The Trade-off between Private Lots and Public Open

advertisement
DISCUSSION PAPER
July 2007 „ RFF DP 07-33
The Trade-off
between Private Lots
and Public Open
Space in Subdivisions
at the Urban–Rural
Fringe
Elizabeth Kopits, Virginia McConnell,
and Margaret Walls
1616 P St. NW
Washington, DC 20036
202-328-5000 www.rff.org
The Trade-off between Private Lots and Public Open Space in
Subdivisions at the Urban–Rural Fringe
Elizabeth Kopits, Virginia McConnell, and Margaret Walls
Abstract
In many communities on the urban–rural fringe, subdivisions are subject to “clustering”
rules, in which houses must be located on a portion of the total land area and the remainder of the
land is left as open space. This open space may be undisturbed forest or pastureland, or it may
include recreation facilities and trails. In some communities, the open space may remain in
agricultural use as pasture or cropland. Although the open space may provide benefits to
subdivision residents, it means that those residents are living in a higher-density setting than
people living in conventional subdivisions. It is unclear whether the benefits offset the loss
experienced by smaller lots and higher density. This trade-off is the focus of our study. We use
data on subdivision house sales occurring between 1981 and 2001 in a county on the fringe of
the Washington, DC, metropolitan area to estimate a hedonic price model. We examine how
households value being adjacent to open space and having more open space in the subdivision,
and how they may be willing to trade off those amenities with their own private lot space.
We find that private acreage matters to households—a 10 percent larger lot leads to about
a 0.6 percent higher house price, all else being equal. Subdivision open space is also valuable to
households, but the marginal effect is much smaller than the marginal effect of private lot space.
We also find that subdivision open space does substitute for private land, but the extent of the
trade-off is small. We use the results of the estimated hedonic model to simulate the effects on
prices of jointly increasing open space and reducing average lot size, holding the size of the
subdivision constant. We find that average house prices are lower with clustering, particularly
for interior lots that are not adjacent to open space.
Key Words: subdivisions, clustering, hedonic property values, open space
JEL Classification Numbers: Q51, Q24, R14, H41
© 2007 Resources for the Future. All rights reserved. No portion of this paper may be reproduced without
permission of the authors.
Discussion papers are research materials circulated by their authors for purposes of information and discussion.
They have not necessarily undergone formal peer review.
Contents
Introduction............................................................................................................................. 1
Overview of Relevant Literature........................................................................................... 3
Data .......................................................................................................................................... 5
Econometric Model and Results ............................................................................................ 8
Results: Preferences for Lot Size and Subdivision Open Space Amenities ....................... 9
Results: Other Variables ................................................................................................... 12
Simulating the Effect of Clustered Subdivisions on House Prices ................................... 12
Conclusions............................................................................................................................ 13
References.............................................................................................................................. 15
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
The Trade-off between Private Lots and Public Open Space in
Subdivisions at the Urban–Rural Fringe
Elizabeth Kopits, Virginia McConnell, and Margaret Walls ∗
Introduction
Open space in the form of parks, forest preserves, wetlands, and protected agricultural
lands provides a range of benefits to local communities. Many hedonic property value studies
have shown that house sales prices are higher, all else being equal, the closer a house is to open
space, the greater the amount of open space surrounding the house, and the larger the size of the
open space (McConnell and Walls 2005). However, few studies have focused on the particular
type of open space we analyze here: preserved open space within a residential subdivision.
