MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02618 0221 DUPL Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from MIT Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/biddingforindust0439gree DEWEY Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Econonnics Working Paper Series Bidding for Industrial Plants: Does Winning a "Million Dollar Plant" Increase Welfare? Michael Greenstone Enrico Moretti Working Paper 04-39 November, 2004 RoomE52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, 02142 MA This paper can be downloaded without c harge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection http://ssrn.com/abstract=6231 22 at MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY DEC ? 200^1 LIBRARIES I Bidding for Industrial Plants: Does Winning a 'Million Dollar Plant' Increase Welfare? Michael Greenstone MIT, American Bar Foundation and NBER Enrico Moretti University of California, Berkeley and NBER November 2004 We thank Alberto Abadie, Michael Ash, Hal Cole, David Card, Gordon Dahl, Thomas Davidoff, Michael Davidson, Rajeev Dehejia, Stefano Delia Vigna. Mark Duggan, Jinyong Hahn, Robert Haveman, Vernon Henderson, Ali Hortacsu, Matthew Kahn, Tom Kane, Brian Knight, Alan Krueger, Steve Levitt, Boyan Jovanovic, David Lee, Therese McGuire, Derek Neal, Matthew Neidell. Aviv Nevo, John Quigley, Karl Scholz, Chad Syverson, Duncan Thomas and seminar Columbia, Illinois, Michigan, NYU, NBER Summer Wisconsin for very helpful discussions. Kanter, Yan Lee, Moretti thanks the Adina Allen, Ben at Brown, Chicago, Wharton, and Gallagher, Genevieve PhamBerkeley, Rice. Stanford, Bolitzer. Justin UCLA, Schulhofer-Wohl, Antoine St-Pierre, and William Young provided outstanding Greenstone acknowledges generous funding from the American Bar Foundation. Sam research assistance. participants Institute. UCLA Senate for a generous grant. Bidding for Industrial Plants: Does Winning a 'Million Dollar Plant* Increase Welfare? Abstract Increasingly, local governments locate within their jurisdictions. compete by offering substantial subsidies to industrial plants to This paper uses a novel research design to estimate the local consequences of successfully bidding for an industrial plant, relative to bidding and losing, on labor Each issue of Ihe corporate real estate journal Site earnings, public finances, and property values. Selection includes an article titled "The Million Dollar Plant" that reports the county where a large plant chose to locate (i.e., the 'winner'), as well as the these revealed one or two runner-up counties (i.e., the 'losers'). We use rankings of profit-maximizing firms to form a counterfactual for what would have happened in the winning counties in the absence of the plant opening. We find that the plant opening announcement is associated with a 1.5% trend break in labor earnings in the new plant's industry in winning counties, as well as increased earnings in the same industry in counties that neighbor the winner. Further, there is modest evidence of increased expenditures for local services, such as public education. Property values may provide a summary measure of the net change in welfare, because the costs and benefits of attracting a plant should be capitalized into the price of land. If the winners and losers are homogeneous, a simple model suggests that any rents should be bid away. We find a positive, relative trend break of approximately 1.1-1.7% in property values. Since the winners and losers have similar observables in advance of the opening announcement, the property value results may be explained by heterogeneity in subsidies from higher levels of government (e.g., states) and/or systematic underbidding. Overall, the results undermine the popular view that the provision of local subsidies to attract large industrial plants reduces local residents' welfare. Michael Greenstone Enrico Moretti MIT Department University of California, Berkeley of Economics 50 Memorial Drive, E52-359 Cambridge. 02 1 42- 347 MA and NBER mgreenst@,m it.edu 1 Department of Economics CA 94720-3880 Berkeley, and NBER moretti@econ.berkeley.edu Introduction • Over the past 30 years, state and local governments have economic development. assumed a greater responsibility for For example, they frequently offer substantial subsidies to businesses These incentives can include tax breaks, low-cost or free within their jurisdictions. to locate land, the issuance of tax-exempt bonds, training funds, the construction of roads, and other infrastructure investments. These policies are controversial: local politicians and the subsidized companies usually extol the benefits of these deals, while critics complain that they are a waste of public monies.' competing claims, because there is little systematic evidence on the consequences of these policies.^ approach to evaluating policies designed I'he traditional plant in is it to calculate the is widely cited for locating in Vance, Georgetown, Kentucky was awarded $200 million ($80,000 per job) and Boeing was given $50 million ($100,000 per job) it plants Mercedes received a $250 million ($165,000 per job) incentive package Alabama, the Toyota in new For example, at attracting number of jobs gained and the cost of the tax breaks awarded to firms. that difficult to evaluate these It is in tax abatements to locates its corporate headquarters Chicago (Mitol 2001; Trogen 2002). This "accounting" approach produces eye-catching but statistics, has two important limitations. First, these calculations are done ex-ante and are rarely verified ex-post. Second, and more fundamentally, this approach does not offer a framework policies increase or decrease welfare of local residents. the residents of Vance, On ' the results on this question, as one hand, some models suggest that the positive spillovers and/or increases producer surplus. enhancing or, at least, neutral for local residents. local subsidies may is determining whether the $165,000 per job good deal a for Alabama? Economic theory provides mixed recent survey. For example, for reflect government gain or satisfying Leviathan goals. On emphasized by Glaeser (2001) attraction in a of new businesses generates In these cases, local subsidies may be welfare the other hand, there are models that indicate that officials' private interests In these settings, local by providing for government their own financial officials grant subsidies whose costs to local residents are larger than the benefits and therefore reduce residents" welfare. - This paper empirically assesses the consequences for counties of successfully bidding for large industrial plants ' on county-level earnings, property values, and government finances. For example, a recent front-page provided generous subsidies to limited benefits to the local article in the attract large New York Times manufacturing firms economy. ("Paying for Jobs The empirical describes the experience of several localities that in the 1980s and 1990s and apparently obtained Doesn't Always Pay Off, New York Times, November 10, 2003). " "seem to be a economic landscape, economists do not yet know why these incentives occur and desirable". Further a Standard & Poor's publication states, "Economic development wars of In a recent survey of the literature, Glaeser (2001) concludes that, although location based-incentives permanent part of whether they are in the urban fact recent years have not developed a sufficient track record to assess their true cost-benefit ratio" (Standard 1 993 ). Bartik ( 1 99 1 ) provides the most comprehensive evidence. & Poor's challenge choose to locate where that plants is their expected profits are highest, which are a function of A any subsidies. their location-specific expected future costs of production and depend on many costs of production in a county plant's expected future unobservable factors, including the presence of a suitable skills, and the local regulatory transportation infrastructure, the availability of workers with particular environment. These factors are typically difficult to measure and factors, including number of unmeasured importance varies across Similarly, the subsidies are likely to be a plants based on plants' unobserved production functions. function of a their relative any potential spillovers and the degree of local politicians' malfeasance. Heterogeneity counties the factors that determine variation in costs of production and subsidies across in likely to bias standard estimators. Valid estimates is identification of a county that is of the impact of a plant opening require the identical to the county where the plant decided to locate We future production costs and the factors that determine subsidies. ascertain and As measure all a solution, we rely to open a large subsequently narrow the both expected in our ability to in the absence of the plant opening. These rankings come how which includes a regular a large plant decided plant, they typically begin to roughly 10 list sites, where selection process, but narrowly lost the competition. firms are considering by considering dozens of possible among which the 'losers'). (i.e.. feature titled the "Million When to locate. (i.e., The "Million the 'winner'), as well as the The losers are counties that Our identifying assumption is have survived a long is invalid, we suspect that this pairwise sampling approach is form a that the losers in pre-existing trends. valid counterfactual for the winners, after adjustment for differences assumption They locations. 2 or 3 finalists are selected. Dollar Plants" articles report the county that the plant ultimately chose one or two runner-up counties to identify a valid on the revealed rankings of profit-maximizing firms real estate journal Site Selection, Dollar Plants" that describes where in these factors. counterfactual for what would have happened from the corporate have little faith Even if this preferable to the leading alternative of comparing winners to the other 3,000 U.S. counties. Consistent with our assumption, we find that before the winning and losing counties have similar trends employment-population ratio. in wage bill, years before the announcement of the winner, the trends finding ' suggests that Under not the winner county, employment, per capita income and Several other observable characteristics are also similar. trends in the winning counties tend to be different from trends in are virtually identical. announcement of the plausible assumption only are in all other US By counties. Notably contrast, in the 8 property values in winning and losing counties that property markets are forward-looking, this before the winning and losing counties similar in the years tax competitions and the See also the classic Gates (1Q72) and Zodrovv and Mieszkowski (1986) papers on Wilson 1999) provides another recent review of this literature. provision of local public goods. ( annouiiceincnt. but the expected Future changes values are also ex-ante similar. economic in activity arc capitalized into property tliat Overall, these findings lend credibility to the identifying assumption that the losers form a valid counterfactual for the winners. The primai7 employment by a statistically significant opening announcement 1-digit industry in result that in the $16.8 million per year in new wage bill in in the the new wage some of the attraction bill in first of a new the I -digit industry the winning counties (relative plant's I -digit industry We wage to losing 1.5% of the average wage is Taken year before the announcement. the plant opening than predicted by pre-existing trends. the total plants' (relative to the period before). This winning counties that six years later the is increased bill ones) after the bill in the plant's literally, this implies roughly $100 million higher due to is also find evidence of positive trend breaks in plant's industry in counties that neighbor the winner.' These results provide ex-post estimates of the increase in local economic activity due to the successful large, new plant and indicate that the new activity doesn't crowd out existing activity locally. However, by themselves, these findings local residents' welfare subsidies effect is We unavailable. of attracting a plant the increased economic taxes—or reduction We in cost. will be reflected in property values. (i.e. This may homogeneous and pay values. This from state because property values capitalize (i.e. the cost of the subsidy).' derive a simple model that demonstrates that in the presence of bidding for plants by cause property values to increase, decrease or remain unchanged. politicians solely maximize This is is for part because counties raise their bids When because the county that has the less than the politicians derive private benefits most homogenous result in increased property attractive characteristics or the largest contribution second best county, and from granting subsidies, they still win the will overbid, ',',,, decrease. of until the costs counties are not may of the subsidy, the successful attraction of a plant government can bid When residents' welfare, the successful attraction equal the benefits and they are indifferent about winning or losing. if states is the benefit of the subsidy) and the increase in property public services— necessary to pay for the subsidy a plant will leave property values unchanged. or Direct information on the cost of the follow the stylized Roback (1982) model and argue that the net welfare activity in the county counties, a successful bid counties are are not informative about whether the subsidies increase because they do not account for their ., , when local and property values may plant. Finally • , , . See Hanson (1998) for evidence that local shocks affect neighboring jurisdictions and that this effect dissipates with distance. See Chapter 2 of Bartik (1991) for a review of the effects of state and local economic development programs on employment and economic growth in local areas. On a related topic, Evans and Topoleski (2002) examine the social and economics consequences of the opening of an Indian casino. ' Gyourko and Tracy 1991 demonstrate that the efficient provision of public services is capitalized into land. They ( ) find that with services held constant, higher taxes are associated with lower land values. Ultimately, the question of the effect of successfully attracting a plant on property values empirical one. Using a unique self-collected data results in increased property values. Specifically, break of approximately 1.1-1.7% model's assumptions are valid, Even if in file, we we find that the successful attraction find that in this finding can be interpreted as an increase The of local subsidies final part to attract large industrial plants of the paper estimates the is welfare for local residents. in Governments, we find that local governments in in police government finances. A Using data from the Annual Survey of winning counties experienced positive and roughly equal trend breaks in revenues and expenditures. Notably, there and no change local governments pay for them by cutting that local important services, such as education and police protection.'' expenditures. Overall, there is is little a substantial increase in education spending evidence of deterioration in the provision of public services in counties that win '"Million Dollar" plants. We for a county want to emphasize that the focus of successfully bidding for a new related policy and/or welfare questions, only of this paper the credible estimation of the consequences is plant, relative to bidding some of which analysis does not provide evidence on whether states competitions between local governments to attract new and losing. For example, the business. Further, it whole benefit from tax is not informative about at all. However, since openings induce tax competitions between jurisdictions, the salient question for a government interested in attracting one of these plants consequences of successfully bidding. The analysis The paper proceeds local subsidies There are a number of paper can address. this or the nation as a whether individual counties should pursue industrial development policies virtually all large plant It a relative trend decreases welfare. winning a plant on effect of widespread concern about the provision of subsidies local is annual property values after the plant opening announcement. If our the assumptions are not valid, the property value results appear to undermine the popular view that the provision vital winning counties there an is of a plant as follows. by local governments also provides a case study of describes our research design. Section 1 is Section III but what are the and the determinants of plants' location decisions. new plant in South Carolina and intuitively reviews the Roback (1982) model opening and presents a stylized model of counties' decisions on property values. Section ail structured to inform this very question. decision to locate a II not whether to bid at reviews the theoretical explanations for the provision of to attract plants BMW's is to bid for describes the data sources and presents Glaeser (2001) emphasizes the importance of answering what happens when localities are deprived of the marginal this in the context of a plant a plant and the effect of winning some summary statistics. Section question empirically, "Economists need to estimate dollar. Does this loss lead to eliminating very valuable services or are fairly marginal services cut off?" (pp. il-12). If outcomes in counties that bid and lose are similar to counties without industrial development policies, then the analysis sheds light on the broader question of the consequences of whether industrial development policies are welfare enhancing. There is no a priori reason to believe that this condition does or does not hold. IV explains the econometric iikhIcI and Section V describes the results. Section VI interprets the results and VI concludes. 