entire career on it. I have worked at the business–environment interface for 20 years, thinking about how businesses need to bring environment and sustainability into strategy, and thinking about how policy needs to engage the business community. I want to reflect on my tracking of the Porter Hypothesis over 20 years and start where Mike Porter started, by saying I think we’re at an auspicious moment. There has been I think a very unhelpful debate over regulation in this country in the last couple of years, and we need to get it back on track. Frankly, I can’t think of a better institution to lead that process than RFF, so I am grateful to RFF for teeing up the conversation we’re having today. I hope very much that it goes beyond today and that we actually can see a push to get some of the conversation today into the discussions across this town. I want to share some thoughts on where I see progress having been made over 20 years and then raise some questions, or invite some inquiry about where progress has not been made and why. First of all, I think there has been a substantial degree of consensus over the need to move regulation beyond the old model of command and control. And I think there are a number of aspects to that, including a focus more on performance and output results as opposed to technology mandates or so-called best-available technology or requirements. I think there is also recognition that there is real value in a regulatory structure that seeks to induce innovation and not just force compliance. And I think there is a growing recognition around some of the principles of smart regulation that Mike highlighted: the need to have a market payoff for those who bring innovations to bear that help solve problems; the need for predictable frameworks that help people understand that there will be that potential for a market payoff; the value of data and metrics and measurement and information as a way to figure out who’s doing well and, perhaps with some analysis, why; and the value of disseminating best Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 26 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 practices—being able to figure out who’s leading, what they’re doing, and then share that information. I guess the greatest success, which Mike hinted at but I want to really hone in on, is the enormous change in attitudes in the business community. I think for many, many years, but beginning to deteriorate 20 years ago in part because of this Porter Hypothesis, there was a sense in the business world that environment as a topic was a burden. It was about regulations to follow, costs to bear, risks to manage, and the old model in business was to send it off to the general council’s office, and the less heard about it the better. I think we’ve seen a dramatic transformation in how business deals with the environment today. Almost all companies, and certainly all of the leading ones, see the environment and sustainability more broadly as an area of opportunity, first because there is an opportunity to differentiate yourself from the competition by managing those risks, costs, and regulations better. But then even more dramatically, there is an upside opportunity, a chance to drive growth, to be innovative, to build your brand, and to add intangible value to your business by taking these issues on in a constructive, strategic way, and really playing offense on this agenda and not defense. And so from Chad Holliday’s DuPont to Junior’s Drycleaners in Cheshire, Connecticut, there are companies big and small across every sector that now are positioning themselves as solutions providers. And they do this not to be good citizens. This is not a corporate social responsibility agenda. They do it because there’s an economic promise of marketplace success. I think that is the greatest positive element of what the Porter Hypothesis has helped us rethink and refocus on. I am concerned, and it raises a puzzle for conversation today, over why the policy process in Washington seems not to have gotten some of these fundamental principles clear. Frankly, I think there is a real question about whether some of the fundamentals of good policy analysis have gotten lost in recent years: the idea that you want to focus on a full picture of costs and benefits of regulation—not just short-term cost to the regulated community, but the cost of inaction or what the economists here might think of as opportunity costs. Again, that’s an important reframing that I hope we can begin to push. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 27 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Second of all, there are longer-term and perhaps less tangible elements of this cost and benefit calculation that need to be thought about—for example, whether we’re structuring regulation to induce innovation that will produce competitive opportunities and a vibrant business community going forward. I think we really have lost the recognition that environmental progress is fundamentally a function of technology development and broader innovation, and we should do much more to center our policy processes, our regulatory strategies, and our debates about how to move forward on how to induce that innovation. A lot of what the business community has picked up, I’ve written about and called the green-to-gold agenda. Businesses are recognizing there is a payoff to thinking about the environment. But I want to argue today that there’s also a gold-to-green agenda, which is to say if we’re going to make progress on the environment, it helps a great deal to harness the commitment to economic growth, prosperity, and competitiveness. We’ve done too little to think about how to ensure that our environmental regulatory strategy is in alignment with those broader economic goals and with business success. I think that’s the flip of the Porter Hypothesis that has gotten too little attention. I would critically argue that the important effort for RFF and others is to figure out how we make that part of the conversation here. I would like to just stress one other point, and then I’ll let Chad