In many communities, particularly those on the urban–rural fringe, most housing is
located in subdivisions. Increasingly, those developments are subject to “clustering” rules, in
which houses must be located on a portion of the total land area and the remainder of the land is
left as open space. In some communities, zoning laws mandate clustering; in others, clustering is
recommended but not required. This subdivision open space may be undisturbed forest or
pastureland, or it may include recreation facilities and trails. In some communities, the open
space may remain in agricultural use as pasture or cropland. Proponents of clustering
requirements argue that undeveloped areas convey value, not only to the residents of the
subdivisions themselves, but also to the broader community, by preserving more of the aesthetic
and rural character of the community and improving environmental quality through habitat
protection or water pollution reduction (Arendt 1992). In communities on the urban–rural fringe,
∗
Elizabeth Kopits is an economist at the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) National Center for
Environmental Economics. Virginia McConnell is professor, Department of Economics, at University of Maryland,
Baltimore County, and Senior Fellow at Resources for the Future. Margaret Walls is Senior Fellow and Co-Director
of Research at Resources for the Future. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not
necessarily represent those of the EPA. No official EPA endorsement should be inferred. The helpful comments of
Soren Anderson are greatly appreciated.
1
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
clustering residential developments may be one option in the local government’s toolkit for
maintaining an agricultural base and curbing sprawl.1
Open space may provide benefits to subdivision residents, but clustering means that those
residents are living in a higher-density setting than residents of conventional subdivisions, with
neighboring houses in closer proximity to one another. Although the external benefits from the
preserved forest, wetland, recreation area, or other kind of open space may be positive, it is
unclear whether those benefits offset the loss experienced by smaller lots and higher density.
This trade-off is the focus of our study. We use data on subdivision house sales occurring
between 1981 and 2001 in Calvert County, Maryland, located on the fringe of the Washington,
DC, metropolitan area, to estimate a hedonic price model. We examine how households value
being adjacent to open space, how they value having more open space in the subdivision, and
how they may be willing to trade off those amenities with their own private lot space.
We find that private acreage matters to households—a 10 percent larger lot leads to about
a 0.6 percent higher house price, with all other factors held constant, and this result is significant
and robust to all specifications of our model. Subdivision open space is also valuable to
households, but the marginal effect of an additional acre is much smaller than the marginal effect
of an additional acre of their own private lot. We also find that although subdivision open space
does substitute for private land, the magnitude of the effect is small. Having a lot that is adjacent
to subdivision open space also enhances the value of a house, particularly if the open space is not
too steeply sloped. However, we find no evidence of homeowners’ willingness to trade off their
own lot size for adjacency to the open space. Finally, we use the results of the estimated hedonic
model to simulate the effects on house prices of jointly increasing open space and reducing
average lot size, holding the size of the subdivision constant. We find that average house prices
are lower with the clustering, particularly for interior lots that are not adjacent to open space.
1
Daniels (1997) takes a more critical view of the use of clustering requirements for preserving farmland on the
urban fringe. He argues these requirements are often incompatible with an active agricultural economy and are often
used as a “quick fix” by local planners and elected officials faced with difficult land use choices.
2
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
Overview of Relevant Literature
McConnell and Walls (2005) review the extensive revealed and stated preference
literature on valuing open space. In the revealed preference literature, almost all the studies use a
hedonic property value approach. These studies look at a range of different types of open
space—natural areas, wetlands, urban and suburban parks, forested lands, and different kinds of
farmland. They use different measures of open space, including distance from the house to the
nearest open space, open space acreage, adjacency dummy variables, and the percentage of land
in a particular radius around the property that is in open space; many studies include interaction
variables between these different measures.
In this brief review, we emphasize studies that focus on the value of open space amenities
within and surrounding residential subdivisions. Lacy (1990) and Mohamed (2006) compare
housing prices in clustered versus non-clustered, or conventional, subdivisions in communities in
Massachusetts and Rhode Island, respectively. Lacy (1990) does not use the hedonic approach
but finds prices appreciate slightly more in subdivisions with commonly owned open space areas
than in non-clustered subdivisions. Mohamed (2006) uses data from South Kingstown, Rhode
Island, to examine per-acre lot prices in the two types of subdivisions as well as costs of
development. He estimates a price premium in “conservation” subdivisions of 12 percent to 16
percent and also finds development costs to be lower in conservation subdivisions.2 Neither of
these studies controls for the many other factors that could explain price differences.