1 I. This section is Local Subsidy and Plant Location Decisions divided into two parts. The governments use incentives local provides a case study of BMW's to atti'act Why do more real Some New of incentives to decisions. is localities models may be unable that the standard Here, in we review a recent line why The second subsection jurisdictions. the Greenville-Spartanburg Plants? firms reduces the welfare of a locality's because the incentives lead to inefficiently high levels of local production. Yet, world, large businesses frequently receive subsidies implication why is tiicir generally, describes the intuition of our research design. Local Governments Offer Subsidies to In standard models, the provision residents.^ This reviews the existing theoretical literature on plants to decision to locate a car assembly plant area of northwestern South Carolina and, A. first some in exchange for to capture of research that provides provide incentives to newly locating firms. in the The their location decision. an important feature of these location a number of possible explanations for some of the This review aims to highlight "structural" forces that are likely to underlie our "reduced- form" estimates of the welfare consequences of successfully attracting a plant. The first set of theories emphasizes the idea One example welfare of their residents. number the in that local governments aim to maximize only the where agglomeration economies are associated with the case For example, finns the location of the firm. as the is same industry may experience productivity increases or size of geographically concentrated firms increase (Henderson 2003; Garcia-Mila and McGuire 2001). These spillovers workers (Ranch 1993; Glaeser other firms in the future. to attract the firms that may be due et al. to the sharing of information, the number of high skilled 1995; Moretti 2004a and 2004b), or that the Regardless of their source, in the new firms will attract presence of these spillovers, localities will bid produce them and the resulting subsidies allow the firm to capture the spillovers that they produce. Glaeser (2001) suggests that local incentives that will generate analysis suggests that there ' ' may represent bids by communities to attract firms producer surplus for the current residents of the community. may Conventional welfare be welfare triangles to be gained by local workers. In particular, See Wilson (1999) for a review of the theoretical literatures on tax incentives. ). See that paper for further This review follows a recent paper by Glaeser (2001 details. if the labor supply curve new The firm. upward sloping, inframarginal workers is Another explanation for tax incentives tax payments (Wilson 1996). change its made are size of the bids will reflect the welfare gains generated. location, because Gross 2000 and tax collectors. Ramey and Since that these upfront of the "sunk" nature of many Shapiro 2001). The by the presence of the payments are compensation to operate at a site it to credibly makes firms easy commit advance in for future can be costly to industrial investments (see e.g., resulting immobility governments difficult for is it is once a plant begins In particular, better off '" Goolsbee and targets for local to future tax rates, the upfront tax incentives compensate firms for future expropriation. All of the previous theories are consistent with local politicians solely acting in the interests of their citizens, but an alternative view desire on the politician's part to influence, the side-payments employment future bribes will depend may is due to corruption and influence or a government. In the case of corruption and that local incentives are maximize the size of occur through direct payoffs, contributions to re-election for politicians or their friends or family (Glaeser 2001). An on the probability of detection and the punishment. derived from the Leviathan view of government (Brennan and Buchanan 1980). politicians will seek to maximize the welfare of their For the purposes of our paper, are motivated by agglomeration expropriation--suggest that subsidies (We will second subsidies two show set later it is worth noting that the may be in first set As is applied to this case, of models— where local subsidies producer surplus or compensation for ex-post welfare enhancing or, at least, neutral for local residents. under what conditions subsidies can be welfare enhancing or welfare neutral.) The of models— where local subsidies reflect government may alternative possibility of government or the tax base. citizens and the size economies or increases campaigns, or The magnitude of these be welfare decreasing. We officials' private interests— suggest that return to this point in Section II, where we incorporate these alternative views in a simple theoretical framework. B. A its new Case Study of the BMW Plant Location Decision and a New Research Design In this subsection, plant. In particular, we use a concrete example to we estate Journal Site Selection to describe BMW's 1992 decision Greenville-Spartanburg area of South Carolina. Notably, this goal of this case study it is also possible that the a particular firm selected a site for is to site one of the to highlight the empirical difficulties that arise is plant openings on local economies. if there are local how illustrate use information from the "Million Dollar Plant"" series new we (e.g., sports teams). Because our purposes. , ; the corporate real plants in our sample. when we A second estimating the effect of use this case study to informally explain firm generates consumer surplus for the residents. markets for outputs possibility' is less relevant for Further, in a manufacturing plant in the The consumer gains why our are possible focus mainly on manufacturing plants, this may circumvent research design Section these identitlcation problems. A more formal analysis is After overseeing a worldwide competition and considering 250 potential sites for BMW announced months conducted in II. 1991 that in BMW later. they had narrowed the announced that the two of potential candidates list in 1992 new plant, 20 counties. Six competition were Greenville-Spartanburg, finalists in the South Carolina, and Omaha, Nebraska. Finally, to its BMW announced that they would site the plant in they would receive a package of incentives worth appioxiniately $1 Greenville-Spartanburg and that 15 million funded by the state and local governments. Why profit did BMW choose Greenville-Spartanburg? seems reasonable It assume to that firms are maximizers and choose to locate where their expectation of the present discounted value of the stream of future profits is Two greatest. plant's expected future costs a location, which in is The selection it receives BMW factors. characteristics at first is is the present discounted value the site. case provides a rare opportunity to observe the determinants of these two key Consider that the a function of the location's expected supply of inputs and the firm's production technology. The second factor of the subsidy The factors determine their expected future profits. of production first the county's expected supply of inputs. According made Greenville-Spartanburg more attractive than the to other 250 site- BMW, sites the initially considered were: low union density, a supply of qualified workers; the numerous global firms, including 58 German companies, in the area; the high quality transportation infrastructure, including highway, and port access; and access to air, rail, county characteristics are a first key local services. For our purposes, the important point to note here potential source of unobserved heterogeneity. BMW case, they are generally unknown. that these is While these characteristics are well If these characteristics also affect the documented in the outcomes of interest (i.e., labor earnings, property values and county finances), a standard regression that compares Greenville- Spartanburg with the other 3000 A US counties will yield biased estimates of the effect of the plant opening. standard regression will overestimate the effect of plant openings on outcomes, if for example, counties that have more attractive characteristics better outcomes Now, (e.g., (e.g., better higher earnings). consider the second determinant of Dollar Plant" article explains willing to provide transportation infrastructure) tend to have BMW why BMW's decision, the subsidy . The BMW "Million the Greenville-Spartanburg and South Carolina governments with $115 million in subsidies." According were to local officials, the facility's estimated five-year economic impact on the region was $2 billion (although this number surely does not As account for opportunity cost). a part of this $2 billion, the plant was expected to create 2,000 direct jobs and lead to another 2.000 jobs new indirectly created by the by the in related industries BMW A, Greenville-Spartanburg's subsidy for plant. may late 1990s.'' As we argued in subsection be rationalized by the 2000 "spillover" jobs As an example. Magna International began construction on an million plant that was to produce roofs, side panels, doors and other major pieces for the BMW $80 plant in 1993.'^ It some notable that is For this reason, the factors that represent subsidy) heterogeneity a second may counties industrial structure, labor force skills, benefit unemployment determine the a particular plant, depending on their and the other factors that affect spillovers. total size all of the spillover (and presumably the size of the of unobserved source potential more from rate heterogeneity. If this unobserved correlated with outcomes, standard regression equations will be misspecified due to is For example, omitted variables, just as described above. spillovers (and therefore offer more generous subsidies) compares the winners with the other 3000 US if counties that have more to gain in terms of also have better outcomes, then a regression that counties will overestimate the effect of plant openings on outcomes. In order to make valid inferences in the presence of these two forms of heterogeneity, knowledge of the exact form of the selection rule that determines plants' location decisions As the BMW example demonstrates, expected future supply of inputs in two the is faith in to location decisions be confounded by differences — the unknown to we have known they are difficult to measure. all this information. Thus, the effect of a plant opening our ability to ascertain and measure very likely generally necessary. a county and the magnitude of the subsidy— are generally researchers and in the rare cases where they are little factors that determine plant is in factors that In short, determine the plants" profitability at the chosen location. As a solution maximizing firms plant opening. chose loser (i.e., is to this identification problem, to identify a valid counterfactual for we rely on the revealed rankings of what would have happened in profit- the absence of the In particular, the "Million Dollar Plants" articles typically report the county that the plant the 'winner'), as well as Omaha, Nebraska. In the its 2"'' choice (i.e., subsequent analysis the 'loser'). For example, in the we assume that the BMW case, the winning and losing counties are Ben Haskevv, chairman of the Spartanburg Chamber of Commerce, summarized the local view when he said, "The addition of the company will further elevate an already top-rated community for Job growth" (Venable, 1992, p. 630). '" Interestingly, BMW headquarters from '' later decided New Jersey to to open a second plant Although the Magna Plant was slated million in incentives. in the Greenville-Spartanburg area and relocated its U.S. South Carolina. Interestingly, to hire the proportional basis) than those received by 300 workers, incentives BMW, state offered to and local governments only provided about $1.5 Magna are substantially smaller (even on a implying that local governments appear to be judicious concentrating the incentives on plants that are likely to have the largest spillovers. in identical in assumption expected proHts. controlling for dilTcrcnccs t'utiiie we unlikely to hold exactly, is regression adjustment to compare based on observable variables.'' identifying assumption may II. pre-existing trends. in suspect that this pairwise approach Although preferable to using the winners to the other 3,000 U.S. counties or a matching procedure In Section we V, present empirical evidence that suggests that this be valid. Laud When Prices and Wellare Counties Bids for Plants This section presents a simple framework that guides the empirical analysis and helps the resulting estimates. new One of the paper's empirical goals The plant affects housing prices. assumptions under which the change interpreted as a change this is in tlrst to test to interpret whether the successful attraction of a subsection presents a stylized model that specifies some land values induced by the exogenous opening of a plant can be in residents' welfare. In the second subsection, and specify some assumptions about the bidding process. what conditions a successful bid is we The goal of for a plant will result in higher or allow counties to bid for plants this subsection is to show under lower property values (and therefore welfare). A. Land Prices and Welfare Here, we follow the stylized Roback (1982) model, which We assume that decisions. Further, they rent land for is often used to model firm location individuals are perfectly mobile, have identical tastes and a fixed labor supply. homes in the returns to scale technologies and there county where they work. All firms are assumed to have constant is a fixed supply of land in each county.''