This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike License. Your use of this material constitutes acceptance of that license and the conditions of use of materials on this site. Copyright 2007, The Johns Hopkins University and Damian Walker. All rights reserved. Use of these materials permitted only in accordance with license rights granted. Materials provided “AS IS”; no representations or warranties provided. User assumes all responsibility for use, and all liability related thereto, and must independently review all materials for accuracy and efficacy. May contain materials owned by others. User is responsible for obtaining permissions for use from third parties as needed. Types of cost data Lecture 4 Damian Walker Aim of lecture To provide conceptual and practical insight into how to do costing in an economic evaluation Structure of lecture What do we mean by cost? Identify which costs to include How to measure resource use? How to value resource use? How to analyse/present cost data? Why consider costs? There are not, never have been and never will be enough resources to meet all of society’s needs or wants Scarcity implies choice between alternatives Cost is one factor which enables choice What do we mean by cost? Opportunity costs Opportunity cost = economic cost Cost is foregone benefit of a resource in it’s best alternative use Cost = market price only when price reflects value of marginal product (perfect competition) Need to estimate shadow prices / social value of resources: no market price: donated goods, volunteer time distorted price: MP of labour ≠ wage unstable prices: inflated / deflated exchange rates where goods have a yield over a period of time: capital goods (Wednesday’s lecture) Opportunity cost As simple as the opportunity cost concept is, it is one of the most important in microeconomics and economic evaluation The art in applying the concept correctly lies in being able to recognize the most valuable alternative that is sacrificed by the pursuit of a given activity Pop quiz You won a free ticket to see an Eric Clapton concert (which has no resale value). Bob Dylan is performing on the same night and is your next-best alternative activity. Tickets to see Dylan cost $40. On any given day, you would be willing to pay up to $50 to see Dylan. Assume there are no other costs of seeing either performer. Based on this information, what is the opportunity cost of seeing Eric Clapton? a) $0, (b) $10, (c) $40, or (d) $50. Remember The opportunity cost of an activity is the value of everything you must sacrifice to pursue it So if you are willing to pay as much as $50 to see Dylan and the cost of a ticket to see Dylan is $40, what is the opportunity cost of seeing Clapton? Reference Farraro PJ, Taylor LO. Do economists recognise an opportunity cost when they see one? A dismal performance from the dismal science. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 2005; 4(1) Which costs to include? Julien Harneis freedryk andyinsouthamerica The Crownless King How can we categorise these costs? Classification of costs Capital items: those that last longer than a year or have a unit price > $100 Recurrent items: those that are used up in the course of a year and are usually purchased regularly Examples? Classification of costs Fixed costs Semi-fixed costs Variable costs do not change when the quantity of output produced changes change according to how much output produced Examples? In the long-run it is assumed that all costs are variable Activities as inputs If one activity is clearly separate from the others, both financially and administratively, it may be easier to record the total cost E.g. start-up, training and social mobilisation activities are treated as categories of inputs and included along with personnel, vehicles etc. it is assumed that all the resources required for the activity are included in that category and not under the separate categories Shared costs The resources that you are costing may not be fully used in the specific cost centre that is being examined In this case, a decision needs to be made about what proportion of the resources should be allocated to the specific cost centre that is being costed and the way it should be allocated Shared costs What are some examples of typical shared costs? What allocation rules might be used to distribute these costs to specific cost centres? E.g. in a hospital, how might we allocate the costs of the kitchen to different wards? Methods for allocating shared costs: direct allocation step-down allocation Other costs? So far focussed on programme costs What other costs might we consider in, for example, an economic evaluation of vaccines against rotavirus? Classification of costs Direct Indirect Intangible Health sector Other sectors Patient / family Productivity losses Future Which costs to include? Perspective of analysis Societal broad Other agencies Health service Patient narrow Which costs to include? Perspective of analysis Range of costs Perspective Inpatient days & Special education outpatient visits Days off work Health service ✔ ✖ ✖ Health service & other agencies ✔ ✔ ✖ Societal ✔ ✔ ✔ Which costs to include? Time-frame of analysis Suitable for disease and intervention in question days: prophylactic drugs for diarrhoea months: chemo-prophylactic drugs for malaria life-time: drugs for HIV/AIDS Which costs to include? Future costs Life-years normally Gained life-years lived Related medical and non-medical costs Incorporate Incorporate Unrelated medical and non-medical costs Leave out of the analysis May be incorporated at analyst’s discretion in a sensitivity analysis Which costs to include? Quantitative importance big-ticket items first will inclusion of additional costs affect the conclusions? Attribution does the resource use consumed relate to the disease (intervention)? How to measure resource use? How to measure resource use? Different study designs Possible vehicles for resource use data: Best source of data depends on: RCTs observational studies literature administrative databases expert opinion study question research resources Economic evaluations