Peiser and Schwann (1993) analyze house prices in a Dallas subdivision that has publicly
useable open space between houses and also survey residents about their preferences. While the
survey findings suggest that households place a high value on the open space, the hedonic price
analysis shows otherwise. Houses on the open space generally sold at a premium, but the effect
was statistically insignificant and much smaller in magnitude than the effect of the size of the
private lots themselves.
2 The term “conservation” subdivision usually implies something broader than clustering. Arendt (1997), the most
notable proponent of conservation subdivisions, suggests that prior to building on a parcel, the important natural
resources and habitat areas should be delineated and designated as open space. Then, after the developer has
considered slopes and soils, houses should be clustered onto the land most suitable for development.
3
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
Although other studies using subdivision sales data do not focus specifically on the
effects of clustering on house prices (or the extent of the trade-off between subdivision open
space and lot size), they still shed light on the value of particular characteristics of open space
amenities within subdivisions or from proximity to open space surrounding, but external to, the
subdivision. For example, Thorsnes (2002) uses sales data from 1978 to 2000 from three
subdivisions in Grand Rapids, Michigan, each bordering permanently preserved forested lands,
to estimate hedonic price equations for both building lots and houses for each subdivision. He
finds that lots next to the preserves sell at a premium equal to 19 percent to 35 percent of the
total lot price, but the benefits appear very localized. Prices of lots across the street from the
preserve are, for the most part, no different from those of other lots in the subdivisions.
Hardie, Lichtenberg, and Nickerson (2006), using a random sample of subdivisions in
five Maryland counties, calculate the average per-acre price of developed lots in 255
subdivisions. Their price estimate is a function of the percentage of the subdivision area that is
required to be planted in trees (by the state Forest Conservation Act) and the percentage of
surrounding land in farmland and other kinds of open space as well as other factors likely to
affect house prices. They find that land prices increase with an increase in the percentage of land
that is required to be planted in trees. Their paper is only able to draw conclusions about average
prices in a subdivision.3
Patterson and Boyle (2002) focus on estimating the value of a view from evidence on
housing prices. Using a hedonic estimation, they find that houses with forested area visibility
have higher value than those with visibility of agricultural land. Kearney (2006), in a survey of
residents of different subdivisions with different configurations and different amounts and types
of open space, also finds that the view from a home, and particularly views of forested areas, are
strongly valued by residents.
Complementing the economic literature are several studies by urban planners who look at
the environmental merits of clustering rules and conservation subdivisions, especially with
3
Because of missing data, they must also construct lot sales prices for some subdivisions before averaging.
4
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
respect to habitat and ecological benefits that likely pertain to the entire region, not just the
subdivision. Berke and his colleagues (2003) find that there are potential watershed protection
benefits to new urbanist developments compared to conventional developments.4 Odell,
Theobald, and Knight (2003) show that songbird habitat is less disrupted by clustered
development than conventional, non-clustered development. A survey of residents of
subdivisions in Michigan by Kaplan, Austin, and Kaplan (2004) find that “natural features” of
subdivisions appear to be important to residents of clustered subdivisions.
These studies provide evidence of different types of amenities from open space in or next
to subdivisions. We look for similar evidence but focus on open space amenities within the
subdivision and trade-offs between those amenities and private lot space.
Data
Calvert County is located in southern Maryland on the western shore of the Chesapeake
Bay. It has 101 miles of shoreline along the Chesapeake Bay and the Patuxent River to the east.
Historically, the county has been made up of small villages and predominantly rural lands and
has had an agricultural economy. In the past 20 years, however, population growth has been high
and the county has increasingly become part of the broad Baltimore-Washington, DC,
metropolitan area.5
Most of the housing growth in recent years has been in low-density suburban
subdivisions in the residential and rural areas of the county. Figure 1 shows average lot sizes
within the county by different time periods.6 Although the average gross lot size, calculated as
total subdivision acreage divided by the number of houses, has remained relatively high and
constant over time, the average lot size net of open space has declined. This provides some
4
The term “new urbanist” generally implies more than conserving open space and building more densely; it also
incorporates mixed use development, providing pedestrian and transit options, and other factors. For studies that
focus on the merits of new urbanism, see Song and Knaap (2004).
