Electricity Market Design on Two Sides of the Atlantic The German ‘Energiewende’ MIT, 2 May, 2013 Dr. Bernd-Michael Zinow Senior Vice President Public Affairs, EnBW AG Energie braucht Impulse What is „Die Energiewende“? Def. Energiewende: Decarbonisation of German energy supply by 2050 – under the constraint of the phase-out of nuclear energy until 2022. 2 Source: Stadtwerke Duisburg 1 Energiewende: Status Quo › 1 Every sixtieth German has become a power producer – there are 450 power plants in Germany, but Renewables 1,3 million decentral generation sites (PV, wind, biomass) › 2 RES produce roughly a quarter of Germany‘s power generation – RES generation has tripled since 2000; 35 GW of new RES capacity was built since 2008 (almost the capacity of Germany‘s hard coal plants (about 38 GW) › 3 Sharp cost decreases: costs for rooftop PV installations (10 kWp) dropped from 5 €/Wp (2006) to 1,8 €/Wp now; on sunny days, PV in some hours covers 35% of German energy consumption Conventional generation › 4 Conventional generation sharply decreasing – e.g. gas-fired generation: -26% compared to 2011 › 5 Massive price decline on wholesale market: 2012: 42,60 €/MWh (– 9 €/MWh; 17 % below 2011. In 2008 prices occasionally beyond 80 €/MWh › 6 No improvement expected: forward prices for 2014, 2015, and 2016 hardly higher than 40 €/MWh › 7 Gas-fired plants with negative margins; margins for coal-fired plants decreasing (15-20 €/MWh (2009) to 5-10 €/MWh) › 8 First plant decommissionings announced; govt. prohibits retirement of ‚systemic‘ capacities (‚winter Downstream reserve‘) › 9 Trend towards local supply: 60-70 municipal utilities founded since 2008 › 1 Competition landscape changing: market share of „Big Four“ (e.on, Vattenfall, RWE, EnBW) dropped 0 from more than 70 % to 47 % since 2002 (installed capacity; mostly due to growth of RES) 11 Changes in customer behaviour: churn rates increasing continuously– every industrial and every fourth household customer will have switched to another supplier by end of a year 3 1 € = US$ 1,30 (Apr. 23) What is the German Energiewende? Ambitious long-term targets defined in 2010 for the next 40 (!) years „Green“ targets… … and nuclear phase-out 80 65 50 22.000 20.000 16.000 14.000 -­‐ 26 -­‐ 40 -­‐ 55 -­‐ 70 4 -­‐ 10 12.068 10.793 9.509 10.000 -­‐ 25 8.107 8.000 6.000 4.049 4.000 -­‐ 80 Reduction of greenhouse gas emissions in % 2011 12.000 7% of electricity generation (2010) 2020 Source: BNetzA 2012 23% of electricity generation (2010) 18.000 35 20 -­‐ 2 20.490 2.000 Reduction of electricity consumption vs. 2008 in % 2030 RES Share of gross power consumption 2040 2050 0 2010 • • 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022 Phase-out decision adopted after Fukushima catastrophe Creates concerns about security of supply in the South (‚winter reserve‘ to be implemented) 2 Shares of RES in Germany Shares of renewable energy in German power supply Gross domestic power consumption % Gross power generation 2012 35 35 30 25 20 20 14 15 10 Oil, pumped storage, other Hard coal Natural gas 6.0% 19.1% 11.3% 23 15 17 16 12 8 Nuclear 16.0% 9 21,9% RES 5 5.8% Biomass 3.3% Hydro 4.6% PV Waste Lignite 2002 2004 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 target 2020 • • Wind 0.8% 25.6% 0 7.3% Germany‘s 2020 RES-targets will be surpassed by far: we expect more than 40% RES share. Most of RES capacity volatile Sources: bdew, BMU 5 Increasing costs of RES and beginning reform debate cause the need to act Development of EEG-costs Strong increase of RES and RES support… … creates political reform debate 20,4 bn. EUR ct/kWh 13,2 4,5 0,4 200 3 0,7 200 5 14,1 (FIT), especially › › 10,8 9,0 2,6 13,5 1,1 200 8 1,1 200 9 2,1 201 0 › All parties still in support of Energiewende › Increasing criticism of support scheme 3,5 3,6 5,3 Main cost driver PV Efficiency potentials and distribution effects › Probably fundamental reform of the EEG after federal election in Sept. 2013 › concerns 2011 201 2 201 3 about functioning of the market model (energy-only-market) Sources: BMWi, BDEW 6 3 Public opinion still in favour of RES but increasingly sceptical about costs Opinion polls: Majority supports Energiewende „Is the RES surcharge too high?