usually use a range of methods Most reliable Least reliable How to measure resource use data? Advantages of RCTs ‘Economic analyses … are likely to be most helpful when undertaken as part of large, unblinded, pragmatically designed, randomised trials based as closely as possible on regular clinical practice’ (Freemantle & Drummond 1997) How to measure resource use data? Advantages of RCTs Randomisation ensures internal validity Facilitates prospective data collection accurate unbiased Can link with measurement of health outcome Uses individual patient data can use standard tests of significance How to measure resource use? Disadvantages of RCTs Often too short in duration May lack external validity May include protocol driven costs Will need to extend study to measure others costs How to measure resource use data? Data collection techniques Case report forms Medical records Questionnaires Patient diaries DeMTAP pictorial diaries Consumption and expenditure data Health and non-health 12-month period Includes home-produced consumption Prompts in the form of a checklist and aide mémoire Lesong Conteh Source: Wiseman V, et al. Using diaries to collect data in resource-poor settings: questions on design and implementation. Health Policy Plan 2005;20:394-404. Used with permission. Copyright 2005 Oxford University Press. All Rights Reserved. Source: Wiseman V, et al. Using diaries to collect data in resource-poor settings: questions on design and implementation. Health Policy Plan 2005;20:394-404. Used with permission. Copyright 2005 Oxford University Press. All Rights Reserved. How to measure resource use? How detailed to go? Micro costing vs. gross costing (Gold et al. 1996) Top-down vs. bottom-up (Drummond et al. 2005) Choice depends on need for specific estimation vs. research costs Precision vs. pragmatism How to value resource use? How to value resource use? Principles involved Opportunity cost value of next best use of resources perfectly competitive market, price = opportunity cost prices in health care often unavailable or distorted caution in using prices derived from health care ‘markets’ need to use shadow prices Well, that’s the theory at least … In practice, most studies use unadjusted market prices and / or use cost-to-charge ratios Costs vs. charges In the USA, a common method for estimating the economic cost of medical services is to adjust the charges through the use of cost-tocharge ratios Cost-to-charge ratios are coefficients developed by expert panels to convert charges for medical services to their true economic costs Applying cost-to-charge ratios to medical service charges produces average estimates of true costs How to value resource use? Principles involved Average vs. marginal cost? Marginal costs only cover the costs of producing one additional unit of output Choice depends on time-frame of analysis short-term, few items are variable, e.g. drugs, tests long-term, all items are variable including labour and capital Economists often take long-run perspective In long-run can use average cost = marginal cost Definitions Average cost = TC / Q, the average cost per unit of output Marginal cost = (TC of x + 1 units) – (TC of x units), the extra cost of producing one extra unit of output Average marginal cost = (TC of x units – TC of y units) / (x units – y units), where x > y Incremental cost = extra cost incurred by one programme over another Example Say, for example, 60% of children in Nepal are fully vaccinated at a cost per child of $15 The National Immunisation Programme in Nepal aims to fully vaccinate 85% of children: do you think the average marginal cost per additional child fully vaccinated will be <, = or > than $15? Why? How to value resource use? Sources for health service unit costs Administrative databases (DRGs, reference costs), e.g. www.who.int/choice/country/en/index.html Manuals, e.g. www.pssru.ac.uk/uc/uc2006contents.htm Published literature Specific estimation How to analyse and present cost data? Present resource use separately from unit cost Present distribution of costs Despite the usual skewness in the distribution of costs, it is the arithmetic mean that is the most informative measure Measures other than the arithmetic mean do not provide information about the cost of treating all patients, which is needed as the basis for healthcare policy decisions Issues in analysis of costs Parametric statistics assume normal distribution Costs may not be normally distributed So either: use standard approaches such as t tests OR use non-parametric techniques (such as bootstrapping) May not have power to detect difference in costs Critique of published costing studies A review of 45 randomised trials that included economic evaluations and were published in 1995 showed serious inadequacies in the use of statistical methods for costs (Barber & Thompson 1998) A re-review of these studies found that the costing methods were of poor quality (Graves et al. 2002) Graves et al. (2002) concluded that “No amount of statistical analysis can compensate for poor quality cost data” Conclusions Good costing needs to: be explicit about assumptions define the perspective adopted apply the opportunity cost principle recognise the importance of the time-frame Conclusions Issues for debate include which perspective should be adopted? how long should the time-frame be? whether to include future costs? precision vs. pragmatism: how detailed should cost measurement be? References Barber JA, Thompson SG. Analysis and interpretation of cost data in randomised controlled trials: review of published studies. BMJ. 1998; 317: 1195-1200 Freemantle N, Drummond M. Should clinical trials with concurrent economic analyses be blinded? JAMA. 1997; 277(1): 63-64 Graves N, Walker D, Raine R, Hutchings A, Roberts JA. Cost data for individual patients included in clinical studies: no amount of statistical analysis can compensate for inadequate costing methods. Health Econ. 2002; 11(8): 735-739. Wiseman W, Conteh L, Matovu F. Using diaries to collect data in resource-poor settings: questions on design and implementation. Health Policy Plan. 2005; 20(6): 394-404