5
The northern border is about 35 miles from Washington, DC, and 40 miles from Baltimore.
6
The time periods are chosen to reflect zoning and other changes in the county.
5
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
indication of the extent to which clustering has increased in the county in recent years. Gross lot
size trended up in the late 1990s due to the downzoning that occurred, but actual house lot size
continued to fall slightly, reflecting more open space in subdivisions.
Figure 1. Average Lot Size in Subdivisions, Calvert County, Maryland
3.5
Gross average lot size
3.0
Average lot size net of open space
Lot size (acres)
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
1964-1974
1975-1979
1980-1992
1993-1998
1999-2001
Subdivision recording period
In this study, we limit the sample to subdivisions that had at least 10 house sales over the
study period (1981–2001). This allows us to include 3,386 individual house sales within 89
subdivisions. Table 1 provides summary statistics for house and subdivision level variables
included in the model. The mean lot size is 1.5 acres and subdivisions are, on average, 134 acres
with a little more than 20 percent of their land under easement as protected open space. The
degree of clustering varies considerably over the sample, however; 16 of the 89 subdivisions
have minimal open space (less than 1 acre) and 20 subdivisions have more than 40 percent of
their acreage in open space.
6
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
Table 1. Summary Statistics for House and Subdivision Data, Calvert County, MD
Variable
Mean
Std. Dev.
Range
House variables (3,386 house sales)
House sale price (in year 2000 dollars)a
Lot size (acres)
Sale year
221,749.30
1.511
1994.422
Structural characteristics:
House size (square feet)
2075.047
House age (years)
5.821
Dwelling grade (dummy)b
0.177
Number of full bathrooms
1.999
Number of half bathrooms
0.583
Fireplace (dummy)
0.618
Townhouse
0.008
Open space and surrounding land uses (dummy variables):
Adjacent to subdivision open space area
0.249
Adjacent to another subdivision’s open space
0.024
Adjacent to preserved farmland or parkland
0.014
Adjacent to undeveloped, unpreserved land
0.142
Adjacent to water
0.016
Subdivision variables (89 subdivisions)
Size of subdivision (acres)
Size of subdivision open space area (acres)
Proportion of open space area in steep slopesc
Subdivision recording year
Accessibility/location:
Distance to the northern border of county
(meters)
Access to Town Center indexd
Distance to Route 2/4 (meters)
RCD Rural zoning district (dummy)
FCD Rural zoning district (dummy)
Residential zoning district (dummy)
Town Center (dummy)
74,000.48
1.586
5.087
801.959
10.026
0.382
0.512
0.498
0.486
0.091
0.433
0.153
0.118
0.351
0.126
133.615
28.951
0.373
1983.675
104.853
46.316
0.347
10.218
18965.170
10.732
2419.191
0.685
0.079
0.213
0.022
13351.700
83.375
1799.510
0.467
0.271
0.412
0.149
12642.15–939179.5
0.034–30.41
1981–2001
576–6575
0–186
0–1
1–5
0–2
0–1
0–1
0–1
0–1
0–1
0–2
0–1
16.609–589.590
0.250–295.130
0–1
1928–1999
955.715–49912.290
0–768.431
167.872–7633.653
0–1
0–1
0–1
0–1
a
CPI adjusted prices.
Dwelling grade equals 1 if house is categorized as low to fair quality, and 0 otherwise.
c
Steep slopes are defined as land with a grade of 15 percent or higher.
d
Access to Town Center is a simple gravity index that is increasing in the size of the eight major town centers and decreasing
with distance from the subdivision location. The index is defined as:
b
c
I i = ∑ ( M k / d ik2 )
k =1
where i denotes the subdivision, c is the number of town centers, Mk is the size of town center k, and dik is the distance from
subdivision i to town center k.