“ … speed of RES growth 61 75 51 51 46 32 30 25 10 6 2011 too high • • 2011 201 2 adequate or too low too slow 201 2 good too fast RES still with great public support but costs becoming increasingly important. Public (esp. local) acceptance being another major issue Sources: Infratest Akzeptanzumfrage 2012, 4000 persons; shares of persons interviewed; BDEW Energiemonitor June 2012, Forschungsgruppe Wahlen, interviewed persons: 1.011 7 Conventional power generation will be decreasing in the future Load factors and forward prices Decreasing load factors of conventional power plants… … and decreasing wholesale prices price (€/MWh) Full load hours 6060 Lignite 5555 Base 2016 E UR /MWh Hard coal N-Germany 5050 Hard coal new plant (since 1985) Base 2015 4545 Base 2013 2006 › › 8 2007 2008 2009 2010 Hard coal old plant (before1970) 2011 4040 Base 2014 3535 01/12 03/12 01/12 Base Y-­‐13 05/12 07/12 Base Y-­‐14 09/12 11/12 Base Y-­‐15 01/13 03/1303/13 Base Y-­‐16 RES-expansion puts pressure on prices and load factors Overcapacities in European market due to historical investment decisions and more efficient market design (more efficient cross-border dispatch) 4 Reduced margins put economic viability under pressure Spreads of conventional power plants C lean Dark S pread (B as e) Clean Dark Spread (Efficiency: 36%) Wirk ung s g rad: 36% 12 › German merit order 10 curve is very flat; significant margins rare € /MWh 8 6 › No improvement 4 2 0 01.01.2012 31.03.2012 29.06.2012 2013 27.09.2012 2014 26.12.2012 2015 26.03.2013 2016 › Additional new C lean S park S pread (P eak ) capacities unlikely; amount of capacities to leave the market difficult to predict Wirk ungs grad: 50% Clean8Spark Spread (Efficiency: 50%) 4 0 € /MWh expected due to new (now being built) capacities › Political concerns -­‐ 4 about security of supply -­‐ 8 -­‐ 12 01.01.2012 31.03.2012 2013 29.06.2012 27.09.2012 2014 26.12.2012 2015 26.03.2013 2016 9 Even efficient gas-fired plants out of merit Example: Irsching 5, 860 MW CCGT, commissioned 2010 June – August 2012 20.000 20.000 16.000 16.000 Generation(MWh) Genereation(MWh) June – August 2011 12.000 12.000 8.000 8.000 4.000 4.000 0 June 2011 July 2011 η : 59,7 %; Investment: 400 mln. € • August 2011 0 June 2012 July 2012 August 2012 Source: E.ON To be fair: Plants rendered uneconomic not only because of Energiewende (economic crisis and lack of energy demand in Europe) 10 5 Lack of redispatch capacity triggered decommissioning prohibition of ‚systemic‘ plants (‚winter reserve‘) › Plant decommissionings announced (also in the South) in Nuclear phase-out addition to planned retirements of nuclear capacities Shutdowns in 2011 Shutdowns in 2015-2022 › Govt. and TSOs concerned about lack of redispatch capacity › Govt. to issue regulation to implement ‚winter reserve‘ › Prohibition to decommission ‚systemic‘ plants; plant owners may receive compensation for incremental costs › Industry recommends Strategic Reserve instead › similar to solutions in Sweden and Finland › capacity payments determined competitively (via tender) › Strategic Reserve may be used both › for redispatch and › to balance national capacity household (if necessary, in second half of decade) 11 Capacity not scarce until end of decade but generation gap of 4 – 8 GW in 2022 due to plant decommissioning Sufficient new capacity commisioned until 2016 … but scarcity may occur by end of decade. MW GW 8.000 7.157 7.000 80,0 12,5 2,5 12,5 2,5 4,0-8,0 6.000 72,0 80,0 5.000 4.013 4.000 Plant retirements 3.000 2.000 734 1.000 0 -­‐ 1.000 -­‐ 2.000 2012 existing 2012 -­‐ 875 -­‐ 1.357 -­‐ 1.646 2013 2014 2015 2016-? new built cap. credit RES phaseout nuclear cap. buffer gap Capac needed . 2022 2022 total Debate sparked: Does Germany need a capacity market? Simulation of European power plant utilisation until 2022 shows capacity gap in GER – problem only in case of autarky requirement; Range of gap caused by different assumptions about plant retirement decision behaviour. 12 Sources: Consentec; EnBW 6 Implementing of Energiewende requires investments of > €650 bln. into the German electricity sector until 2050 Forecast of cumulated necessary investments into German electricity system (target scenario) 669 250 3 Electricity generation Storage 4 115 -distribution grid 42 44 -transmission grid -Maintenance 29 Grid 372 Consumption Total until 2030 Total until 2050 Signficant investments, esp. in generation and grids required. Source: Boston Consulting Group 13 Germany: Two capacity mechanism paradigms under discussion Customer-based definition of required capacity Def.: amount of capacity needed defined by customer demand for reliable supply › Capacity requirement defined by decentral demand, retail as market intermediary › Capacity price determined e.g. via tradeable capacity certificates › Investment decisions based on energy and capacity prices; individual risks remains at indivdual investor › Capacity creation only to the extent needed to Central buyer-approach Def.: amount of capacity needed defined by state authorities (e.g. regulator) › Capacity requirement defined administratively according TSO forecasts › Capacity price determined by central auction › Investment decisions based on capacity price, wholesale energy price becomes short term