^ In equilibrium, firm's unit costs equal the nationally determined product price and individuals' utility cannot be increased by moving to a different county. Now. suppose but it is that a county is exogenouslv assigned a new a useful starting point for expository purposes. Importantly, continue to choose their location to maximize profits and The opening of the new The its land purchase and by increasing the '* Propensity score matching our approach observables. score is As it is its is all This case other producers and unrealistic, all new new to increase in the county. plant will directly increase the demand if there plant will lower the costs of production for other an alternative approach (Rosenbaum and Rubin 1983). assumption that the treatment workers respectively. and nominal wages First, the may be number of workers who need housing. Second, are agglomeration economies, the presence of the relative to utility, plant causes land values increase in land values occurs for two reasons. through plant. (i.e., winner status) is Its principal shortcoming "ignorable" conditional on the should be clear from the example, adjustment for observable variables through the propensity unlikely to be sufficient. See Hoehn, Berger, and Blomquist ( 1987) for a model that allows for flexible city boundaries. In the parlance of firms in the county. Roback, productive amenity. this is referred to as a And, in the presence of a productive amenity, firms will bid up the price of land to gain access to the spillovers. In order to retain workers, firms must pay higher wages to compensate them for the higher rental rate of land, so that real wages are unchanged. This necessary because is in equilibrium workers' must be utility constant across counties. With This residents. provides a one-time gain to property owners this set-up, the increase in land values county that receives the new plant. is This because the increase in is the only wages is is B. A Stylized Model of Bidding for Plants and In the previous subsection, the assumed that the new plant to its we assume jurisdiction. in exchange the incentive package (e.g., in In practice, local In this subsection, consider the possibility that the 3,000 U.S. counties compete for the bids. mayor that acts as their agent to bid to attract plants successful bid involves a trade-off for the county. The increase the plant. attract for a plant's location decision. costly to the county, because they involve the provision of services and tax revenues. land in Land Values that a county's residents elect a A Further, the higher rental rate of welfare. county does not have to incur any costs to by offering subsidies or We unchanged. to rent opening of a new plant increased property values because we governments frequently provide subsidies and the remainder of the paper, in the welfare experienced by the county's Thus, under these assumptions, changes land counterbalances any spillovers available to tlrms. in residents' in by the higher prices that workers face offset land (e.g., for apartments/houses), leaving their utility values translate one-to-one in changes change On the one hand, subsidies are may reduce public services includes the special services for the the future stream of new plant stipulated by the construction of roads, or other infrastructure investments, tax abatements, job training funds, provision of low-cost or free land, the issuance of tax-exempt bonds, provision of cheap electric power, protection). is We etc.), as assume well as the standard public services (e.g., garbage removal and police that the county's incentive package is financed by property taxes, so that its cost capitalized into land values.'" On the other hand, the which raises the value of raise the value land. new As plant directly increases the level of the BMW Annual Survey of Governmenis activity in the county, case demonstrates, the presence of the of land indirectly by generating spillovers, lowers the costs of production for other plants. In the economic if, for example, it new plant may Thus, property values capitalize both the costs data, property taxes account for 49% of total revenues from For comparison, total sales and gross receipts taxes account for only 4.5% of total revenues. IiO also attracts other plants and/or own (i.e., the sources. increased property taxes and/or reduced services) and beneHts attracting (i.e., increased economic activity) of tiie plant. tiic Tiiis subsection's goal is when to theoretically analyze increase or decrease property values (and therefore welfare) denote propeity values as expressed as AP,, = Vi| - P, and assume C,j. Vi, that the change denotes the benefit of to the county. We assume also that known is it We the presence of county bidding. property values lor the winning county can be in new plant The increase in property values (in the absence of a subsidy). the successful attraction of a plant will in j for county i, and size of this benefit is to all the other counties bidding it eqiiivalent to the is exogenous and known on the plant. Cy is the cost to the county of the subsidy provided to the plant. In the real world, In this case the total contribution. We it often the case that the state bears part of the cost of the incentive package. is subsidy received by the plant assume that S is exogenous to the B,, is = county and + Cij is where Sy denotes the Sj,, state's provided by the state to account for the benefits to other counties in the state. The we assume plants are the other side of this two-sided matching problem and locate in the county where their future profits are their expected future profits in a given county: the subsidy and the expected future costs that county. offer, due subsidy, values. likely that there It is heterogeneity is in the maximum we assume The not any collusion in the bidding In the A air, rail, We highway, and port access. in likely that there It is is the expected supply of future inputs. denote the value to the firm of higher Zy implies that production costs of firm exogenous to the We county and is known to all assume each county has also other counties, (i.e., Z,j for all i) and all j different county. If this assumption why such overbidding would be is B, I + Z,,, is We assume that Z is other counties' bids incorrect, it b\- (i.e.. B,, for all i). This assumption prevents exaggerating the benefits of locating would cause counties to all "overbid." It is in a not evident an equilibrium strategy. the county-specific cost advantages. sum, i. these factors as rational expectations about the plant's production costs in Overall, the total value for a firm of locating this are lower in county all counties. finns from increasing the subsidy that a count)' offers where counties. BMW case, recall these factors included the presence of qualified workers, the presence of German companies and Z,j. of independent, or private, among firm's choice also depends on the location-specific production costs. heterogeneity in a plant's valuation of a county due to differences in In order to obtain the highest that the firms conduct an English auction in the presence is of production subsidy that counties are willing to to differences in counties characteristics (recall Section I-B). We further assume that there that they will maximized. As described above, two factors determine It maximized. in a particular seems reasonable to county presume is the sum of the subsidy and that a plant will select the county Homogeneous Counties. 1. tiie plants' homogeneous assumption in V in that and Z: we Vi, Z,j. = Vq and Here, we = Zq for Zjj we if this identification assumption Case This case J. is the simplest. welfare and the state provides no subsidy between winning and losing. We S (i.e., i. This would be the case valid. our key identifying if The homogeneity case is important because We Z and to investigate how our consider four cases. assume 0). V in losers. Under homogeneity, the firm simply not valid. is = and plant, Vy, homogeneity assumption when comparing winners and will retain the chooses the county that offers the highest subsidy, B. (!) all analyze the more general model that allows for heterogeneity conclusions differ new begin by considering the case where counties are winners and losers are identical were our empirical analysis, Later, In genera], counties differ in their valuations of a valuation of the county, that the county's The mayor Formally, the equilibrium bid, B*, mayor maximizes raises the bid until she is residents' indifferent determined by is B* = Vo AP = Vo - B* = Consequently, and the successful attraction of the plant does not change land prices or residents' welfare. Case We now 2. assumptions. is It allow states to subsidize the incentives offered magnitude of spillovers in neighboring counties differs across most generous incentive from the most generous state state will win the new does not need to raise the bid until she states. plant. is the county with the second optimal bid B* where 2"'' Here, the county that receives the at the point that makes the between winning and mayor of losing. The S™,., the incentive provided by the second most generous states: provided by the most generous most generous AP = Vq - state. (B*-S|„.ix) = state. between the S^ax - Sn.ax-i state subsidy >0, where Importantly, the source of the increase in in the state subsidies and the county's capture of part of the state subsidy. 3. We now the mayor the incentive housing values Case allow for the possibility that the mayor ma\ have her provided by the S,„ax is heterogeneity we assume located in the indifferent between having the plant and not state subsidy indifferent Specifically, land values increase by the difference most and for example, the is B* = Vo + S,„;,^.| is most generous if, The mayor of the county having the plant. She can win the plant by setting the county's bid (2) to the plant but retain the other possible that different states provide different level of incentives own goals. is the In particular, benefits from a higher incentive package because opportunities for graft or enlarging government are increasing in B. higher the subsidy provided by the mayor We define this personal benefit as to the firm, the larger the kickback. determined probability of detection and punishment, the mayor chooses B which depends on residents' increase in welfare AP and her benefit T: 12 to U = U(AP, T = f(B), with Due to maximize her T); f >0: the an exogenously where U| > utility U, and U2 > case where U2 = 0, there In the 0. are perfectly aligned. own U2 > 0, the is We assume Ut this case, the having the T ma)or no principal-agent problem and the mayor's and residents' we assume For simplicity, of the bid a fixed fraction y is (i.e., T= U(AP,T) that y B), where is separable <y< I raises her bid to the point that plant. If all the mayors behave in the makes her same way, indifferent in its first and U = AP + yB. Thus, . but reinstate the assumption that states do not subsidi/.c the bid ;<: interests mayor's objective function includes residents' welfare as well as her private gain from the subsidy. second argument and (i.e. S = 0). In between having the plant and not the mayor's optimal bid is B*-Vo/(l-y) (3) In this case, the Vo < mayor overbids, by choosing B* which Such overbidding causes land values residents. in larger than the value of the plant to the is the winning county to decline relative to the losing The magnitude of the decline depends on the mayor's weight on her own county. y)) If AP= welfare: (y / (1- - 0. Cose 4. When U2 ^ and there is a positive state subsidy (i.e., S,|>0), the cannot be signed. The state subsidy increases land values, as shown above in the mayor's personal gain in the objective function results in Depending on the magnitude of these two in effects, land values a decrease may case change 2, in land prices but the inclusion of Case land values as in 3. increase or decrease in the winner '^ relative to the loser. 2. Heterogeneous Counties. Although the key assumption winning and losing counties are homogeneous, assumption is not valid. Here, we is our empirical analysis is that the important to understand the consequences allow for heterogeneity V, and plants" valuations of counties, Z. effect it in In section I-B, in counties' valuations we used the BMW if this of attracting the plant, example to argue that the of the plant opening could be confounded by these two sources of unobserved heterogeneity across counties. Specifically, we suspect that a naive estimator that ignores the presence of unobserved heterogeneity will be biased. This subsection formalizes this point. For simplicity, the firm chooses firm j where we to locate of choosing county (Vh) and low V (Vl); and i is two = and Uj = V and Z vary across counties, based not only on the bid B, but also on Z. Specifically, the value for retain the assumptions that Bii+Z,,. Assume levels of Z, high S.j for simplicity that there are only Z bid is such the plant: that the j county with low and is two (Zh) and low Z, (Zl). Consider and Z are positively correlated, so that the county with high gain the most from attracting firm 0. If V also has high Z. levels first is indifferent V where V the case Thus, one county will also the least cost production location for firm Z and low V of V, high j. Its optimal between having the plant and not having B* = Vl-(Zh-Zl). (4) county that In this case, the the best is Land values increase by an amount proportional Vl) + (Zh - Zl) >0. match enjoys a rent that V to the difference in Importantly, the increase in land values capitalized into land values. is and the difference in AP = (Vh - Z: due to the underlying differences is V in and Z. now Consider the case where V Z and are negatively correlated. Vh+Zl > Vl + Zh, county County while county 2 has high Z and low V. If B* indifferent between having the plant and not having the that makes county 2 B* = (5) in rent that the case of positive correlation Zl) - if (V|i Vh+Zl < Vl + Zh- has high V and low Z; plant: + (Zh-Zl) V,. The winner county enjoys a applies 1 wins the plant by bidding an amount 1 is capitalized in land values, although the rent between Z and V: AP = (Vh In this case county 2 Vl) >0. Again, the heterogeneity our empirical analysis are discussed further III. is is Vl) - the winner and (Zh - its is lower than the rent A similar conclusion Zl) >0. AP = land prices increase by the source of the change in the - (Zh The implications in prices.'^ - for econometrics section. Summary Data Sources and Statistics A. Data Sources We implement the design using data on winning and losing counties. Each issue of the corporate real estate journal Site Selection includes large plant decided where to locate." an article These titled the 'winner'), and usually report the runner-up county or counties (i.e., study indicated, the winner and losers are usually chosen from an that in many impression is cases number more than a hundred."' that they provide a representative articles usually indicate the plant's output, The that the plant sample of all new chose a the (i.e., BMW case sample of ""semi-finalisf" sites the "losers")."" initial As the on large articles tend to focus which we use how "Million Dollar Plants" that describes always report the county articles large plant openings and our plants, in US. the to assign the plant to the relevant The -digit 1 industry. In this case, the optimal bid is B* = (Vo + S^m-i )/ (l-y). The change in land prices is AP= - (y / (1-y)) Vo+ S^iK - (i/(i-y))S„,ax-,. '^ In the unlikely case that Vh + Zl = Vl + Zh, the two counties are equivalent, and the winner is randomly determined. In 1985, the journal Indiistiial some years Development changed its name to Site Selection. was Henceforth, Also, "° instances the "Million Dollar Plants" articles do not identify the runner-up county. In some in the feature ""Million Dollar Plants" titled did a Lexis/Nexis search for other articles discussing the plant opening and losing counties. in Site "' The Lexis/Nexis searches were The names of the in semi-finalists are rarely reported. 