7
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
Econometric Model and Results
We assume households choose housing characteristics, location, and open space
amenities so as to maximize utility. Under this assumption and also assuming a housing market
in equilibrium, we can use the hedonic price model to examine consumer behavior with regard to
housing choices.7 The hedonic price function is specified as:
P = f(l, C, S, T, O),
(1)
where P is the price of the property, l represents the lot size, C is a vector of the structural
characteristics (age, number of bathrooms, square footage, etc.) associated with the house, S is a
vector of subdivision characteristics other than open space amenities, T represents a vector of
accessibility measures, and O is a vector of open space attributes.
Because evidence from the literature suggests that the value of open space amenities to
residents may vary by proximity or the type of open space (e.g., number of trees, usability,
steepness), in our model we include three subdivision open space variables: open space acreage,
a dummy for whether a house is adjacent to subdivision open space, and the percentage of
subdivision open space that is in steep slopes. We also include interaction variables, which we
discuss below, as well as surrounding land use variables, including adjacency to preserved
agricultural land.
Several econometric issues must be addressed in estimating the hedonic model. Irwin
(2002), in a study focusing on farmland and forested lands, discusses the problem of possible
endogeneity of these kinds of open space. In this study, since we are focusing on the amount of
open space inside the subdivision, it is unlikely that endogeneity is a serious concern. Moreover,
all subdivisions since 1993 have had minimum open space requirements. We also assume that
households know and accept county rules, which require that subdivision open space has a
permanent easement barring future development.
7
See Rosen (1974) for the foundations of hedonic analysis.
8
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
We also address the issue of unobserved spatial correlation in the error term, a common
source of inefficiency and inappropriate covariance estimates in spatial models. To partially
address this problem, we have included dummy variables for the 31 census block groups in our
sample to account for any unexplained effect of different neighborhoods on prices.8 In addition,
we tested for spatial autocorrelation and rejected the null hypothesis that it is not present, even
with block group dummies.9 Therefore, to account for spatial correlation caused by
misspecification of the regression function (e.g., omitted variables), we specify the error term
with a standard first-order AR process (Anselin 1988), in which the error depends on the
weighted average of the error terms of “neighboring” houses, which we define to be houses that
are in the same or adjacent subdivisions.10 The results are shown in Table 2. We tested the
sensitivity of our results by estimating the model with an alternative weighting scheme in which
all houses within 1 mile of each other are considered neighbors.11 This latter specification
yielded coefficients of similar magnitude and significance as the results presented in Table 2.
Results: Preferences for Lot Size and Subdivision Open Space Amenities
Households have a consistent preference for larger lots, when all other factors are the
same. We calculate homeowners’ marginal willingness to pay for additional private acreage and
subdivision open space by the partial derivatives of the price function with respect to each
attribute, evaluated at the mean values of the relevant interaction variables. The elasticity
estimates at the bottom of Table 2 summarize the results of that calculation. We find that a 10
8 We
tested a number of different specifications, including a subdivision fixed-effects model. While that
specification has the advantage of controlling for all unobserved subdivision characteristics, it prevents us from
estimating the effect of specific subdivision-level variables, including the total amount of subdivision open space. In
general, coefficients on house-specific variables are very similar to the results with block group fixed effects shown
in Table 2.
9 The Moran I statistic is found to be 11.570.
10 Letting u denote the vector of error terms, u , i = 1 to N , in our model, we assume u = ρW u + ε , where ρ is the
i
i
i
i
spatial autocorrelation parameter to be estimated, Wi is the ith row of the weighting matrix, W, and ε i is the
component of the error term made up of independently and identically distributed (iid) random variables. The
weighting matrix, W, selects the “neighbors” so that W = {wij}, where wij = 1/ni (where ni = number of “neighbors”
of house i) if i and j are within the same or adjacent subdivisions. Because a subdivision is not viewed as its own
neighbor, wii = 0 for all i.
