AMBIO A JOURNAL OF THE HUMAN ENVIRONMENT VOLUME XXXV NUMBER 6, SEPTEMBER 2006 The economics of greenhouse gases advocates that mankind should minimize the total social cost of climate change and equate the marginal cost of abatement to the present value of the marginal damages. As greenhouse gases accumulate, temperatures warm, and damages increase, abatement should increase as well. But how much abatement is justified over time given the magnitude of expected damages from climate change? We now know a lot more about the impacts of climate change than we did a few decades ago. The literature has quantified ‘‘market impacts’’ to agriculture, forestry, energy, water, and coasts. ‘‘Non-market impacts’’ to coasts, ecosystems, and human health have also been identified. In this essay, I will focus on market impacts but many of the qualitative insights apply to non-market impacts as well. Impacts have been valued primarily by using either experimental-simulation modeling or cross-sectional analysis. These studies suggest that the welfare of farms, homes, and firms tend to have a hill-shaped relationship with temperature. This hill-shape implies that small amounts of warming are good for subjects currently on the cool side and bad for subjects currently on the warm side of the optimum. The impacts of climate change will vary from being beneficial to harmful depending on current climate conditions. More recent research has also shown that people will adapt to climate change and change their behavior. Farms will switch crops and livestock, households will switch fuels towards electricity and invest in cooling, and forest owners will expand intensive plantations and shift species. Governments also have a role to play in adaptation, for example, by reallocating water or raising fortified structures along valuable coasts. When adaptation is included, impact studies imply that climate changes over the next 50 years will have very small net impacts because expected agricultural and forestry benefits will offset expected energy, coastal, and water damages. The present value of damages to the global economy from an emission of carbon today is small. These results justify only modest Editorial 273 Degradation of Littoral Habitats by Residential Development: Woody Debris in Lakes of the Pacific Northwest and Midwest, United States Tessa B. Francis and Daniel E. Schindler 274–280 Global Invasive Potential of 10 Parasitic Witchweeds and Related Orobanchaceae Kamal I. Mohamed, Monica Papes, Richard Williams, Brett W. Benz and A. Townsend Peterson 281–288 The Economic Impact of Sea-level Rise on Nonmarket Lands in Singapore Wei-Shiuen Ng and Robert Mendelsohn 289–296 Assessing the Risk of Impact of Farming Intensification on Calcareous Grasslands in Europe: A Quantitative Implementation of the MIRABEL Framework Sandrine Petit and Berien Elbersen 297–303 abatement efforts over the next few decades. As greenhouse gases accumulate, the present value of damages will rise, and more aggressive policies in the future may be warranted. How aggressive these future policies should be will depend on how much climate changes. The current scientific consensus is that unabated warming will range from 1.48C to 5.88C by 2100. If warming falls near the lower end of this range, the benefits and damages from warming will offset each other and there will be little incentive to abate this century. If warming reaches towards the higher end of this range, however, the impacts will be much larger and society should aggressively abate in the future. Recent research into impacts in Africa also suggests that there is an important equity issue not addressed by abatement. Farms that are already hot (in low latitude countries) will suffer large reductions in net revenue from climate change (1). Low latitude countries will likely bear the biggest brunt of climate change damages (2). In contrast, mid-high latitude farms are expected to benefit. Low latitude economies heavily depend on agriculture and the people are amongst the poorest in the world. The bulk of greenhouse gas emissions will come from relatively wealthy countries, but the bulk of victims will be relatively poor. The world should consider a compensation package for low latitude countries for future damages. For example, the world could help these poor countries develop their economies away from climate sensitive agriculture. References 1. Kurukulasuriya, P., Mendelsohn, R., Hassan, R., Benhin, J., Diop, M., Eid, H. M., Fosu, K. Y., Gbetibouo, G., Jain, S., Mahamadou, A., El-Marsafawy, S., Ouda, S., Ouedraogo, M., SPne, I.,Seo, N., Maddison, D., and Dinar A. 2006. Will African Agriculture Survive Climate Change? World Bank Economic Review (in press). 2. Mendelsohn, R., Dinar, A., and Williams, L. 2006. The Distributional Impact of Climate Change On Rich and Poor Countries. Environment and Development Economics 11, 1 –20. Guest Editor Professor Robert Mendelsohn Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies SYNOPSES River Hydrology and the North Atlantic Oscillation: A General Review Joanna Pociask-Karteczka 312–314 Megacryometeors: Distribution on Earth and Current Research Jesus Martinez-Frias and Antonio Delgado Huertas 314–316 Ecological Economic Problems and Development Patterns of the Arid Inland River Basin in Northwest China Lihua Zhou and Guojing Yang 316–318 Hydrological Indicators or Desertification in the Heihe River Basin of Arid Northwest China Qi Shanzhong and Luo Fang 319–321 Growing Need for a Global Environmental Specimen Banking Network Jarkko Utriainen 322–323 International River Basin Management under the EU Water Framework Directive: An Assessment of Cooperation and Water Quality in the Baltic Sea Drainage Basin Susanna Nilsson and Sindre Langaas 304–311 Ambio Vol. 35, No. 6, September 2006 Ó Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2006 http://www.ambio.kva.se 273