14 refer to it as Site For these cases, we 4 cases were able to identify the also used to identify the plant's industry Selection. we "Location Reports." Selection. when this was unavailable These data have two important winning counties counties. This is is in many limitations. cases unobserved and the bid magnitude of the subsidy offered by the is almost always unobserved for losing unfortunate, because an interesting check of the validity of our research design whether the subsidies offered are equal to test First, the in the winning and losing counties. Second, in would be many cases the articles do not report the expected size of the plant. order to conduct the analysis, In we collected the most detailed and comprehensive county-level data available on employment, government finances, and property values available for the period from The employment data comes from 1970 through 1999. (CBP) data by industry level. many CBP The trends in Consequently, we conduct total wage bill at the county our analysis at the 1-digit industry by county data are used to test whether a plant opening industry, as well as other industries. its Census Bureau's County Business Patterns In order to protect the confidentiality of the respondents, these data are "zeroed out" for industry by county cells. level." the These annual data report the number of employees and the file. employment since the latter cannot detect changes We is associated with changes in focus on the total in the skill wage wage bill rather than total bill content of labor. Unfortunately, the CBP does not report hourly wages. We also test whether the successful attraction of a plant affects property values. ^^ unaware of any existing electronic county by year data governments values."'' in file files of annual county-level property value data, so on property values from two sources. we our winner and loser samples directly and requested These data contacted all we supplemented all We created our are own the state and county their historical data because governments determine the value of property exist the purpose of assessing property taxes. Second, First, we on property in their jurisdictions for , these data by hand entering data from the 1972, 1977, 1982, 1987. and 1992 Census of Governments. Volume 2 Taxable Property Values and Assessment-Sales Price Ratios. The censuses reports market values in the year before each census was unavailable from both sources, we was conducted. In years where data estimated county-level property values by linearly interpolating the Census of Government data, which likely causes the true variation to be understated. For the purposes of the analysis, we divide output into the 5 broad "1-digit" industries defined by the CBP for which uncensored wage bill data are available in most years. These industries are: Manufacturing; Transportation and Public Utilities; Trade (Wholesale plus Retail); Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate; Services. At this level of aggregation, ^^ Ideally, 1 7% of the cells we would have are "zeroed" out. also examined the effect on property rental rates, but we were unable to find a source for annual or other high frequency rental data. ^'' We attempted to get this data for the at least 1 primary sample of 166 counties dating back to the early 1970s. earlier years. We collected governments did not have data from the For example, we have nonmissing property value date for 68 counties in 1977, 102 in 1980, 149 in year of property value data from 153 counties. In general, these 1990, and 153 in 1998. 15 One limitation of these data is that our and structures across residential and industrial that it will include the value but we is the is sum of the values of land The drawback of this measure of property values land. discussed more extensively in the is unavailable for many of the counties mean value of new plants' buildings. Despite our extensive data collection efforts, the property value data are missing Our preferred property value sample The Data Appendix provides more losers. is details fiscal consequences for and capital outlays). The and securities holdings. held fixed. of all In The is ASG used to determine the is an annual survey of (e.g., education, intergovernmental transactions, current operations, aggregate these data to the county that are (ASG) level. by source, indebtedness, and cash This aggregation is done on the surveyed continuously from 1970 through 1999 so that the units are our "Million Dollar Plant" sample of 166 winning and losing counties, 150 counties have one governmental unit that reports continuously. governmental units expenditures. (i.e., data also contains information on revenues We sample of governmental units at least Statistics Series on governments' expenditures by function administration, and public assistance) and type some comprised of 30 of the 82 winners and 62 of the 129 governments of new plant openings. local that asks detailed questions for on the property value data. The Amntal Survey of Governments: Finance governments in subsequent description of the property value note here that the estimated increase in propeity values appears to be substantially larger than any reasonable estimate of the counties. is of the new plants' structures, which mechanically causes measured property Unfortunately, a series for land values only values to increase. our sample. This issue results, measure of property values This is in these counties The continuous but account for reporters comprise only approximately 75% 12.5% of revenues and because large government units are sampled with certainty, while smaller units are sampled with "varying probabilities within an area, type of government, and size ordering" (Census Bureau, 1990, B. Summary p. 1-1)." Statistics Table 1 presents of the analysis. The and an average of first summary statistics on the sample of plant location decisions panel indicates that 1.6 losers per winner or in a total that form the basis our primary sample there are 82 separate plant openings of 129 losers. There are 166 counties in this sample, so According to the data documentation, the following governments are sampled with certainty: "all county governments with a population of 50,000 or more, municipal governments with a population of 25,000 or more; township government in the New England and Middle Atlantic states with a population of 25,000 or more; school with an enrollment of 5,000 or more; and special revenue or expenditure of $5 million." districts total districts 16 with long-term debt outstanding of $10 million, or the average county appears roughly 1.3 times. '"^ of losers per winner. We The losers. analysis is were most informative about the consequences of in announcement about 1991 and 1992, suggesting that they of each plant, identity 57 of the 82 cases there table also reveals that 63 of the 82 plants the distribution of the year of the announced In its reports the distribution of the niuriber winner and accompanying loser(s) associated with each plant refer to the opening announcement as a "case." The second panel may is in the and a single loser in attracting industrial plants. The final valuations of counties be countercyclical. Appendi.x Table 2 reports the Column small. (i.e., in Z,j), the three years before the (3) presents the t-statistic and p-value from the winning and losing counties are similar so In contrast, we or the announcement of the plant opening. These columns (1), (2), and test that the entries in (1) that any differences in and columns expect that a comparison of the winners (or losers) with (4), respectively.^' (2) are equal. U.S. counties all We (!) and (2) will be is likely produce larger differences. to The first two panels reveal that the winning and losing counties are similar pre-announcement trends of the primary outcome of three outcome variables total wage bill in the new in same conclusion. The third row of two sets The second panel compares rates in earnings, "* the data. 127 counties appear once the entire empirical analysis, in we exclude the losers for a given case. is winning counties, compared of counties. The count of full-time employees leads to at all the US counties are much smaller."^ conventional significance levels. employment and land values are not Second, statistically different in 33 counties appear twice and 6 counties are present three times. Through the 7 counties with populations exceeding 2 million. would be difficult to detect the impact of a plant opening. "^ The losing county entries in column 2 are calculated in The in not statistically meaningful and indicates that trends in the outcome variables in the three years before the announcement. The growth cases so that each case means panel indicates that the hypothesis of equivalent aggregate property values across winning and losing counties cannot be rejected all is In contrast, the corresponding figures for this both the levels and announcement of the plant opening. The mean approximately $1,127 million This difference there were similar levels of activity in the the is in variables. Specifically, the first panel reports the the three years before the plant's industry to $1,145 million in losing counties. "^ (i.e., V,j) Table 2 presents the means across counties of some likely are reported for winners, losers, and the entire U.S. in e.xpect that lists industry, and the winning and losing counties. detenninants of these variables means Thus, our panel 22 of the plant openings were the plant opening. Although we do not know the determinants of the counties' valuations of plants plants' 14 there are 2 manufacturing industry. we the following manner. First, we In these counties, it mean across mean across all calculate the calculate the overall loser average as the unweighted given equal weight. figures in the top panel of column 4 are a weighted average for years 1982 to 1993, with weights proportional number of Million Dollar cases in each year and industry. The figures in panels 2 to 5 of column 4 are a weighted average for years 1982 to 1993, with weights proportional to the number of Million Dollar cases in each year (see bottom of Table for the distribution of cases across years). to the I We winning and losing counties. trends in wage bill, return to this issue in Section V, wiiere employment and land values we winning and losing counties. For now, property values is if graphically show that the note that the finding that both the level and growth rate of similar in winning and losing counties our research design, we before the announcement are similar in in the 8 years is an especially important Under property markets are forward looking. test of the validity of the plausible assumption that property markets are forward looking, this finding indicates that the expected future changes in the level of economic activity capitalized into property values are also ex-ante comparable. Overall, the first two findings provide reassuring evidence on the quality of this research design The third panel reports mean conventional criteria. This is and changes of socioeconomic and demographic variables. In levels general, the null hypothesis of equal means in opening announcement and the percent growth important exceptions where the p-value two graduates. However, for these mean across all U.S. counties in statistically different in all winning and losing counties cannot be rejected with true both for the levels of the variables in the 3 years preceding the plant is in those years for selected variables. There are two .05 or less: level of per capita column (4). income and fraction of college mean than is the Furthermore, for per capita income, the percent growth is not variables, the losers" mean closer to the winners' is winners and losers counties. Interestingly, there are important differences between U.S. counties and the winning counties. larger population, a higher In particular, the employment-population winners are richer, have a substantially ratio, a better educated population, and fewer people over the age of 65. The fourth and fifth panels show the geographic distribution of plants across the four regions of the U.S. and the industry distribution of the labor force within the categories. winning and losing counties are not well balanced. compared to 39% of the losers. unobserved differences (e.g., This is For example, 66% Here, the means across the of the winners are potentially problematic, since it in the suggests that there South may be union density) across the winning and losing counties. This finding underscores the value of our identification strategy's reliance on comparisons of changes in outcomes between winners and losers, rather than cross sectional comparisons. In this setting cross-sectional differences will only bias the results if levels of these variables determine future changes. This would be the case if for example, union density predicts growth As the next section discusses, we that is limited to cases employment and property values. estimate models that include region by year fixed effects to account for the uneven distribution of winner and losers across regions. sample in where the winner and We also estimate models on a restricted loser counties are both from the South. To preview the results, our findings are unaffected by these specification checks, implying that the geographic imbalance does not explain our results. IV. Econometric In light of the firm's selection Model rule, the goal is to estimate the causal effect of winning a plant on county-level outcomes. This section discusses the 2-step econometric model used to estimate this effect. In the first step, we the following equation: fit 17 17 = aic+ Yj Y„c, (6) + Yj '^wtW.ic, 17 Y,„ = (6') where but i is it ^li Lijci + Hi, + iiut+£,.ic., 17 ac+ Y. X ":vvtWjcx+ references industry, j J^lt Ljcx + Ht + %+ ^.ic„ indicates a case, c denotes county, and normalized so that for each case the year the plant opening variable in equation a,c |i„ ([!,) is a is (ttc) in full set outcome variables. The use of -8 and denotes year, The outcome 0."' county-level measure that adjust for same in the is permanent for all fixed county characteristics. we others in the smaller sample that the industry x year (year) effects are the Hut in (6'), Y,^,, is a x also = are the respective stochastic error terms. These account sample includes the entire U.S., while Plant" sample of 166 counties. >= ^j^, is t of indicators that nonparametrically controls for industry x year (year) specifications the (t1it) is and announced of industry x county (county) fixed effects the intercept of the a vector ^ijci indexes year, t is wages. The outcome variable (6), Y.jct, is total of property' values or a government finance variable, differences or t=-i9 T=-:9 restrict it effects. In some our "Million Dollar to equivalent to imposing the restriction 166 counties and the remainder of the country. a set of separate fixed effects for each of the cases interacted with an indicator for whether i t <= We 5. restrict attention to these values of i, because the sample is balanced over this range. W,,eT industr>' in and are indicator variables. Wjjct (Wj^O equals Wj^^^^ winning counties (the new plant's county) analogously for losing counties. 