11 With the 1-mile weighting scheme, the Moran I test statistic is 12.895.
9
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
percent increase in private lot size is associated with an approximately 0.6 percent increase in
house price, all else being equal. This suggests that for an average-priced house in 2004 (about
$300,000), an increase in lot size from 1 acre to 1.5 acres would increase the house price by
about $9,000. The magnitude of this estimate is robust across various specifications of the
model, including one with subdivision fixed effects.
The amount of open space in the subdivision, given subdivision size, is also statistically
significant; its effect on house prices is small, but positive. When all other factors are held
constant, a 10 percent increase in subdivision open space leads to a 0.1 percent increase in
average house price. This result was also robust to alternative specifications of the model. This
suggests that increasing open space acreage from 20 acres to 30 acres would increase sales price
by half a percent, or $1,500 per house (evaluated at an average of $300,000), holding all else
constant. Of course, all the houses in the subdivision would be affected if open space increased.
There is some evidence that residents will trade off their own lot size for the amount of
open space in the subdivision. The interaction term between the amount of open space and
private lot size is negative, which implies some trade-off. We show the full effects of changes
below.
Adjacency to subdivision open space has a positive effect on house prices, but the
magnitude of the effect depends on how much of the open space is in steep slopes. The greater
the percentage of open space that is steep, the smaller the effect that adjacency has on house
prices.12
Perhaps our most surprising result is that we find no willingness of households to trade
off their own lot size for adjacency to open space. One explanation for this may be the result
from the literature that suggests it is not so much proximity to open space, but having a view of
forested or undeveloped areas, that is valuable to residents (e.g. Patterson and Boyle 2002).
12
Our steepness variable can not measure the slope of the open space adjacent to particular houses, but the greater
the percentage of open space in the subdivision in steep slopes, the higher the probability that any house adjacent to
open space will be adjacent to steep open space.
10
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
Table 2. Results of the Spatial Error Model with Block Group Fixed Effects
(Dependent variable is the natural log of house sale price)
Variable
1
Description
Own lot size (acres, logged)
Variables related to subdivision open space
Subdivision open space (acres, logged)
Percent of open space acres in steep slopes
Subdivision open space (var 2)*pct steep (var 3)
Subdivision open space (var 2)*own lot size (var 1)
Adjacent to own subdivision open space (dummy)
Adjacent to own sub open space (var 6)*pct steep (var 3)
Adjacent to own sub open space (var 6)*lot size (var 1)
Other adjacency variables
Adjacent to another subdivision’s open space area
Adjacent to water
Adjacent to undeveloped, unpreserved land
Adjacent to preserved farmland or parkland
House characteristics
House size (square ft, logged))
Age of house
Dwelling grade
Number of full baths
Number of half baths
Fireplace (dummy)
Townhouse (dummy)
Accessibility variables
Distance to northern border of county (meters, logged)
Distance to Route 2/4 (meters, logged)
Accessibility to Town Centers
Other subdivision variables
Subdivision size (acres, logged)
Year subdivision was recorded
Subdivision in Farm Community District
Subdivision in Residential zone
Subdivision in Town Center
Constant
Spatial autocorrelation parameter, ρ
R2
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
Coefficient (t-stat)
0.078*** (10.423)
0.010** (2.279)
–0.024 (–1.140)
–0.003 (–0.410)
–0.007*** (–2.715)
0.029** (2.181)
–0.059** (–2.327)
0.016 (1.512)
0.010 (0.582)
0.300*** (12.805)
–0.006 (0.741)
–0.012 (0.532)
0.280*** (23.042)
–0.002*** (–5.896)
–0.090*** (–6.845)
0.073*** (10.159)
0.039*** (5.437)
0.037*** (5.922)
–0.113** (–2.435)
–0.129*** (–4.361)
–0.026** (–2.533)
0.000 (0.245)
0.026*** (2.751)
0.002*** (75.502)
0.011 ( 0.473)
–0.025 (1.241)
0.037 (0.168)
4.792 (14.909)
0.358 (41.269)
0.7795
Coefficients on individual sale year and census block group dummy variables available upon request.
