` L 2, 2 M 3, 1 R 0, 0 r 2, 2 1, 0 0, 1 2 2 L M s ` @r @ 3, 1 1, 0 1c @ @ R @ 2 @s ` @r @ 0, 0 0, 1 ECON5210 Topics in microeconomics — Spring semester 2009 Example illustrating sequential equilibrium Consider the above example. An assessment is the following object: (β, µ) = ((β1 (∅), β2 ({M, R})), µ({M, R})) , where • β1 (∅), player 1’s behavioral strategy, is a probability distribution over player 1’s strategies, L, M , and R, • β2 ({M, R}), player 2’s behavioral strategy, is a probability distribution over player 2’s strategies, ` and r, and • µ({M, R}) is player 2’s belief conditional on 2 being asked to play over the two histories, M and R, that lead to her information set. A sequential equilibrium is an assessment that is sequentially rational and consistent. Sequential rationality precludes that player 1 assigns positive probability on R, since R is strictly dominated for 1. Hence, in any sequential equilibrium, β1 (∅)(R) = 0. There are two types of sequential equilibria. Sequential equilibrium where β1 (∅)(M ) > 0. In this case, 2’s information set is reached with positive probability, and the consistency of the assessment entails that µ({M, R} is determined from β1 (∅) using Bayes’ rule: β1 (∅)(M ) = 1, β1 (∅)(M ) + β1 (∅)(R) β1 (∅)(R) µ({M, R})(R) = = 0. β1 (∅)(M ) + β1 (∅)(R) µ({M, R})(M ) = 1 With these beliefs, β2 ({M, R}) is part of a sequentially rational assessment if and only if β2 ({M, R})(`) = 1 , β2 ({M, R})(r) = 0 . This in turn means that β1 (∅) is part of a sequentially rational assessment if and only if β1 (∅)(L) = 0 , β1 (∅)(M ) = 1 , β1 (∅)(R) = 0 . Hence, there is unique sequential equilibrium where β1 (∅)(M ) > 0: (β, µ) = ((β1 (∅), β2 ({M, R})), µ({M, R})) = (((0, 1, 0), (1, 0)), (1, 0)) . Sequential equilibrium where β1 (∅)(M ) = 0. Hence, β1 (∅) is given as follows: β1 (∅)(L) = 1 , β1 (∅)(M ) = 0 , β1 (∅)(R) = 0 . This behavioral strategy of player 1 is part of a sequentially rational assessment if and only if β2 ({M, R}) satisfies β2 ({M, R})(`) = 1 − p , β2 ({M, R})(r) = p , with p ≥ 21 , because otherwise player 1 would want to have β1 (∅)(M ) = 1. If 1 2 ≤ p < 1, then player 2’s behavioral strategy is part of a sequentially rational assessment if and only if µ({M, R})(M ) = 12 , µ({M, R})(R) = 21 . 2 To check that this is part of a consistent assessment, consider β = ((β1 (∅), β2 ({M, R}))) , where is a “small” positive number and β1 (∅)(L) = 1 − 2 β2 ({M, R})(`) = β2 ({M, R})(`) , β1 (∅)(M ) = β2 ({M, R})(r) = β2 ({M, R})(r) , β1 (∅)(R) = . Then µ({M, R} is determined from β1 (∅) using Bayes’ rule: β1 (∅)(M ) 1 = = , β1 (∅)(M ) + β1 (∅)(R) + 2 β1 (∅)(R) 1 µ({M, R})(R) = = = . β1 (∅)(M ) + β1 (∅)(R) + 2 µ({M, R})(M ) = Furthermore, β → β as → 0. This shows consistency and establishes that (β, µ) = ((β1 (∅), β2 ({M, R})), µ({M, R})) = ((1, 0, 0), (1 − p, p)), ( 12 , 21 ) , is a sequential equilibrium if and only if p ≥ 12 . If β2 ({M, R})(r) = 1, then player 2’s behavioral strategy is part of a sequentially rational assessment if and only if µ({M, R})(M ) = 1 − q , µ({M, R})(R) = q , with q ≥ 12 . To check that this is part of a consistent assessment, consider β = ((β1 (∅), β2 ({M, R}))) , where is a “small” positive number and β1 (∅)(L) = 1 − β2 ({M, R})(`) = , β1 (∅)(M ) = (1 − q) β2 ({M, R})(r) = 1 − , β1 (∅)(R) = q . 3 Then µ({M, R} is determined from β1 (∅) using Bayes’ rule: 1−q β1 (∅)(M ) = = 1−q, β1 (∅)(M ) + β1 (∅)(R) 1−q+q q β1 (∅)(R) = µ({M, R})(R) = = q. β1 (∅)(M ) + β1 (∅)(R) 1−q+q µ({M, R})(M ) = Furthermore, β → β as → 0. This shows consistency and establishes that (β, µ) = ((β1 (∅), β2 ({M, R})), µ({M, R})) = (((1, 0, 0), (0, 1)), (1 − q, q)) , is a sequential equilibrium if and only if q ≥ 21 . A final question: Are the sequential equilibria of the second type reasonable? Geir B. Asheim, 2 February 2009 4