1 on the new plant's for observations for a given value of i. L,|ct and Lj^t are defined In the cases with multiple losers, this indicator variable will equal 1 for observations from multiple counties within a case. The specific vectors means of (or until) the plant I. and Kl are the parameters of interest in these equations. They measure the dependent variables in winning and losing counties, respectively, are conditional on with ttv, all the indicator variables described above. opening announcement. For example, tiwt when i = 3 is The period is where the means determined by the years since Thus, the effect of winner or loser status the conditional the period- mean of the outcome in is allowed to vary winning counties 3 years announcement and TiLiWhen after the = i -3 mean the conditional is in the losing counties 3 years before the announcement. A few of the details about the identification the case fixed effects (i.e., r|,„ >= winner-loser pair for x differencing in a -8 and <= t First, and most importantly, guarantee that the n's are identified from comparisons within a r\^^) and bear highlighting. ti's 5 and are a way Second, regression framework. to retain the intuitive appeal of pairwise possible to separately identify the is it Ji's and the industry x vear (vear) effects because the plant opening announcements occun'ed in multiple years. Third, are winner and/or losers multiple times and any observation from these counties will some counties simultaneously Fourth, the specification does not control multiple n's. identify covariates, such as the variables listed in Table 2. This per capita income and population) is because many, if time-varying for not all of these variables (e.g., be affected by the plant opening so are likely endogenous. may Table 2 suggested that there might be important unmeasured region-specific determinants of the outcome variables in (e.g., and county level (6) (6'), in nonparametrically adjust for we Since the analysis differences in union density). all it is industry x county level at the possible to include region x year fixed effects is unobservables that vary across regions over time. As a test in order to of robustness, present results from specifications that include these fixed effects. The implement 2"'' step provides a to summarize the To to infer the effect of attracting a plant. jt"s stack the vectors Jiw and n^ for -8<= we this step, method i <=5 into a 28 x 1 vector. This vector is the dependent variable in the following equation: (7) jisT = +5 1 (Winner) + + y (trend * + p (trend where * y trend +X (trend * l(Winner)) I(t>=0)) 1 (Winner) * 1 (x >= 0)) indexes winner status and x remains the year relative to the plant opening announcement. s equation allows for a differential intercept for the trend, + Vs„ \|/. The parameter k measures whether the trend differs after the winner parameters. It also includes a common This time the time trend differs for winners, while y captures whether announcement of the plant opening (i.e., when x >= " 0). when the plant begins production is unknown, so we use the year of the announcement of the winner = 0. In most cases, the construction of the new plant starts immediately after the announcement. '° We include the winner fixed effect in (7), because (6) and (6') include all periods (i.e., fi-om -19<= t <=17), while the second step only uses observations where -8<= x <=5. For this reason, the winner fixed effect in (7) is not '' The date county as T collinear with the county by industry (county) fixed effects (6) and (6"). include the interaction of winner status and a the trend break. " Since The equal to one if x >= We also experimented with to allow for a mean models that shift in addition to findings from this approach are qualitatively similar. the estimated identical. dummy ir's for winners (losers) are obtained Consequently, the fact that the Tt's are from a balanced panel, estimated 20 is their standard errors are virtually unlikely to be a source of heteroskedasticity in the P the parameter of interest. is It measures the difference announcement of the (relative to losers) after the plant's opening in the time trend specific to winners 0)), Uwt] = It is is its expected production costs outcome variables variables predict the assumption * l(Winner) * 1(t >= valid. instructive to consider this assumption in the context of Section Il-B. that Bj, (i.e., Z,j) in (6) are greatest. and It is we In that section, where the sum of the subsidy that plants will plants will choose to locate in the county negative of announcement). (relative to before the Formally, the consistency of this paraineter requires the assumption that cov[(trend likely that these (i.e., B;,) state and the same unobserved Thus, consistent estimation requires the (6'). and Zy are individually equal between the winner and loser counties, after adjustment for the covariates in (6) or (6") and (7). Notice, this is stronger than assuming that the sum of B,| and Zn is equal after adjustment. The differential growth rates in the South and Rust Belt this period in and the fact that the winners are disproportionately from the South and the losers from the Rust Belt provide a basis for concern that the identifying assumption may not hold. Specifically, ^Winner ^ gLoser ^ j}-"'", but thc wiuucrs havc an advantage winning a plant more and therefore make losers value source of bias if Z and/or B it is possible that on average B^^'""" production costs in larger bids (B^°^" growth and are a proxy for a county's future > (i.e., z^^''""" > g*'"""^') and the jhis would be a and (6) or (6') Z"-"'"') + (7) fail to fully adjust for these differences. Consequently, estimation. by year fixed and T >= is it especially important to clarify Specifically, the identifying assumption effects, case fixed effects, region is how we have that the industry guarded against inconsistent by county fixed by year fixed effects and the detrending by winner status As a also report the results from the fitting of (6) or (6') and (7) on a subsample that is together condition out any differences in By and Zy between winners and losers. robustness check, we restricted to cases where the winner and loser are both from the South. ^" This sample the possibility that the results are due to differential growth rates across regions South). Notably, the paper's findings are similar It is This is noteworthy that if in the full the identifying assumption sum think of cases where the < if is where positive and cases counties with bad future outcomes ones that have the most estimation of equation (7). to gain by attracting a removes the Rust Belt and and restricted samples. is it (i.e., new restriction (e.g., invalid, the bias cannot be signed a priori. because the sign of the bias depends on whether cov(By,t>WT) + cov(Zy,UwT) cov(Bij,uwt) effects, industry is < negative. For example, declining plant. is wage > or it is 0. One can possible that bills or land prices) are the At the same time, it is plausible that Regardless, the subsequent results are insensitive to weighting by the square root of the inverse of the standard errors of the n"s from equation (6). cov(Zij,UwT) outcomes > since counties with ciiaracteristics that firms find desirable 0, (i.e., increasing wage bills or may also have good future land prices). V. Results This section is divided into three subsections. The workers' earnings within the winning county and for the new plant's 1 industry and for -digit its reports the estimates of winner status on surrounding counties. The II). Separate results aie reported The second subsection other industries. all reports the Under some assumptions, property values may association between winner status and property values. provide a measure of overall welfare (Section first third subsection examines the association between winner status and a series of local government revenue and expenditures categories. Employment Outcomes A. Columns and (2) of Table (1) the fitting of equation (6) is normalized so that estimated Ttw and total => I wage >= effects. bill in -8. til i ^ on wage total is for a given value of i. (3) reports the difference on the same scale, the winner's This same nonnalization difference in the estimated tiw and is it evident that line used is and ttl's their standard errors is announced. Each row reports the Consequently, the point estimates are annual measures of the in the 1 -digit industry of the new plant for 5 industry, industry by time, and case fixed between the estimates of ttw and til in the have almost identical trends from i = is in all til shifted up so that the difference within each row. is -digit industry -8 through t = between In order to get the i. the lines 1 a graphical version of column (3) of Table of the new -I A . plant, the statistical test when is The bottom panel of Figure the subsequent figures. against i and 1 from counties from 1970-1998. Recall, i separately plots the estimates of tiw and Kl against 1 lines bill in CBP for all millions of dollars by winner/loser status = wage data from the These estimates are conditioned on county by Column these graphs, bill estimated ttw's and the year that the plant location decision The top panel of Figure -1. 3 report the i plots the 3. From winning and losing counties confirms that the trends in the the winning and losing counties are statistically indistinguishable in the 8 years before the plant opening annoimcement Importantly, this (e.g., the t-statistic associated with the test of equal trends is 0.37.) consistent with our identifying assumption that losing counties provide a valid is counterfactual. However beginning with the trend in the ' wage Specifically, a case losers, the sample is is bill in the 1 the year that the plant opening -digit industry of the new plant required to have a winner and at least 1 restricted to the losers located in the South. 22 is in announced, there is a sharp increase in the winning counties. loser located in the South. In contrast, the For cases with multiple losing counties' trend is largely unchanged. announcement with the effect of the plant opening mean in differences is it appropriate to model more a trend-break, rather than the typical difference shift. 7'able 4 reports estimates of column figure also demonstrates that 'I'iie (1) (a), the JXw's and wage digit industry, the used ttl's 1.'' and the top panel of Figure and (i its standard error that result from fitting equation (7). were presented to obtain these estimates are those that The column parameter estimate suggests that (1) (a) increased by a statistically significant $16.8 million per year bill Table 3 in new in the In plant's I- winning in counties (relative to losing ones) after the announcement of the plant's opening (relative to the period before the announcement)."' This Taken literally, this digit industry is is 1 .5% of the average wage implies that by the end of the period bill in (i.e., x = winning counties 5) the wage bill in in the year new the = x -1.^' plant's 1- roughly $100 million (9%) higher due to the plant opening than predicted by pre-existing trends. It is openings. possible that this finding Belt counties that are on a bid a lot to downward However, it is losers (recall Figure Nevertheless, this is may largely be all among winners and in the wage an important issue and restriction reduces the to cases In all the When and standard error (in subsequent figures, specification In the to 54. parentheses) column (a) is standard errors, the results are virtually identical. '' column This after adjustment). documented in Table 2. opening announcement specification checks to explore to equation (6), so the (b). nw's and Notably, the point estimate In the effects. The are 31.7 (1) (a) result is second check, is is we it. ttl's essentially restrict the This loser are located in the South. results are not and (7.0), shown in the table, respectively. but the These two not due to unobserved regional shocks. used to obtain the ttw's and ttl's. the 1" step standard errors are clustered by county and year, and the (1) (a) specification losers prior to the plant where both the winner and number of cases from 82 specification checks demonstrate that the "'"' than the plant time varying region-specific factors. The results from the estirnation of the version of sample of winners and losers " bill we implement two unchanged by the inclusion of the region by year fixed estimate rates, rather comparisons of losing Rust 1). equation (7) that uses these n's are presented in column (1) point to on an upward trend (even that are check involves the addition of region by year fixed effects are adjusted for due trend (even after adjustment for pre-existing trends) and willing to undermined by the similar trends among winners and growth to differences in regional (a) estimate supported by the geographic imbalance is first due winning Southern counties possibility The is For example, the column (1) 2"^* step is weighted by the f step For example, the p coefficient (standard error) from the column 16.6 (5.3). (1) (a) specification when the dependent variable estimate and standard error are 0.0079 (0.0037). 23 is the In of the total wage bill, the parameter Column the restricted when (2) reports the results The estimates are used to estimate P from equation (7). bill the estimated n's are obtained from fitting equation (6) on sample of 166 winning and losing counties (rather than the and in (a) As entire U.S.). before, the (b) suggest that the trend in the Tt's wage increased by $13.2 and $12.6 million, respectively. In the context of the standard errors, these The estimates are essentially identical to those in column (1). cases where both the winner and the loser are from the South is point estimate (standard error) based on shown not in the table, but it is 28.0 (6.0). Figure 2 presents the column (2) (a) results graphically. As mentioned above, we focus on cannot detect changes to the total wage bill employment, rather than the to Table 4, wage Appendix Figure ones. For example. Returning the total bill employment rather than total since the latter content of labor. However, the employment results are generally similar in the skill total column wage presents graphs that are analogous to Figure 2 for 1 bill.^" (3) reports a "naVve" estimator that obtained by using a standard is regression to test for a trend break in the winners after the announcement relative to before, controlling for observable characteristics. it is It is labeled "naive" because the losers are not used as a counterfactual, so not conditioned on case fixed effects. This the estimator that is would typically be used in the absence of the Million Dollar Plant research design. Interestingly, the point estimates here are roughly than those in column (1) and almost double the column 50% larger This highlights the value of our (2) estimates.' research design. Column (1) of Table 5 and Figure 3 associated with changes in columns is (I) (a) employment whether the announcement of the new plant opening is winning county. The point estimates in and (1) (b) suggest that the trend approximately 0.9-1.1% of the i = -1 level. significant by conventional criteria, but the The remainder of Table new test in other industries in the 5 plant affects the trend in the in the bill in bill The column column one (b) and Figures 4 and wage wage 5 is increased by $42.0-32.1 million, which (a) estimate would be judged examines whether the successful is attraction of the Here, a neighbor counties that neighbor the winner. defined as a county that physically abuts a county or statistically imprecise. We connected by a bridge or boat. is compare the neighbors of winners to the neighbors of losers. This part of the analysis offers an opportunity to assess whether the wage bill gains "spillover" to neighboring counties or In Figure 4, there appears to be a trend break in the total plant. The estimates in column The corresponding is million, or approximately coefficient (standard error) from the 467.3 (176.2). The zero sum locally. the bill in in column 24 .2-1 .5%. employment regression on coefficient from a regression that includes Estimates are based on data from the entire U.S. as 1 ( 1 ). all same 1-digit as the They suggest 2 of Table 5 confirm this visual impression. announcement trend increased by $36.5-40.4 Plant counties is wage the new that the post- This estimate borders sample of Million Dollar U.S. counties is 287.8 (192.0). on statistical significance as judged by conventional industries from the (a) specification. the announcement of criteria. F-'igure 5 plots the results for all other l-digit The bottom panel reveals that the relative the plant opening in winning counties is column reflected in the large point estimate ($33.8-161 .7 million) and standard errors in These