talk, and hopefully we can begin a dialogue back and forth. I don’t think the big challenges of the day—energy strategy, climate change, building competitiveness—can be addressed in a bitter partisan battle. I just don’t see how we make progress when people are broken down in one party against the other. I hearken back to the Clean Air Act of 1990, which a number of people in this room can remember. It is a great trivia question as to what the final Senate vote was on the Clean Air act of 1990. And Phil Sharp, who was there, did not know the answer this morning, so I won’t test any of the rest of you. My students at Yale all assume it was 51-49. The really smart ones think it was 60-40, knowing you had to get 60 votes to get closure in the Senate. The actual answer was 89-11. Why I raise that is because it suggests that we really built a consensus up the middle that drew Democrats and Republicans together on getting the Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 28 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 job done. And frankly, I think that’s what is essential to make progress on issues like climate change. You can’t do it with one party because I promise you that the year after that bill went through, there were not a few, not dozens, but a hundred fixes that had to be made to the legislation—because little things go wrong in big, complicated pieces of legislation. But we had a broad base of the Congress committed to getting this job done right and working to fix it up. We don’t see that, for example, on healthcare, and it’s going to be a mess. And I think we need to ensure that when we’re looking at transformation like we need to on the energy foundation of our society, on how we address climate change, how we build a competitive economy for the 21st century, we find ways to pull together. It is with appreciation for what the Porter Hypothesis has done in the business world to build an appreciation of the green-to-gold agenda and a recognition that the next challenge is the gold-to-green agenda that I’m glad to have a chance to be with you here today, and to talk about how to start that process. I do have a sequel coming out to Green to Gold, and there’s been a debate about whether it should be called Green to Platinum, or Gold to Green. But it’s actually going to be Green to Gold Business Playbook. It’s the “how” after the “why” of green-to-gold. Chad Holliday: Thanks, Dan. And Michael, it’s just really helpful to hear what you say. Let me try to add just a few things from a business perspective so we can get to the questions. About 20 years ago, not long after you were writing that one-page article, Bill Reilly came to DuPont and led a board-level committee that challenged us not just do the right thing for the environment, but asked, how do we make a business case for that? I think one of the things is having a board-level committee and someone of Bill’s stature to lead us. It made a tremendous difference, and we ended up with a company mission of sustainable growth, which we defined as increasing shareholder value and societal value while we reduced our environmental footprint. That stuck through the company over that period of time, and every action has sort of built on that. I won’t take you through the specific accomplishments, but they’ve also been good for our shareholders. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 29 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 As I looked back preparing for today at the businesses in DuPont and the changes they’ve made, and looked at our suppliers, which are critical, and our customers who are critical, there are three things that I saw that really made it click, and when they were all in place, it really worked. First, there had to be a vision of where you were going. It had to be a vision not the next quarter, not the next year, but generally five to seven years out. It had to be a vision that the senior leadership of the organization bought into, and the people who are there today had to see their picture in that vision. You know the group picture you take? When you get it back, the first thing you look at is to see where you are. If you’re not there, you don’t look that hard. So what some people miss is they don’t show where you fit into that. So the first thing is a vision that people can relate to—not too high-powered but one that makes sense. If you stop with vision, you probably won’t go very far, so you have to give people some tools. You have to give them some money to invest. You have to say what the rules are, the regulations for that investment. You have to put some processes in place—probably the processes you use in your company won’t work like they should in the future. And you have to give training to people. Michael mentioned that a couple of times. If you don’t give people the training of how to apply themselves, it won’t work. In our experience, if you stop there, you make a little progress but not much. The third piece, as we look back at the business being successful, is you have to get some early wins. People can’t wait five to seven years for success, so you get early wins. The biggest thing you do with those wins is you communicate them effectively throughout the entire organization because people believe real examples inside their own company. And you’re also giving people permission to do stuff by saying, “This is a good example, it’s what happened, and they didn’t break the rules, but they’re right on the edge, and we’re going to celebrate them.” What we found is that if you put those three things in place, whether you’re in DuPont or any other company, those kind of make sense with what you’re doing. Michael, as you were talking today, I really related. I did read your article before I came. I grew up in manufacturing plants; my first 12 years were on plants, and I’m an industrial engineer, and I just love plants. So I love going into a plant and talking to a plant manager who’s rather successful. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 30 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 It really hit me again as I read your article that the most successful plant managers work in concert with their local community. You can’t tell them from corporate how to do that because in every community, the tools to work with are very different. I go into one plant and I say, “Where’s your XYZ crane, because I know you’ve got to move this vessel twice a year.” He says, “Well, we don’t have one. The aluminum plant down the road has that crane, and we do this for them.” And I say, “Does corporate know you’re doing that?” “No. They would not understand. So basically we’re scheduling our plant with the aluminum plant. Yes, we are. Don’t tell corporate, because they’ll have a fit, and you know, the marketing guys.” So I think that’s very, very successful. We also see that we have to have a precision welder. They have to be available. They’re not available by contract, so we share it with different companies in the community. And that’s something I found we did a lot more in Asia, where we just didn’t have the resources to draw from. The second example that came to mind is that I work with an engineering company, CH2M HILL. They’re one of your clients I know, they’ve been a leader around the environment, and they’re considered to be the best water engineering company in the world. I asked them, “How come you’re the best water engineering company?” “Aah, we’re the best engineers. We’re widening the Panama Canal.” I keep probing them because this is fundamental engineering; anybody can learn it. “Well, why are you better?” And really they say, “Well, they only call us in when they’ve got a real problem. And we know the secret to a real problem is a community system to solve it.” So you have to work with the city on their water needs, with the plant on their water needs, and get a comprehensive way of doing that. And that’s why they have a contract with seven states to answer, how do you deal with the Colorado River? They think about not just the industry around that, but they think of everything else going on. So I just could not agree more that a lot of the value you’re talking about—you know, we never did use the term “corporate social responsibility” in DuPont. We just didn’t. It was fine, but that’s not what we were about. But the value you’re talking about can be done. There are examples of it being done, but how do you unleash that? Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 31 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 The last thing is that Bill was key at Rio 1992. Dan, you were helping him with Rio 1992. Rio is coming again in 2012. And I’m very pleased to be working with a group formed by the International Chamber of Commerce, the World Business Council for Sustainable Development, a new and global compact that petitioned the United Nations to be the business representatives, to bring a voice of business on how we can work together. We had a chance to present to 192 delegates of the United Nations that case just two weeks ago, and we got a lot of receptivity. We’re hopefully going to go to Rio 20 years after you guys got started and maybe talk about how business can be part of the answer. Thanks very much. Phil Sharp: Now we have an opportunity for about 20 minutes for engagement with the audience with this very stimulating speech and commentary by our two other guests. Please, if you have a question, we have two microphones we’re going to carry around, and if you would quickly identify yourself and ask your question, we would appreciate it so we can get multiple people in. Question: My name is David Clark. I’m with Inside Washington Publishers, and in my reporting on environmental and energy issues, one of the things we constantly hear is that there’s this train wreck coming with EPA regulations, especially the air regulations but also the 316(B) water regulations. Is this the result of poorly designed regulations, or what do you attribute that to given what we’ve heard today? Dan Esty: Everyone’s looking at me, but I’m going to look at Phil. I think there are constraints within the current regulatory structure, and I think there is an important opportunity to have a dialogue about how to do regulation differently and better. But I do think that there’s also been a lot of criticism leveled at the EPA that’s unfair. They are doing the best they can within a constrained regulatory structure, and there are enormously high expectations across our society for improved air, for improved water. I think this is an agency that’s struggling with limited resources and constrained regulations to try and deliver the best it can on that agenda. So I think it would be great if instead of having a bloodbath, as you describe it, or a train wreck, there was more of a conversation about how we could sharpen the regulatory portfolio and really move these things forward in a way that engages the business community. I think that’s the lesson we’ve heard today: one really would like to see a regulatory structure that helps to foster creativity, that brings to bear the thinking of the business community about the best way forward from the biggest Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 32 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 companies to the back-of-the-garage entrepreneurs. That’s how we have historically made progress, and it would be great if we could again focus on that as the path forward. Phil Sharp: I would just quickly add that you do need to take into account the order in which these things arise on the agenda. They’re not necessarily chosen to arise on the agenda by virtue of the leadership of EPA. Off and on, they are because a court suit has been filed that has said you have to by X date come to some kind of resolution or conclusion on that. And indeed, sometimes parties in both camps, environmental and business, find themselves having fought something in the courts and won, only to find it to come back and bite them in the rear end two years later when suddenly they have to confront a new and different regulatory environment. We see that on a couple of these clean air issues, they’re among this package of things that you’re addressing here. Question: Reid Detchon with the Energy Future Coalition. I’d like to follow up on that line of reasoning because what I find persuasive about the Porter Hypothesis is that the consumer’s going to put some demand pressure on a producer to make change. And environmental change can be a differentiator, a positive selling point in the marketplace. But the area we’re just talking about has to do with the regulation of power plants, and power plants don’t have any direct relationship with customers. Their incentive is to extend their life and instead of matching up their investment cycle, to prolong it. I wonder if you could imagine a way, as we head toward this train wreck, where a succession of important clean air rules are going to be applied at power plants. How would you think of applying the Porter Hypothesis to that environment? Michael Porter: Unfortunately, I’m not an expert on power plants. The fundamental idea here is that if an entity can be given a platform and a set of rules and an expectation about the set of rules in the future, there will be both an incentive and a necessity—but also the time and the scope—for innovation. Dan and I have written a piece about climate change, and hopefully this piece will be seeing the light of day shortly. The basic argument we make about climate change is that the efforts in the United States over the last two years really violated a lot of the key principles of the Porter Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 33 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Hypothesis. It really wasn’t about stimulating innovation or stimulating it in the best possible way. What mistakes did we make? We created this very complicated cap-andtrade system that was kind of hard to understand, and there wasn’t a really clear link between that system and motivation for companies to invest in innovation. There wasn’t a predictability about what the value of innovation would be because you couldn’t tell what these credits were worth. There was a lot of uncertainty about how the value of innovation would play out over time. Then we decided that we were going to start subsidizing individual technologies rather than actually creating a motivation for anybody with a good idea, with any technological solution, to ultimately be able to be successful. Dan and I have suggested that the simplest, cleanest approach to climate change policy is what we call an emissions charge, a carbon tax. You know, I think the name itself—when we’re stuck on what we call something and when the word tax is ruled as invalid from the start—I think we put in the article, let’s call this a depletion charge for depleting future generations’ energy resources. Let’s call it whatever we need to call it, but the point is that we need to create an incentive for innovation. We need to start small and phase it in over a long period of time, so that companies have an opportunity and power plants have an opportunity to understand this is the way the world is going to be. This charge is going to go up over time. All of a sudden there’s a great business case for investing in new technology. There’s a level playing field so that the people who are the most effective at building out this technology over time will succeed. So again, I think that we have allowed ourselves to get into a situation where we’re fighting over interest groups trying to minimize the shortterm impact that these issues will have on their business, rather than finding a way of formulating the regulatory question to really mobilize innovation. Dan, you pick up from there. Dan Esty: Well, I hope we don’t draw the wrong conclusions from the debate over the last couple of years, one of which could be that market mechanisms aren’t a good way to go. Frankly, that is not at all the conclusion that should be drawn. I do think we ended up with a cap-and-trade package Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 34 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 that had some problems and therefore sank. I think the truth is that capand-trade is a strategy that locks in an environmental target and leaves open the question of at what price those allowances are going to trade; therefore it leaves open the question of the economic burden. And as the economy soured over 2008–2009, that became a tough nut to sell—that is, to say that we’re going to have an economic burden at a difficult moment for the economy. The alternative, which is an emissions charge, or an energy resources depletion charge, would in fact not lock in the environmental target as the cap-and-trade would but locks in the economic price, which could start very low and escalate slowly over time. I think that’s more attractive. Second of all, I think there was the problem of giving away so many of the allowances—not as the 1990 Clean Air Act gave some number for a few years of transition to help people adjust, but to give away 80 percent of the allowances out to the 2030s began to make it look like a special-interest capture of a regulatory program, and that helped sour it. Third of all, the very nature or idea of a carbon market, which seemed very cool and cutting edge three years ago, in the wake of the collapse of the year 2008 started to look like another opaque market—too complex for everyday people, and one where the average citizen would not win and probably some Wall Street folks would. So I think all of that burdened this idea of how we should regulate and has left us, Reid, with a not very attractive Clean Air Act command-andcontrol strategy. I guess I’m hopeful that we don’t pursue Clean Air Act models to the ultimate end here because I don’t think it is a good structure for addressing big-picture problems like the energy future of our society. I guess I’m hopeful—but in Washington one can be quickly discouraged about this—that there could be another pass at the right market approach, the right market mechanism, some kind of a charge, with the logic being not only that it’s the right way to regulate, but that at a moment where we need revenue—because we’re not going to be able to get where we need to go cutting spending alone—there might be a way to use a pairing of a slowly escalating charge not hitting until out years in a big way as an answer to two problems at once: how do we get the right energy strategy in place that’s really thoughtful, addresses not only climate change, but our dependence on foreign oil, and begin to address some of the budget deficit concerns? Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 35 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Chad Holliday: Maybe I’ll just add a few quick points to that. What business will say is, “Give me certainty, and I can deal with it.” I think that’s a competitive advantage to this country because I still think we’re the most creative, innovative country in the world. So the more we can get that certainty, we’ll move. Second, I was with a group of 130 CEOs of chemical companies globally yesterday, and we had one of these responses—you know, where you vote. And it said, “How many of you think you’ve got to somehow price this stuff”—it didn’t say how—“to be successful?” and it was 82 percent. So I think there is a belief in it. And as an industry we’ve already looked at it, and we’re going to have to do something to put a price on it some way or another, or it won’t work. The other phenomenon that’s really surprised many of us since this last summer, after Copenhagen wasn’t a big success and there wasn’t an energy bill here, is we’ve seen more and more companies say, “They’re not going to make the rules; we’d better get on with it.” So we’re seeing more companies step up to the party. Dan Esty: Our proposal by the way is a $5-per-ton charge escalating $5 per ton per year for 20 years: predictability, slow escalation that allows people to regear their capital investment over a timeframe that’s logical, and we pair that with a proposal that the international negotiations shift focus not on targets—at least not on emissions targets—but on a common price target of $100 a ton in 2050. It turns out to be much easier to get the Chinas, Indias, and developing countries of the world to focus on that common price target because every government in the world needs revenue, and it doesn’t seem to feel like a growth cap the way the emissions targets do. Question: I’m Roy Gamse. I was director of economic analysis at EPA in the dark ages. I’m amused that after politicians have disingenuously managed to label as a tax what isn’t a tax, the solution seems to be to make their dreams come true and actually use a tax instead. But my question is, there seems to be a major disconnect between politicians on Capitol Hill who purport to represent business interest and what I’m hearing here about business interest. It’s obvious from a lot; this isn’t a secret. You read the ads in the Washington Post from hundreds of CEOs. It’s plain as can be. What can we do to close that disconnect so that the politicians can Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 36 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 represent what business really wants and have a chance of closing the gap between the parties? Chad Holliday: We put together a very interesting group two years ago—three years— called U.S. Climate Action Partnership (CAP), a group of twelve businesses and four NGOs. We locked ourselves in a room for a year and said, “Could we come up with something we could all buy into?” There were some very long nights, but we came up with a plan. It did have a capand-trade aspect to it. We didn’t communicate it very well, so it got way off track. So I think that’s an example. These were companies across various different industries. And we came out with it. So I think it can be done, and shame on us: somehow we did not sell that effectively, but I think the underlying premises for how it can be done are out there. We’ve just got to find a way to communicate it better. Phil Sharp: I think Chad underestimates the impact that they had. While they did not get it over the finish line in the U.S. Senate, the fact is I think it’s very doubtful the House could ever have advanced this legislation with the speed that it did without U.S. CAP being engaged. I say that because what you’re advocating is a huge investment, as Chad articulated, in the time and the energy of leadership of various companies on this kind of proposition. And the question they’re naturally going to ask is, “Is it worth it?” And I think the evidence is very clear: yes it is, even though the final result wasn’t achieved at this go-around. Tony Knowles here has a question. Question: Yes, thank you. Tony Knowles with the National Energy Policy Institute. Thanks to the continued public service of Bill Reilly, and Bob Graham, and other members of the Oil Spill Commission, it has probed into the complete disconnect between regulations and the government and corporate response to those regulations. I was wondering if you could comment on the tragic human and environmental consequences. I was wondering if you could comment on the concept of a corporate shared value in the relationship between the regulated and the regulators, and how we can avoid this kind of situation in the future. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 37 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 Michael Porter: Well again, I’m not nearly as well informed on this particular case as many of you. I actually was a board member of one of the predecessor companies of Transocean, so I do know a fair amount about the offshore drilling industry. The notion of shared value is built around specific areas of societal concern, or specific societal needs. So in this case, it would be the safe development of offshore energy resources. And the question is, how do we get the safest use of offshore energy resources at the minimum added cost of business? And how can we innovate in how we develop those resources? How can we advance the technology in ways that improve safety, but without keeping more and more cost, by doing things better and using better technology and using better methods and using better processes? Shared-value thinking says the companies that can figure out how to develop their