Asymptotic t-statistic given in parentheses. *** signifies significance at the 99% level; ** at the 95% level;
*
at the 90% level.
Marginal effect
evaluated at var. means
Elasticity of sales price with respect to:
Own lot sizea
Subdivision open space acreage
Adjacency to own subdivision open space
(t-stat in parentheses)
0.055*** (7.15)
0.006* (1.75)
0.014* (1.68)
a
Marginal effect for interior lot; for lot adjacent to open space, the marginal effect of own lot size is 0.070
11
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
Results: Other Variables
Most of the other explanatory variables in the model are significant and of the expected
sign. All the variables describing house characteristics and variables measuring proximity to
commuting routes are significant at the 99 or 95 percent level. The northern edge of Calvert
County marks the closest point in the county to the urban centers of Washington, DC, and
Baltimore; moving the average house 1 mile farther south reduces house price by a little more
than 1 percent. Locating the average house farther from the major highway in the county, Route
2/4, also significantly reduces sales price. Larger and newer subdivisions tend to have slightly
higher-priced houses.
Some of the other amenities and surrounding land uses are important in explaining house
prices and others are not. Being on the water is highly valuable: sales prices of waterfront houses
(on the Patuxent River or Chesapeake Bay) are found to be 30 percent higher than prices of other
houses. However, being adjacent to parkland, privately owned preserved farmland, or the open
space area of another subdivision does not significantly affect housing prices.13
Simulating the Effect of Clustered Subdivisions on House Prices
There are multiple effects of lot size and open space amenities on housing prices from the
analysis above. We can illustrate the overall effects of changes in subdivision configuration by a
simple simulation.
We start with a representative subdivision in our sample: 134 acres in size, with about 30
acres of open space and an average lot size of 1.5 acres. Holding total subdivision size and the
number of lots constant, doubling the amount of open space to about 60 acres would require
average lot size to decrease to 1.1 acres. Based on the results in Table 2, we find that such an
increase in clustering (from about 22 to 44 percent) would decrease the average house price by
1.2 percent (for a house not adjacent to open space). The loss in value from the smaller lot size
dominates any increased value from more subdivision open space. The additional clustering may
13
Adjacency to another subdivision’s open space becomes significant at the 10 percent level if subdivision fixed
effects are included in the model.
12
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
also increase the probability of a house being adjacent to the open space area, however, and this
adds some value. For houses on lots that become adjacent to subdivision open space as a result of
the increased clustering, we find the change in sale price is minimal, decreasing by only
0.3 percent.
Conclusions
Our results suggest why we may not see many clustered subdivisions on the urban–rural
fringe without government regulations requiring such clustering. Households appear to strongly
value their own private lots. While we do find in our analysis that households also value having
more open space in their subdivisions or having a lot that is adjacent to subdivision open space,
they do not value these amenities nearly as much as a larger private lot. Thus, reducing private
acreage to provide more public subdivision open space tends to lead to overall reductions in
house prices, all else being equal. The small amount of previous literature on this issue has been
mixed, but these results are consistent with those of Peiser and Schwann (1993).
One of the most important questions we wanted to address in this study is whether
households would be willing to trade off the size of their own lot for open space in the
subdivision. Clustering subdivision development is being viewed by local governments as a way
to reduce the development footprint and preserve open space in fringe communities. Our findings
suggest that there is some small willingness to trade off lot size for more subdivision open space.
But overall, clustering appears to come at a cost to residents within the subdivision. Creating an
acre of subdivision open space in a fixed amount of total land area comes at the expense of
private lot space. When all other factors are equal, this reduces property values, particularly for
lots not adjacent to any open space.