Put another way, the effect of the plant opening announcement neighbors. fact, winning counties are not the results suggest that the gains in the appears to spillover to The poor neighboring counties." downward trend before This halted, but the data are noisy. result not zero is (3) of Table of losses sum is 5. in their locally and, in precision of the ""other industries" estiinates temper any conclusions about spillovers outside the new plant's industry.' B. Property Values we Mere, assess whether winner status is associated with changes property values. In a model in with rational, perfect-foresight agents, the net effect of winning the plant should be capitalized into property values immediately after the announcement. immediate mean shift in reappraised every few years in gradually in As property values. many our sample. Consequently, states, we In this case, it would be appropriate to test for an the Data Appendi.x describes, property values are only so that changes in property values will emerges only continue to use the trend break model specified in equation (7). The property value 6, the <= T sample <= sample 5. fhis restriction losers, in column California to ( 1 ) of Table in 2% is This is As (relative to the period before the announcement). zero by conventional criteria. also explored whether there are effects in a test of robustness, we included a time-varying state factors. This state. (2) of Table -8 adds the = on the wage is full set of state annual increases in -1. the plant's These estimates would not be judged Nevertheless, this The column bill at little property values increased is the state level. The to be approximately 0.6-0.8% of (2) specifications add California by point estimates are large and empirical content. by year fixed effects in equation (6) in order to control for very demanding of the data due to the small number of observations from each 5. See the Data Appendix (3) announcement of Nevertheless, the estimated trend breaks are generally of a larger magnitude across Tables 4 and and Column restricts in the (relative to losing ones) after the positive but the standard errors are so large that they have all (1 ) the preferred sample. imply that the trend 6, the point estimates winning counties statistically different than imposed, because Proposition 13 annually.'"' the average property value in winning counties at x ^' columns observations from California are dropped, which reduces the sample by 2 restriction that all by $103-140 million We In limited to the "Million Dollar Plant" counties with nonmissing property value data for is property values opening 6. This sample includes 32 of the 82 winners and 69 of the 129 losers. winners and 7 In Table 6 and Figure results are presented in for a further discussion of the difficulties with California data. 25 all the dependent variables year fixed effects to (6') in modestly larger than those Figure 6 two that the is in (1) but overall indicate a similar conclusion. based on the preferred sample that excludes California counties. of counties had remarkably similar trends sets announcement of the plant opening. This and due 2. however to the economic may it result is provide an even more meaningful are similar it wage Figures bill in 1 of our identifying assumption. Specifically, test suggests that the expectations about future winning and losing counties in This figure shows aggregate property values prior to the in similar to the findings for the forwaid-looking nature of property markets, activity advance of the plant opening in Figure 6 also reveals a dramatic upward trend break announcement. These estimates are order to account for the effect of Proposition 13. column property values in in winners that coincides with the announcement of the plant opening. The corresponding point estimates in column (3) of Table 6 indicate that the trend break in winning counties ranges from $176-278 million. Conventional statistically different from zero. They are approximately 1.1-1.7% of the They suggest counties. by the end of the examined period that winning counties had increased by $1.0-1.7 in To mean put this in context, the announcement As a is robustness check, sample It is billion (1983$), or 6.6-1 property values in winning -1 6 years (i.e., six-year change in property values is we also estimated after x property values -1), relative to losing cotmties. 0.2''/'o, in = the years before the opening 41 7.5 (104.4), which natural to entirely reflect the new is to the sample that a is restricted to cases error) from this larger than the estimates in Table 6. measure of property values wonder whether of the new plant's building models based on from the South. The point estimate (standard loser are both Recall, a shortcoming of our structures. = i to be 57.2%.'" where the winner and the restricted would judge these estimates criteria is that it includes the value of land and the property value results are mechanically due to the addition assessment where the property value In the extreine roles. plant's structures, the estimates in this subsection would not reflect results an increase in local residents' wealth. Some back of the to Site Selection, the (1983$). This figure sample. "*" Site Selection " The total investment this is not a first-order it seems on average the plants total total likely that they include the costs in 1 -digit wage bill is 15.0 investment of the plants lists for in our of land, structures, equipment, and 13.6) for this ( According was $390 million investment numbers, but based on sample with specification (a). list. For example, our our sample are smaller than the ones on the Top 10 sample includes 12 plants with 1991 announcement dates but only 2 of them qualified unable to locate top 10 concern. the top 10 plant openings in 1991 vague about what variables enter the is point estimate (standard error) on the We suspect that among almost certainly larger than the mean is our reading of the articles ^' envelope calculations suggest that average other years. ,, 26 . , for the top 10 list. We were perhaps job training tor new employees.'" for a small portion of the total increase million investment is it Overall, the property value results The tliat the new property values, even in correct for our sample and plant reduces property values.''' evident is fail in plants' structures can only account the unrealistic case where the !t)390 only describes the cost of structures. it to provide evidence that the successful attraction of a big implication that the county's share is of the tax incentives is smaller than the local benefits of the plant opening.'^ C. Local Government Finance Outcomes A with cuts issue. widespread concern about the provision of these subsidies in that local from the estimation of In this table, the tt's that are equation (6') used as the dependent variables in (7) on the sample of 150 "Million Dollar Plant" counties one governmental unit reporting consecutively from 1970 through 1999.^* Column mean of the budget variables estimate in column The table ( 1 ) to this winning counties in at i = and column -I this important to bear in approximately 0.8% residents. The Table first mind in that ASG according to the winning counties after the have at of the point (3) lists the ratio reports the effects in absolute terms. in column In viewing these data the trend in population announcement. It is panel reports the expenditure results. The Bureau of Economic in is it by Thus, these counties were gaining straightforward to obtain per-capita effects The 'Total" row suggests = -1 mean. that the trend in total The category can be divided current expenditures, capital outlays, and payments to other governmental units. was roughly equivalent results, increased 3. expenditures increased by $17.2 million or 1.8% of the i increase that (2) reports the mean. by subtracting 0.008 from the entries The are obtained divided into separate panels for expenditures, revenues, and indebtedness and within is these broad categories separate results for subcategories are reported. '" governments fund them For a series of local government tlnance variables, column (1) reports the estimated P and standard error from equation (7). least is important services, such as education and police protection. Table 7 empirically explores In into percentage terms, the the current and capital categories. Analysis' National Economic Accounts reports the total stock of private fixed assets in the manufacturing sector. This figure includes the value of structures, equipment, and software but excludes land. Notably, structures only account for 42% of this total. This is further evidence that the $390 million figure greatly overstates the share of investment devoted to structures. ^ We also tried to estimate (6') with a full set of state by year fixed effects. demanding of the This specification is excessively and 92 counties, but only 7 of these states have multiple counties. The resulting estimates were so imprecise that they lacked meaning. '*' See Chapter 5 of Bartik (1991) for a review of the limited literature on the effect of economic development policies on local property values. Also see Dye and Merriman (2000) for the effects of tax incremental financing schemes that fund economic development projects on property values. data, because the property value data contain observations from 29 1 ** The region by year fixed effects are not included in this version of (6'). 27 states The education expenditures was 4.8% of the in capital money was "selected sub-categories" results reveal where the extra -1 spending per pupil may have increased, although this The trend break accounted for roughly 55% of the this calculation is speculative the trend break in housing and Interestingly, expenditures was larger than the overall trend break publicly operated utilities mean and This finding and the current education expenditure results suggests that increase in capital expenditures. assumptions to be valid. ^^ = i targeted. expenditures. in The and requires a number of community development increase in consistent with the expansion of the manufacturing sector. is spending on Notably, the spending on police protection was unchanged but on a per capita basis results suggest that it declined modestly. The second panel 1/3 of reveals that the trend in revenues increased by $18.5 million. was due this increase important source for the subsidies used to attract tax revenues compared and utility comparison of the revenues. This in required to balance their budgets annually. in of this finding, it The break nonguaranteed debt, which final entry in the table the government. This type of debt status, but obligation to repay the new new It is is results also reveal trend breaks in local larger trend break on utility expenditures plants may receive discounts on utility fees. that the trend break in expenditures is be expected since local governments are generally to notable though that the balance initially surprising that the is million. tax-exempt The was not achieved through valuable public services. In light in The plants. and second panels reveals first roughly equal to the trend break cutbacks new charges of roughly $4 million. to the charges trend break implies that the A Approximately higher transfers from state governments, underscoring that states are an to it it.**^ is It demonstrates that a form of debt that is is this is is trend in long-term debt increased by $16.3 largely explained by the $12.8 million trend not guaranteed by the full faith and credit of generally issued under the authority of a government body to gain used for private purposes and the government generally does not have any seems sensible to conclude that this is one of the types of incentives given to plants. VI. Interpretation The results suggest that the successful attraction of a "Million Dollar" plant associated with an increase in in propert>' values. Under the assumptions detailed property values may be interpreted as an increase For example, the ASG population variable the number of students According to the in ASG is in in Section is II, on average this increase welfare for residents of the winner county. a measure of all residents. It is not possible to separately determine public schools. manual, this type of bond has been used to fund industrial and commercial development, pollution control, private hospital facilities, sports stadiums, and shopping malls (Census 1999, Section 9.3). 28 I'licre tliat are at least three dilTereiil explanations Ibr this result. winning and losing counties aie ex-ante homogeneous is First if the identifying and the mode! valid in Section assumption II is correct, then the results indicate that the effect of state subsidies dominates any malfeasance by politicians. implication to is that the increase in winners' property values due is to the transfer winning counties. It is wage also possible that the columns bill results in may be justified new plant affects property values in the neighbors of winners (recall the (2) and (3) of Table 5) and/or the entire from an efficiency standpoint. state. has no empirical basis, then A we second explanation speculate that winning counties gain that both is In this case, the counties causes property values to increase in explanation is at is unavailable. If this possibility the expense of the rest of the state. winning and losing counties systematically bid benefit of attracting these plants. this In this case, the state subsidies Unfortunately, this possibility cannot be tested directly, because property value data on the neighbors of winners and entire states of The of resources from states winning counties, do not compete away relative to losing ones. all less than the the rents and this The unappealing feature is not a readily apparent friction that would explain such systematic that winning and losing counties are not ex-ante homogeneous, which that there mistakes. A third explanation is would invalidate our identifying assumption. unobserved heterogeneity and Z in Section II). in counties' However, the may combined effect of valuations of plants and plants' valuations of counties (the terms V In this case the findings pre-announcement similarity of the reflect the levels and trends in the wage bill, property values, and observable characteristics of winning and losing counties, as well as the robustness of the results of region-year effects and limiting the sample to cases where both the to the inclusion winner and loser are located in the South, suggests that our research design trends in property values in the 8 years before the announcement is is valid. The similarity in the especially reassuring. Under the plausible assumption that property markets capitalize expected future economic activity, this finding indicates that there losing counties in were not differences in expectations about future economic outcomes in winning and advance of the announcement of the plant opening. Another central issue of interpretation and residents' welfare. validity assumes As Section II is whether there is a connection between property values of the welfare interpretation highlighted, the validity rests on the of the Roback model's assumptions, some of which may not be justified. For example, the model that there is no involuntary unemployment and moving property values would solely reflect the value of land. is costless. Further, the ideal measure of Since the available measure of property values include both the value of structures and land, the property value results overestimate the increase in welfare for landowners. This is because they reflect the value ones, in addition to the change in the price of land. 29 of new structures, or improvements to old Even if the Roback assumptions fail to hold, this paper's results still provide new estimates of the impact of successfully bidding for a large industrial plant on workers' earnings, property values and government finances. policy's