optimisation (dispatch) instrument; investment risks socialised › Tendency to create excess capacity; danger of existing plants being discriminated to keep system ‚cheap‘ meet customer demand › Ex.: French capacity market model; systems proposed by German utility Thüga and German municipal utility association VKU › Ex.: UK capacity market model, EWI (Cologne Completely ‚privatised‘ capacity Tradeable capacity certificates supply (VKU, FR) University), Öko-Institut Central buyer approach (Öko-Institut, EWI, UK) 14 7 Europe: rag rug of capacity mechanisms Ireland Capacity payments introduced 2005 England and Wales Capacity payments between 1990 and 2001. Re-introduction (capacity auctions) 2015 Sweden and Finland TTR administrated by TSO Energy-Only-Market Capacity mechanism Belgium Introduction of Capacity Mechanism planned France Market for capacity certificates 2016/2017 Poland TTR administrated by TSO Romania Auction for capacity certificates Spain Capacity payment since liberalisation; reform 2007 Italy Capacity payment introduced 2004 Greece Capacity obligation introduced 2005 Source: F. Roques, IHS CERA; EnBW 15 Capacity mechansims so far not discussed in European context Concerns about vicious circle of externalities Prices artificially dampened in one Member State by adding new capacity via a capacity mechanism (CM)… p Investments New CM p GW …will reduce investment incentives in other MSs and possibly prompt another CM there, which in turn might make the first region intensify its CM again… 16 8 German FIT (EEG) appropriate to kick-start RES, but costly and incompatible with wholesale market The system has turned out to be effective… › System kick-started RES in Germany. › FIT for up to 20 years › Priority dispatch › Grid access guarantee › Broad public acceptance; several ways to profit individually (‚democratisation of energy supply‘); system meets widespread desire for local autarky … but needs an overhaul › Market integration necessary to deal with signficant amount of RES production; esp. to provide incentives to meet demand (incl. forward and ancillary service markets, where technically feasible) › Support of RES still necessary but funding system should be more market-oriented (e.g. market premium) › No fundamental change needed: lowrisk (‚optional‘) market premium system already introduced as alternative to FIT in Germany since 2012; can easily be modified to become a simple fixed premium system 17 RES-support schemes: all kinds implemented in Europe FIT Some observations: FIT/Premium Quota FIT/Auction › Quota systems often underperformed in meeting national RES targets › FIT often with unexpected growth of RES capacities › Almost all systems support different RES technologies (PV, wind…) differently FIT/Quota Not specified 18 Sources: Frontier Economics, EnBW 9 Efficient market design comprises more than capacity mechanisms and RES support schemes Core elements of future market design What is needed: We need a consistent approach considering the following aspects: › Markets based on short-run marginal costs › RES must respond to market signals › Options for market participants (e.g. ability to choose between RESmarket integration models) › Prevention of market splitting and preservation of high liquidity › European market is the target Smart Grids Demand participation Infrastructure enhancement Capacity incentive mechanisms RES Market integration Energy efficiency European market integration Storage EnBW is in strong support of market-based solutions. 19 Some concluding remarks Energiewende irreversible but RES support and market design controversial › Energiewende still enjoys great public support and is consensual across all political parties: in our view, it is irreversible › However: there are some problems and contradictions: › Costs becoming increasingly important › Concerns about regional grid stability in the South after phase-out of nuclear › Concerns about security of supply after 2020 sparked intensive debate about introduction of capacity mechanisms › Costs and lack of market conformity of German feed-in-tariff system triggered debate about reform of German RES support mechanism (EEG) › › Currently interim ‚winter reserve‘-sytem installed › Capacity Mechanisms will be implemented independently in Europe: interferences? Energiewende creates massive cross-border effects: European co-ordination will become a major issue › RES support mechanism to be reformed in Germany after 2014; quota system unlikely, we expect revised version of existing market premium system; European system not before 2020 Capacity market design will be defined after election in Sept. 2013; mechanism likely to be implemented after 2017 20 10 Thank you! Energie braucht Impulse 11