offshore drilling and development activities the best and the fastest will benefit by hopefully having a limited number of accidents. Look at the disastrous effect these accidents have on a company. Sharedvalue thinking says that safety is not only good for society, it’s actually good for the company as well. So the shared-value philosophy would be that. The question then is how to create a dialogue and a regulatory structure and process that would really hasten that thinking rather than have this be a kind of contest to see companies trying to minimize the requirements and government trying to maximize the requirements, and having a tug-ofwar. How can we create the right kind of process? I think probably step one would be to, as we talked a number of times today, start really collecting data and tracking performance and measuring intensively the environmental impact and the environmental record. Now some of that is probably going on in the industry. But ultimately we ought to be focused on the output, the outcome, which is good safety performance—not on specifying certain specific steps that companies have to go through. So that’s how the philosophy would apply. We should get Bill or others here to talk about how you would actually redesign the regulatory process in that case. Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 38 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 But the other day, I was on an airplane, and I was thinking about airplanes. We can make dramatic improvements on these areas of environmental performance and safety performance. They don’t require in many cases extra spending, but they require new ways of thinking about how you do it and how do you do it well. So the whole philosophy here in shared value is that from a company’s point of view, let’s look at it that way rather than see any social issue like safety as a threat to the success of the corporation. Let’s, as Dan said, see it as an opportunity. But maybe others would want to comment on how in this specific case we could redefine or restructure the regulatory environment. I don’t know enough about it. Phil Sharp: Actually, I was going to recognize Bill Reilly. He’s already spoken to this, and the commission has made a recommendation on it patterned after what was done after the nuclear accident in this country. Bill, do you want to take just a couple of minutes? We’re at the end of our session here, but this is well worth hearing from Bill. Bill Reilly: Your point about performance and performance standards is directly relevant to this situation. The tendency is that our government apparatus— and certainly at the Bureau of Ocean Energy Management, Regulation and Enforcement, the successor to the marine resources regulator—is to prescribe in ever more detail how things should be done: how negative pressure tests should be conducted, where centralizers fit in, all that sort of thing. The great fear I have looking at that situation is that will be effective for three to five years. But if you see the dynamic development of that industry, and the dynamism it took to go 5,000 feet down—now they’re going 10,000 feet down; three rigs are being made for that—one worries that will be out of date. What if instead of those kinds of prescriptive regulations, you had two things? You had performance standards. One of the company CEOs was just telling me the other day, “We learned from a catastrophe in the 1980s to always have three barriers in an under-balanced well.” That is one thing. The other is to put more initiative back onto the company that’s being regulated. Ask them, in the way that is done in the North Sea, “You look at the particularities of this situation. You look at the formation. What is the pressure? How difficult will this be as a drilling proposition? Are Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 39 The Porter Hypothesis After 20 Years: How Can Environmental Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness? Eighth Annual Hans Landsberg Memorial Lecture January 19, 2011 there salt domes, and things of that sort that complicate it all? What do you propose to do about each of those risks that you identify?” And then the regulator looks at that, doesn’t necessarily even approve it, but simply accepts it unless it’s wholly unacceptable, and it’s no longer a mentality of checking the box. The tragedy, part of it, in the Gulf is people checking the boxes didn’t understand the technologies, which they freely admitted. It got way ahead of them, and they didn’t understand it because they were not informed, trained, prepared, and resourced over the years to be the match of the people they were regulating. Your emphasis on performance is exactly right I think, what’s called the safety case, the way this is done in the North Sea. I’ve had people say— smart people who have a history with regulation—that’s not American. It’s un-American not to have black-letter law, and I think there’s some truth to that, frankly. So it might be a difficult transition to make, and some people in the Interior Department were like, “Well, okay, we’ll do that, but we’ll also have stricter regulations.” Well, you have to have a platform, a foundation, but I think there is insight for that industry and for that regulator in your formulation. Phil Sharp: Well, ladies and gentlemen, we’ve run the clock here. I can’t help but seize the moment since Bill Reilly spoke to just indicate that just up on the websites, both ours and for the Oil Spill Commission, are some papers that our scholars were commissioned by the Oil Spill Commission to do, one of them on just this very topic. And those—as all of our work is always ultimately made available to the public—are now available to all of you. But most importantly, I think you’ll surely agree with me what an extraordinary, stimulating conversation we’ve had with one of the profound leaders on the thought in this, with Professor Michael Porter and Dan Esty and Chad Holliday. Thank you so much. [End of Audio] Resources for the Future | 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036-1400 | Tel 202-328-5000 | info@rff.org | www.rff.org 40