efficacy and local There are fails to shed any "Minion Dollar" widely believed that It is at least three of these all outcomes are important measures of a economic well-being. four limitations to the paper's analysis that bear highlighting. First, the analysis on the precise mechanism or channel by which counties benefit fi'om attracting a light plant. For example, we cannot ascertain whether tlie increase in employment increases in demand, agglomeration economies, or other type of externalities. In future work, this same research design to directly test the agglomeration theory by exploring "Million Dollar Plant" lowers the production costs of other plants in the is we due to will use whether the opening of a same industry in winning counties. A second limitation is that the external validity plants in our sample likely differ from the average of the results industrial plant in suspect that these results do not generalize to the opening of any plant. which the "Million Dollar' plants differ the exact selection rule that determines is from the average plant which plants is in is unknown. many In particular, the 82 important dimensions so we The most important dimension their size. in Although we do not know are featured in the "Million Dollar Plant" articles, it quite clear that large plants are the focus. We suspect that the 82 plants in our sample are a reasonably representative sample of US. large plant openings in the that are of interest to the public and policymakers, and that our sample of large plants However, the A results is new to study in this paper. In this respect, the correct one for exploring the positive effects of winning a plant. third important limitation is we seek cannot inform the nonnative question of which is that in general we offered either by the winners or losers. This implies that subsidies all precisely these large plants that generate the type of bidding wars It is t\'pes of plants should be subsidized. don't observe the magnitude of the subsidies we cannot measure how much an extra dollar of worth. Moreover, the paper's results do not provide guidance on whether a local government should increase or decrease its bid for a particular plant. Fourth, the focus of this paper is on local communities. As we mentioned from the outset, the question of whether states or the nation as a whole benefit from tax competitions between governments to attract new business is local beyond the scope of this paper. VI. Conclusions This paper makes two contributions. Substantively, it provides credible estimates of the effect of successfully bidding for an industrial plant, relative to bidding and losing, on local economies. that the announcement of a "Million Dollar" plant opening 30 is We find associated with a 1.5% increase in the trend ill earnings announcement wages new plant's These less precise. due crowd out industry winning counties in We (relative to the period before). other industries in the in activity the in same county and results provide some of the to the successful attraction of a to ones) losing the after also tlnd evidence of positive trend breaks in total in first large, (relative neighboring counties, although these estimates are ex-post estimates of the increase new plant and indicate that the in local new economic activity doesn't existing activity locally. Under some assumptions, property values may provide a summary measure of change in welfare, because the costs and benefits of attracting a plant should be capitalized into the price of land. If the winners and losers are most homogeneous, a simple model suggests reliable data suggest that there is the net any rents should be bid away. The that a positive, relative trend break of l.i-l.7% in property values. Since winners and losers appear to have similar observable characteristics and similar expected future may be property values in advance of the opening announcement, the property value explained by heterogeneity in subsidies from higher levels of government (e.g., states) and/or systematic changes in underbidding. results Overall, the results undermine the popular view that the provision of local subsidies to attract large industrial plants reduces local residents' welfare. The analysis further reveals that local government finances winning counties are not adversely in Local governments affected by the successful bidding for a plant. in positive and roughly equal trend breaks in revenues and expenditures. increase in winning counties experienced Notably, there is a substantial education spending. The second contribution of the paper is methodological. The paper demonstrates that it is possible to use the revealed rankings of profit-maximizing agents to identify' a credible counterfactual. In our particular case, we show that losing counties but narrowly lost the competition absence of the plant opening (e.g., auctions) to make in —may form a —counties that have survived a long selection process, valid counterfactual for what would have happened winning counties. The same methodology may be useful causal inferences. , 31 . in in the other contexts References Timothy Bartik, Upjohn Black, J. Institute for 1991. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Employment Research: Kalamazoo, Michigan. Dan A. and William H. Hoyt. 1989. "Bidding for Finns." The American Policies? Economic Review . W.E. 79(5): 1249-1256. Brennan, Geoffrey, and James Buchanan. Constitution . Cambridge University Press: 1980. New The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal York. Dye, Richard F. and David F. Merriman. 2000. "The Effects of Tax Incremental Financing on Economic Development." Journal of Urban Economics 47: 306-328. Evans, William N. and Julie H. Topoleski. 2002. "The Social and Economics Impact of Native American Casinos." Working Paper No. 9198. Cambridge, MA: NBER. Garcia-Mila, Teresa and Therese J. McGuire. 2001. "Tax Incentives and the City." Brookings-Wharton J. Rothenberg Pack, Washington, DC: Brookings Papers on Urban Affairs, edited by W. G. Gale and Institution Press, 2002, pp. 95-1 14. Glaeser, Edward L. 1932. Cambridge, 2001. MA: "The Economics of Location-Based Tax Institute of Economic Research. Incentives." Discussion Paper No. Harvard Glaeser, Edward, Jose Scheinkman, and Andre of Cities. "Tbwnjfl/ oj Monetary Economics 36: Schleifer. 1 1995. "Economic Growth Glaeser, Edward, Hedi Kallal, Jose Scheinkman and Andre Schleifer. 1992. "Growth of Political Economy 100: 1126-1152. Goolsbee, Austan and David B. Gross. 2000. in a Cross-Section 17-43. "Estimating the in Cities." Journal Form of Adjustment Costs with Data on Heterogeneous Capital Goods." Mimeograph, University of Chicago. Gordon, Roger H., and John D. Wilson. 1998. "Tax Structure and Government Behavior: Agent Model of Government." Mimeograph. Michigan State University. A Principal- Gyourko, Joseph and Joseph Tracy. 1991. "The Structure of Local Public Finance and the Quality of Life." Journal of Political Economy 99(4): 774-806. Hanson, Gordon H. 1998. "Market Potential, Increasing Returns, and Geographic Concentration." Working Paper No. 6429. Cambridge, MA: NBER. Henderson, Vernon. 1982. Journal of Urban Economics "Evaluating Consumer Amenities and Interregional Welfare Differences." 1 1: 32-59. Henderson, Vernon. 2003. "Marshall's Scale Economies." Journal of Urban Economics 53: 1-28. Henderson. Vernon, Ari Kuncoro. and Matt Turner. of Political Economy 103(5): 1067-1090. 32 1995. "Industrial Development in Cities."" Journal Hochn, .loliii P., Mark C. Berger, and (llcnn C. Blomquisl. 1987. "A llccloiiic Model of Wages, Rents and Amenity Values." Joiinial of Regional Science 27; 605-20. Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Enrico Moretti. Social Waste Mitol, 2001. A. Jenniter "Can Free Entry be 2003. Real Estate Industry." Joiirncil of Political in the "Boeing is Wind Under (forthcoming). Wings." Chicago's http://more.abcnevvs.go.com/sections/business/dailynews/boeingO 05 1 Commissions and Fnefficient? Fixed Economy II Interregional Available at: .html. "Estimating the Social Return to Migher Education: Evidence from Longiludiiiai and Repeated Cross-Sectional Data." Journal of Econometrics. Moretti, Enrico. 2004a. 2004b. "Workers' Education, Spillovers and Productivity: Evidence from Plant-Level Moretti, Enrico. Production Functions", American Economic Review. Oates, Wallace E. 1972. Fiscal Federalism . Harcourt Brace Jovanovich: Ramey, Valerie A. and Matthew D. Shapiro. 2001. "Displaced Closings." Journal of Political Economy 109:958-992. New Capital: A York. Study of Aerospace Plant Rauch, James E. 1993. "Productivity Gains from Geographic Concentration of Fluman Capital: Evidence from Cities." Journal of I hhan Economics 34(3): 380-400. Roback, Jennifer 1982. "Wages, Rents and the Quality of Life", Journal of 1257-1278. Political Economy 1974. "Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation Rosen, Sherwin. Competition." Journal of Political Economy 82: 34-55. Rosenbaum, Paul and Donald Rubin. 1983. "The Central Role of the Propensity Score Studies for Causal Effects." Biometnka 70: 41-55. S;7e5'e/ec?/o/;, in ", in 90(6), Pure Observational Various Issues, 1982-93. Standard and Poor's. October 25, 1993. Credit Week Municipal: The Authority on Credit Quality. Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. ""A Pure Theory of Local E.\penditures."' Journal of Political Economy 64(5): 416-24. Trogen, Paul. 2002. "Which Economic Development Policies Work: Determinants of State per Capita Income." Mimeograph. East Tennessee State University. Census Bureau. 1999. "Government Mimeograph, Department of Commerce. U.S. U.S. Census Bureau. and Employment Classification Manual." 2003. "User Guide to Historical Data Base on Individual Government Finances." Electronic File, Department of Venable, Tim. 1992. August: 630-1. Finance "BMW Commerce. Drives into South Carolina with $300 Million Auto Plant." Site Selection 33 Wilson John D. 1996. "The Tax Treatment of Imperfectly Mobile Firms: Rent-Seeking, Rent-Protection, and Rent-Destruction." in The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati edited by Robert C. Feenstra, Gene M. Grossman, and Douglas A. Irwin. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA. , Wilson, John D. 1999. "Theories of Tax Competition." National Tax Journal 52: 269-304. 1986. "Pigou, Tiebout, Property Taxation, and the Zodrow, George R. and Peter Mieszkovvski. Underprovision of Local Public Goods." Journal of Urban Economics 19: 356-70. 34 DATA APPENDIX: Property Viiluc Data There are a number of issues about the property value data that may affect the interpretation of the paper's results. First, the linear interpolation procedure causes the true variability in the data to be understated and biases the standard errors in the regressions downwards. Further, it may obscure the timing of changes in property values associated with plant openings. Second, the data measure the aggregate market value of and industrial land.'*' an assessment rate In is many land and structures across residential all value differs from the market value but, states, the assessed available that allows for the conversion to market values. It in these cases, was not possible to A obtain separate measures of the value of the land, excluding the structures, for our entire sample. drawback of this measure of property values is that it will include the value of the new plant's structure, which mechanically causes measured property values to increase. This issue is discussed more extensively in the subsequent description of the property value results, but we note here that the estimated mean increase in property values appears to be substantially larger than any reasonable estimate of the value of new plants' buildings. Third, there are important differences across states important difference it is that the frequency is in the statutes that govern assessments. of appraisals varies dramatically across important to note that because the property assessment cycles are mandated by the One For our purposes states. state, it unlikely is of assessment is systematically correlated with plant openings. Appendix Table reports the distribution of state mandated property assessment cycles for the 31 states represented in the preferred property value sample. 14, or almost half of the states, require that all properties are reassessed or that the timing 1 revalued every year, but 12 states reassess less frequently than once every 3 years. Connecticut allows 10 years between revaluations. In many of the states that allow for between reappraisals, 1/x of the properties are reassessed each year, where x is the Interestingly, more than a year number of years between mandated revaluations. The relevance our analysis for property values each year. This is is that these data are not designed to give accurate measures of relevant because a model with rational, perfect-foresight agents would winning the plant should be capitalized into property values immediately Thus, it would be appropriate to estimate this effect with a 1-time change in light of the infrequent reappraisals in many states, a trend break model is more predict that the net effect of after the mean announcement. property values. In appropriate and this model A related issue is the property value data. is discussed further in the It is difficult years after change it is Due jumps in a spurious correlation between plant Further, the longer the period between reappraisals, the changes in property values associated with a plant opening in the first few Consequently, we drop all observations from counties with at least one annual to detect opening. its in property jumps could induce possible that these opening announcements and property values. more econometrics section. that since the reappraisal dates are unobserved, there are likely to be values greater than to the passage 70% or less than of Proposition 13 in -70%. 1978, the California data present a set of unique issues. Proposition 13 limits the increase in the assessed value of a home to 2% per year, unless there is a transfer of ownership or substantial improvements are made. As a consequence, it is difficult to detect positive changes in property values in California. To the best of OLir knowledge, no other states place a cap on the increase in assessed property values.^" In our preferred sample, we drop all California counties from the sample. We also demonstrate that the results are robust to including these counties in the sample, with or without California by year fixed effects. States have different names for the market value of land and market value", ^^ Appendix "full D The most frequently used ones of the 1992 Census of Governments, Volume 2 Taxable Property Values, Number Valuations for Local General Property Taxation property. structures. are "fair cash value", or "true cash value". According to this lists Appendix, California is 1 Assessed the state-specific requirements for periodic valuation the only state that places a values. 35 cap on the increase in of real property For a different set of reasons, another state for which property value data fully reflect market value is Indiana. We we are not completely certain that the re-estimated all Due to these data challenges, we its meaningfulness. The propeity. For our purposes, one limitation is OFHEO price index that the index is match with our pioperty value data is not match, the correlation in the annual percentage change is 0.54. counties, so that the Finally we note that when we which the property value data are that are qualitatively similar, For example, the model The OFHEO in price index is column 3a is Table MSAs (OFHEO) in based on repeated sales of the same available for metropolitan areas, but not for perfect. For those observations tiiat we can estimate our property value models dropping the set of counties for entirely although in correlated our measure of property values for counties in with an annual MSA-level produced by the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight order to ascertain models the property value excluding observations from Indiana counties and obtained estimates that are similar to the ones from the Annual Survey of Governments, less precise than the estimates reported in yields an estimate of 283.0 (98.0). available from vvww.ofheo.gov. 36 we Table 6. obtain estimates Table 1: "The Million Dollar Plant" Sample (1) Number of Observations Winners 82 Losers 129 Distribution of the Number of Loser Counties per Winner 1 57 2 14 3 7 2 4 7 1 . 