There are caveats to our findings. First, they may be specific to Calvert County, a
community on the urban–rural fringe with very large average lot sizes and a great deal of
surrounding open space and farmland. It is possible that households highly value their large lots
in such a community and also that there are adequate substitutes for subdivision open space. In
addition, the open space in Calvert County subdivisions tends to be forested lands surrounding
the houses and such land may not have a high-use value component. Second, the values captured
13
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
in a hedonic price study may not include all the values of open space, including aesthetic values
to residents outside of the subdivisions, ecological values from habitat protection, and
groundwater protection and stormwater management benefits. These benefits, which accrue to a
wider population, are not likely to be capitalized into house prices within the subdivision.
14
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
References
Anselin, Luc. 1988. “Model Validation in Spatial Econometrics: A Review and Evaluation of
Alternative Approaches,” International Regional Science Review 11(3): 279-316.
Arendt, Randall. 1992. “‘Open Space’ Zoning: What It Is and Why It Works,” Planning
Commissioners Journal 5 (July/August).
Arendt, Randall. 1997. “Basing Cluster Techniques on Development Densities Appropriate to
the Area,” Journal of the American Planning Association 63(1): 137-145.
Berke, Philip, Joseph McDonald, Nancy White, Michael Holmes, Kat Oury, and Rhonda Ryznar.
2003. “Greening Development to Protect Watersheds: Does New Urbanism Make a
Difference?” Journal of the American Planning Association 69(4): 397-413.
Daniels, Thomas L. 1997. “Where Does Cluster Zoning Fit in Farmland Protection?” Journal of
the American Planning Association 63: 129-137.
Hardie, Ian, Erik Lichtenberg, and Cynthia Nickerson. 2006. “Regulation, Open Space, and the
Value of Land Undergoing Residential Subdivision,” University of Maryland working paper.
Irwin, Elena G. 2002. “The Effects of Open Space on Residential Property Values,” Land
Economics. 78(4): 465-480.
Kaplan, Rachel, Maureen E. Austin, and Stephen Kaplan. 2004. “Open Space Communities:
Resident Perceptions, Nature Benefits, and Problems with Terminology,” Journal of the
American Planning Association 70(3): 300-312.
Kearney, Anne R. 2006. “Residential Development Patterns and Neighborhood Satisfaction,
Impacts of Density and Nearby Nature,” Environment and Behavior 38(1): 112-139.
Lacy, Jeff. 1990. “An Examination of Market Appreciation for Clustered Housing with
Permanent Open Space,” Center for Rural Massachusetts report.
McConnell, Virginia, and Margaret Walls. 2005. “The Value of Open Space: Evidence from
Studies of Non-Market Benefits,” Resources for the Future, Washington DC.
15
Resources for the Future
Kopits, McConnell, and Walls
Mohamed, Rayman. 2006. “The Economics of Conservation Subdivisions: Price Premiums,
Improvement Costs, and Absorption Rates,” Urban Affairs Review 41(3) (January): 376-399.
Odell, Eric A., David M. Theobald, and Richard Knight. 2003. “Incorporating Ecology into Land
Use Planning: The Songbirds’ Case for Clustered Development,” Journal of the American
Planning Association 69(1) (Winter): 72-82.
Patterson, Robert, and Kevin Boyle. 2002. “Out of Sight, Out of Mind: Using GIS to Incorporate
Visibility in Hedonic Property Value Models,” Land Economics 78(3): 417-425.
Peiser, R.B., and G.M. Schwann. 1993. “The Private Value of Public Open Space Within
Subdivisions,” Journal of Architectural and Planning Research 10(2): 91-104.
Rosen, Sherwin. 1974. “Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure
Competition,” Journal of Political Economy 82(1): 34-55.
Song, Yan, and Gerrit-Jan Knaap. 2004. “Measuring the Effects of Mixed Land Uses on Housing
Values,” Regional Science and Urban Economics 34: 663-680.
Thorsnes, Paul. 2002. “The Value of a Suburban Forest Preserve: Estimates from Sales of
Vacant Residential Building Lots,” Land Economics 78(3): 426-441.
16
Download