8 1 Distribution of Cases Across Industries 63 Manufacturing Transportation and Public Utilities 8 Trade 4 Finance. Insurance and Real Estate 1 6 Services Distribution of Year of Announcement of Plant Location 1982 1983 5 3 , 1984 3 1985 6 1986 6 1987 8 1988 9 1989 7 1990 6 1991 12 1992 10 1993 7 Notes: The '"Million Dollar Plant" sample is derived from various issues of Site Selection. See the for more details. text Table 2: County Characteristics by Winner Status Winning Losing (l)-(2) Counties Counties t-stat (!) (2) Ail US Counties [p-value] ( 1 ) Total Wage Bill in New Employment in New Plant's IndustTy Aggregate Property Values (Smillions) Trends in 1127 1145 0.17 175 (1455) [0.87] (760) 40635 41568 0.13 6846 (54143) 17084 (49986) 19099 [0.88J (26990) (8773) (10630) [0.30] in total Wage Bill in New - Percent Growth in Employment in New .023 .016 1.04 .018 (.089) (.084) [.30] (.282) Plant's Industry- .022 .011 1.57 .006 (.092) (.089) [.12] (.283) - Plant's Industry Percent Growth in Property Values .050 .055 -0.25 (.128) (.092) [0.80] Socio-Economic and Democraphic Characteristics Per Capita Income Percent Growth in Per capita Income Per Capita Total earnings Percent Growth in Per Capita Total Earnings Employment-Population Ratio Percent Growth in Employment-Population Ratio Per Capita Transfers Population Fraction of Population with High- School Degree Fraction of Population with College Degree Fraction of Fraction of (4) -1.00 Outcome Variables Percent Growtli (3) (4) (1480) Plant's Industry (Smillions) (2) (3) Levels of Outcome Variables Pop 1 7 or Younger Pop 65 or Older 13660 15223 -2.70 11416 (3211) (4250) [0.008] (2636) 0.014 0.011 -1.02 0.011 (0.010) (0.019) [0.31] (0.057) 8993 I0I02 -1.78 7236 (4359) 0.013 (3730) [0.08] (2253) 0.015 -0.89 0.011 (0.028) (0.025) [0.37] (0.124) 0.541 0.573 -1.40 0.468 (0.170) (0.132) [0.17] (0.126) O.OIO 0.011 -0.51 0.009 (0.017) (0.015) [0.60] (0.042) 1770 1930 -1.76 2333 (628) (554) [0.080] (1480) 342876 449280 -1.79 90139 (424939) 0.729 (346988) 0.762 [0.076] -1.63 (400341) 0.695 (0.088) (0.092) [0.10] (0.103) 0.197 0.238 -2.22 0.134 (0.074) (0.089) [0.02] (0.063) 0.257 0.246 1.41 0.269 (0.037) (0.027) [0.16] (0.035) 0.125 0.123 0.13 0.149 (0.051) (0.029) [0.89] (0.043) Geographic Distribution Northeast Midwest 0.093 0.250 -2.86 0.069 (0.292) (0.392) [0.005] (0.254) 0.129 0.203 -1.43 0.340 (0.320) (0.375) [0.16] (0.473) South West (5) Industi'v Distribution ol'tlit: Maiuifacturiiig I Itililies Wholesale Retail Finance, insurance. Real Estate Services Notes: The figure plant opening. for years 1982 Dollar cases are a in in The to 0,391 3.88 0,449 (0.460) fO.OOO] (0,097) 0.127 0,152 -0.77 0,140 (0.323) (0.348) [0.44J (0,347) Labor Force Construction Trnnsportntion, 0.660 (0.474) columns 1 0.067 0.059 1,79 0,050 (0.036) (0.019) [0,075] (0,043) 0.268 0.222 2,30 0,236 (0.156) (0.107) f0,02] (0,181) 0.052 0.059 -1.56 0.053 (0.031) (0.022) [0,12] (0,044) 0,068 0.068 -0,09 0,065 (0.046) (0.022) [0,92] (0,054) 0.217 0.216 0.17 0,263 (0.053) (0,045) [0,87] (0,104) 0.059 0.074 -3.54 0.051 (0.026) (0.030) [0.001] (0.035) 0.248 0.284 -2.99 0.246 (0.088) (0.070) [0,003] (0.101) and 2 are averages for the three years before the figures in the top panel of column 4 are a weighted average number of Million 1993, with weights proportional to the each year and industry. The figures in panels 2 to 5 of column 4 weighted average for years 1982 to 1993, with weights proportional to the in each year (see bottom of Table for the number of Million Dollar cases distribution of cases across years). All 1 monetary values are in 1983 dollars. . Table 3: The Effect of Plant Openings on the Wage Status Relative to the Date of the Plant Location Time T = T I = = = Losers (1) (2) (3) -320.4 -75.5 -244.8 (159.0) [118.1) -313.1 -38.5 (158.9) 118.0) -8 -6 -253.3 -8.2 (158.8) ,118.0) -5 28.5 118.0) -191.7 I i = = = -3 121.9 :iI8.1) -109.0 156.7 (158.9) ^118.1) -92.7 180.1 -l = -39.0 1=1 = ( = ( 243.6 5 and their standard errors Business Patterns data. column (1) and in ( -169.0 ttw; (column 118.2) (column 2) coefficients (6) on the County reports the difference between the 1) and tti t from the estimation of equation Column (2) entries. coefficients are plotted -186.7 118.1) 412.6 (158.7) Notes: The Table reports the -196.0 118.1) 368.1 181.3 (158.6) 1 118.1) 295.1 99.1. =4 -215.0 269.4 ( (158.7) 1 -215.0 118.1) 54.3 3 -242.1 222.2 (158.7) 1 -272.9 118.3) 7.7 2 -265.8 203.1 (158.7) = -258.4 118.6) (159.0) 1 18.0) -136.4 (158.7) T -258.1 66.3 J (158.9) -2 -274.6 -253.7 -225.1 -4 Difference -245.0 (158.9) (158.9) T by Year and Winner Winners T=-7 T Bill, Announcement (3) See the text for more the top panel of Figure 1 details. The normalized — ' « y pi c ~ p 2 S o '-^ •,"1 It; OJ "- ^ (D ^ p > "0 Uw 00 D 5> — < Z ? >s -— Cj _C OJ 53 z p -S tAl — !> CD a> ^ :5 P C "13 C C n j-j IJ -o > c > S h 00 >- rs OS — . 00 z a3 <^ 0-1 -P Si ^ (U S o o ON >- u _ to OJ b = < r- 00 C3 — ^ E Q. 5. — a ^4- ^ ? p <D c H O u — c (D (U cb OJ Q. E E K3 .— D^ 5 H c/] CQ -^ J^ T3 -O C H S^SO [— OJ eS ^A (D ^^ >f- CQ OJ e2 (D _o ID UU <^ '-^ "O c cr — o o p — oo ro i-ri r^ r^ i ~ c> v-i VO ^o rn O CJ ^^ -X (U p CO _aj Xi 5 c/) 1) ID 2 -z: :- o 2 , lO t^ ir^ s t-~- (^i t^ lo ON IT) ^O "O iO r^ — CN ON CO O o ,L_ 33 oo 22 p^ ^ k: ^ OJ <u = oo lO _- — CO r-i u 2 E 5i) , O .2 ^> t-. <=> OO o _ >- ; E O dj , ^ . , flj t? :^ _0 o ~ e E o U • — o c o H (U P3 Di _ 3 c o ™ u > CO — 1) — j_. ct: U <u c Cxi o X) '~ ac: c <D H c c rt o OU P3 S "C! > < C '.^ C^ c Ki cr Q. (U C Wl o CO c c so a. .£ 5 c :~ :^ t/l '-+— fOJ C>0 <u Cd >, OJ T3 "^ s C s t^ <u c J;:J <u c J= >^ J^ C3 ' CO C^ — CD r-l >>- 5 aj — o o B E ts ^ o o p r<i Z c -a _o CO ^ m ,o £ c "ra a _aj <u Co C/1 o (D C ID H~ _0J — -o c >- ol oo ^ I? *-' (U ca h- -5 •03 ;> P •5 o = n > bo -^ kS " ~ o ^ C) -^ O — > U •^^ ? u Q- o i- AJ p lU O f" CO X ra > 5 r- i^i -a E- b- "H J t— u - c ca cc '^ i^ > —c ^ O- ta — bX) O eXiO < ^ 5 o :^ J Di o o O dI x: o UU > < ra .s Di In ^ Z — u >- ^ en D i- Di Bo o O -a CI. :: < UO U- -<-» c3 :- W) - o iji: '5 ^ H Table The Impact of Winner 7: Status on Government Expenditures, Revenues, and Indebtedness Dependent Variables (l)/(2) P (std. error) Mean (1) (2) (3) 17.2 966.8 0.018 823.5 0.018 143.3 0.019 35.0 0.029 31.0 0.048 290.7 0.015 50.4 -0.002 25.8 0.047 70.7 0.076 953.6 0.019 273.6 0.020 211.3 0.027 680.0 0.019 392.2 0.010 56.3 0.071 904.3 0.018 543.4 0.024 EXPENDITURES Total (4.7) Current 14.5 (4.3) Capital 2.7 (2.1) Intergovernmental 1.0 (0.5) Selected Sub-Cateaories Education (Capital) 1.5 (0.5) Education. (Current) Police Protection 4.3 (1.3) -0.1 (0.3) Housing & Comm Dev. 1.2 (0.6) 5.4 Utilities (i.l) REVENUES Total 18.5 (5.0) Intergovernmental 5.6 (2.0) From State Government Total Own 5.7 (1.6) 12.8 (3.5) All Taxes 4.1 (1.7) Utility Charges 4.0 (0.8) INDEBTEDNESS Total Debt 16.3 (8.3) Nonguaranteed Debt 12.8 (6.7) Notes: The entries from the fitting millions of dollars. column in column of equation Column N The rows of p and their heteroskedastic consistent standard errors all of which are measured in identify the dependent variables, mean of the dependent variable in t-1 in winner counties and of the point estimates from (1) to the mean. The data source is the Annual = 4500. See the previous tables and the text for more details. (3) presents the ratio Survey of Governments. (1) are estimates (7). (2) reports the Appendix Table Cycles by Slates Number Distribution of Real Property Assessment I: in 1991 and Siibsegiient Years. Number of Slates of Years Between Revaluations (1) (2) 1 14 2 2 3 1 4 8 5 1 6 2 7 8 9 10 1 Unknown 2 Noles; The table reports the number of years between revaluations for the states in The the preferred sample for the housing price from this regression are reported in columns (3a) and (3b) of Table 6. In some states, the assessment regressions. results cycle varies within the In these cases, the table reports the state. The "Unknown" categoi^ is was not possible to determine the shortest of the revaluation periods. reserved for states where assessment cycle. D it The source for the information in this table is of the 1992 Census of Governments, Volume 2 Taxable Property Values. Number 1 Assessed Valuations for Local General Property Taxation. Appendix > 2 < o' E X ^o H U - ^r >. <' _l >- u > — 3=: "r; J 2 o o '-c -a o '-T o -r c5 OT ra ^^ ^ ^ E > U -J u . c — _^' < = o 6 ^ Sj£mQ££3:uSS> ^ _i o D < U - < <a ;?_)_) Is < _^ f= I ^ o -I 53 " £I = ra o^-^ J Ji- -5 n 'S ;_, o u 5 j= ^ = P fcDiH-lHc^XUOQOi/i^oQU^eiiH < o > X < o ^^^^^ — .iii _l>_lES_lfS_l_l>_IJ •5 -5 CQ _" < — bp'° o m > -5 Z I UQS o o >3^: a. o U < < aJ < u >; s "I = o~^ 0-- ^ o o-^ 0000 CO X c X "-^ re" ? s f- H g in 0) z XX re' -a lU E c o re a> "re "H 3 X > u a z U t ^ i K ^^ s c _) —1 7: «-> V, -;- 5: c/5 ^ i u 1^ ^'^ in « ^ ^5 If ° 2 re re _1 _J "u J" 5 > OQ u a> u p (U |^ _1 :s re -^ ^ c u § i p on .5 re -; -1 _J rs -J C re C/) f" > re re oj <5 ._ ,_ ^;5 -o P.-\ u PA Westchester, re "3 ?: C/0 jj ^ c c i> ^ 5 D oj S :^ Di ,_ (L> c Montgonier\', re c hp = c c ^ -3 ^ -a (^ re H s ^ ^ c = c w s " c " &^5 i2? _i ::S "E. g: OJ ^ -p a. ,3 '5 c re S = [3 5p 5p < > 2 CQ 5 CQ t^ a- ^ "p ¥ 1 "5 < pa Di 01 rn >r, w^ U-, -a "re re H > c rPf* 5h aft 1 I Z U = ~re [S 5 % ,0ft (L) _^ 1 _ s §• CO a. P 3 ^ = re Q o -^ 1=^ 1) J @c X 5 1 >, 5 f- s 'u "3}) c; "^ c SO ^ fe Si cy B c Z < H 3 5 Q UUQ t. U ^ _) a. (£P c C/1 y. •^ H Delaware, « p K i " P (D Z C/1 IE Jj re Di u < c X ^ t. <u N'S' cS >- bb c -p "0 X CQ ,0 K s 3 to U Z vo M^ ^ * •!l- 0^ ^ < < < -P It; " z s g '> = re c = !3 a! ^ re re re < r X a ^ ^ ^ i ^^K -H -a i ^ p S c ^,3 •— ^ — c "1 B s 5~ '^ 1- Jr; 2n |J c OJ r: J So c re "re (L> Q ^ 1- j- J —1 " - re" i oj re S S 2 g^'? t- k: t. ^zxf re g = ^ Lo 00 < X i_ ^ ^ CQ S ^ Che i K 5 c „ c ^^ IJ "^,3'^ J ? S' ^ V- 1- t- OJ 'G c/1 c3 re E c '-c -J ^ F 22 -0 c < 1 T3 i -a 're u s 5 H i) _E 0. a. E Z U 2 On Q 1 1 @ re B re -D ^ LU < n r^ m "S. -M E 3 < 5 < ^ m t^ r^i -f X3 — X3 a (2 CO r^ c^ m ^ ^ "- IJ c ^ ,'3ft (S c X s ^ ,_ ^ y - c ^ C c ^ c [-L_ ^ re c c ir: _) C K 1 » s. c 1^ "^ < bb ^ '-c: — J J > 1 M c re m2>5 ^ _ -5 < a < > i_ 2^ -J 1 < 5 ^ £P re ;§ " -2c •^y 3 QS _1 < < re VO " 'S1-0 n '* - J < u g < > o < ^ O Z u >- U >- ^"f_ ca c Q. 1 c o 5 -C P-, bfl T3 o U r~ 5P U O U o c5 Q ^ < j; b "_> O o i> 1-3 lU CO Qa s ^ D ^ (-; ^ _1 1 ^ .22 c/) > fe " ?: OJ J^ J (U CQ op o u Z U U — p o 7^ ^^ E o J ^J 33 CrC jj '^ M 2^ ^ 1 c ~ X 'S tS O O - m -^ •^ ^ U ~ ss a. S a3 o3 H P P o ^ Jo ~ ;S J Q i> J^ J I) 1) o if E V, 1^ H 5 ~ ugg^.ls c/2 O 1 & en' O 00 (U o E o CQ u < U Q Q < 53 fU ^ 00 T3 ^4 &i e^- := a 53 1> IJ IJ a o i> u o o o o (U a> ;r i> JJ^J =y 3 ^ til) 4- H o cH? ^ .5 CO S5 1 o =^ ^ Z 5 r"^ _. rl r- t~- S p o Q 1 _3 z a. c '/"I \o r- r~- C/5 ^ fe 1 ^ ^ j_ <u o O a> ^ - _ ^ ._ (L) ^ — o oo r^ GN r- >- _J P J O O r^ P ^ UHJ ^ J 1;^ °r Si. 1 h= o o — n oo E :^' X IX ^ 1- a> J S — EP ,ab C/5 ^ ^ — '^ ^ i- oj ^ O c 1 o < < LO D 6 ra i i Z < *~ < < 5 C^ o o ^ ly, '1 ^ .— ii r-~ t ;_ ^ :_ ~ ^ i S S « VO o > O «3 U ^ r^ ;= Oi t S 3 ^ <Tc 1> >.U u ° i 11 ^ o t_ CO 53 <— c/5 c/i ^ "5 CQ SI fc i_ ^ ^ 1— ^ I— I- t= = " S " " C t<L> 5: J 5^ S 00 c a ,3 s S _ 1 5 ^ s t< u M a oo M3 VO > CO 5 < -c '5. Q- o < CQ 3 C/1 u: en ^ o VO VO t-^ VO O k: « PL- It; Jo '^3 iZ '~ o _1 <y H ,"2) J D i « --0 2 ra ,M u S _L .2 -3 a- 1^ '^^ •l5 5^ 2 -a ^ ra ro o -a ~ r3 O 2 6. u Q- ^5 P H < <U z >- "o 'C omX S =<! c &0 S i> -a s < > > <L> > Cj 5? iz. < < < 5 > 4^12 g V^ I- ^ t. i_ 1- ^ i- ^ QJ (U p H" '^ ?: CO VI o o o O O O ° > ° ^ _1 <L1 •S" H r•^ Q uo 2 d £ m c/5 ^ >; 1 > X <O c o u < ^ o > U .SP coZZ E "1 -d X .° g ^1 1 o c75 "3 O 5^ 'e o U -=3 id CQ U z J £ c/0 ^ 8 sp > m c o 53 r- s ."SB 1 -a ro s > E O -5 2 o •S 1 U o 1 a, <: < M ID 5 > tC 3 ,M> o @ 00 ^ "S i c^ Figure 1: The Effect of Plant Opening on 1-Digit Industry Wage Bill in Winner and Loser Counties — Winners Losers 600 400 200 -200 -10 -5 year -100 - -200 -300 -10 -5 year Notes: Top Panel: Conditional average wage comparison, the scale of the average wage bill in bill in winner and loser counties. To facilitate the winner counties has been adjusted to equal the wage bill in loser counties at time t-1. Bottom panel: difference in conditional average wage bill in winner and loser counties. Figure 2: Counties - The Effect of Plant Opening on Winner and Loser Sample 1-Digit Industry Winners -e Wage Bill in Winner and Loser Losers 400 - 200 -200 -10 -100 -10 year Notes: Top Panel: Conditional average wage comparison, the scale of the average wage winner and loser counties. To facilitate the winner counties has been adjusted to equal the bill in bill in wage bill in loser counties at time t-L Bottom panel: difference in conditional average wage bill in winner and loser counties. Figure 3: Industries, The Effect of Plant Opening on Wage Bill Same County - Winner and Loser Sample in Winner and Loser Counties Winners - Other Losers 1500 500 -500 -1500 -10 -5 year 1000 500 -500 -1000 -10 -5 year Notes: Top Panel: Conditional average wage comparison, the scale of the average wage bill in bill in winner and loser counties. To facilitate the winner counties has been adjusted to equal the wage bill in loser counties at time t-1. Bottom panel: difference in conditional average wage bill in winner and loser counties. Figure 4: The Effect of Plant Opening on Wage Winner and Loser Sample Bill Winners - Same Industry, .\eighl;oriiig Counties —e- Losers 1500 - 1000 500 -500 -10 year 400 200 -200 -400 -10 year Notes: Top Panel: Conditional average wage average wage time bill in bill. To facilitate the comparison, the scale of the winner counties has been adjusted to equal the wage bill in loser counties at t-1. Bottom panel: difference in conditional average wage bill between winner and loser counties. Figure 5: The Effect of Plant Opening on Wage Winner and Loser sample Bill - Other Industres, Neighljoring Counties Winners Losers 0- -1000 -2000 -3000 -10 -5 year 4000- 3000 2000 1000 -10 -5 year Notes: Top time wage bill. To facilitate the comparison, the scale of the winner counties has been adjusted to equal the wage bill in loser counties at Panel: Conditional average average wage bill in t-1. Bottom panel: difference in conditional average wage bill between winner and loser counties. ,") •' . /''(-;,' Figure 6: The Effect of Plant 1 Opening on Property Values Winners a- in Winner and Loser Counties Losers H -5000 -10000 - -15000 2000- 1000 - - -1000 -2000 year Notes: Top Panel: Conditional average property value in winner and loser counties. To facilitate the comparison, the scale of the conditional average property value in winner counties has been adjusted to equal the conditional average property value in loser counties at time Bottom panel: difference in conditional average property value in winner and t-1. loser counties. Appendix Figure 1: The Effect of Plant Opening on 1-Digit Indtistry Employment and Loser Counties - Winner and Loser Sample — Winners in Winner Losers 25000 20000 - 15000 10000 5000 -2000 -4000 -6000 -8000 -10000 -12000 ^ -10 -5 year Notes: Top Panel: Conditional average employment in winner and loser counties. To facilitate the comparison, the scale of the conditional average employment in winner counties has been adjusted to equal the conditional average employment in loser counties at time Bottom panel: difference in conditional average employment in t-1. winner and loser counties. Date Due 3 9080 02618 0221