LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/taxationofearninOObarr V THE TAXATION OF EARNINGS UNDER PUBLIC ASSISTANCE by N.A.Barr and R.E.Hall Number 85 April 1972 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 MASS. INST. TECH. MAY 9 1972 DEWEY LIBRARY THE TAXATION OF EARNINGS UNDER PUBLIC ASSISTANCE by N.A.Barr and R.E.Hall Number 85 April 1972 The research reported here was supported by a grant from the Ford Foundation 1. INTRODUCTION There is substantial agreement among contemporary observers that the system of public assistance in the United States Families with Dependent Children — — especially Aid to is thoroughtly bankrupt. An important link in the chain of arguments supporting this view is the belief that public assistance discourages recipients from working by imposing a confiscatory tax on their earnings. Proponents of a simple negative income tax have argued that the tax of about 50 percent on earnings implicit in their plans is a major advance over the oppressive rates of close to 100 percent implicit in AFDC. That is, they propose to reduce benefits under the negative income tax by 50 cents for each dollar of additional earnings, while they claim that AFDC reduces benefits by a full dollar for each dollar of additional earnings. The proponents of the Family Assistance Plan currently under consideration in Congress have argued that the somewhat higher implicit tax rate of 67% still represents a liberation from the provisions of AFDC. This discussion revolves, or rather should revolve, around a simple question of fact: What tax does AFDC impose on earnings? This question of fact does not seem to have been raised at all in the public discussion of the defects of AFDC. The simple belief that AFDC is confiscatory, or nearly so, has become firmly established without resting on any investigation of the facts about the system under indictment. To complete the argument one must, of course, also answer the question: are high implicit tax rates really a disincentive to labor supply? Simple theories of labor supply are ambiguous on this point. See, for example, R.A. Musgrave, The Theory of Public Finance McGraw-Hill 1959. Chapter 11, page 232 et seq. . -2- Our purpose here is to present a fairly detailed attempt to answer this question of fact, starting from a large body of data on recipients of AFDC. Our conclusions lend no support whatever to the critics of the system. suggest, on the contrary, that AFDC embodies a much more flexible and dis- criminating resolution between the need for high tax rates of the benefits in the hands of the poor — to preserve the incentive to work. for AFDC. They — — — to keep most and the need for low tax rates than does any proposed substitute We show that AFDC benefits are decreased almost dollar for dollar for most categories of unearned income, especially benefits received from other programs of assistance. for earnings are much lower. On the other hand, the implicit tax rates The earnings of mothers receiving AFDC are taxed at below 40 percent in Chicago, Houston, Los Angeles, New York, Pittsburgh and San Francisco, and at less than 75 percent in the remaining three cities included i,n the study, Baltimore, Detroit and Washington, D.C. In the seven cities where it proved possible to estimate the implicit tax rate for the earnings of the father, it was below 40 percent for four and below 70 percent in two more. Statistical tests of these estimates show that their departure from the value of 100% cannot conceivably be explained by random variation in the data. -3- 2. THE DETERMINATION OF AFDC BENEFITS AFDC provides categorical assistance to families who apply for benefits and who are eligible for them. The program is divided into two sections, AFDC- FG (family group), for which a family is eligible only if the father is absent or severely disabled and AFDC-UP (unemployed parent), for which a family is eligible if the father is unemployed. AFDC-UP is optional for states. In December 1967 only 21 states, covering all the cities in the present study For the United States as a except for Houston, had instituted this program. whole 95% of families receiving AFDC do so under AFDC-FO. whose incomes exceed certain levels are excluded. In addition, families We are concerned here with the treatment of families who are eligible for AFDC either because of the abs- ence or disability of the father or because of his unemployment, whose incomes from earnings are greater than zero, but are less than the maximum permitted by welfare regulations. Specifically, we test the hypothesis that the benefits of families in this group are reduced by the full amount of their earnings. Very little information about this question is available from the federal and state laws governing AFDC, or from the regulations of the administrators of the program. A great deal is left to the discretion of the case workers who are responsible for the detailed operation of AFDC. Consequently, we must turn to data on the actual decisions made bv case workers in order to answer our auestions, Our data were obtained from a detailed survey of one out of every hundred families receiving assistance under AFDC in November 1967. The questionnaires were filled out by the case worker, not by the families receiving aid. Consequently, our results measure the implicit tax rates that case workers think they are imposing, and may exceed the tax rates as perceived by family members to the extent that they are able to conceal their true earnings worker. from the case As a partial check against this, we have also computed implicit tax -u - rates from a body of data collected from the families themselves. These results tend to confirm our conclusion that the tax rates on earnings implicit in the actual administration of AFDC are much lower than is generally thought. Our basic data are total monthlv benefits received under AFDC in the survey month for each of 14,224 families in the nine cities, together with income from other sources broken down into the following categories: earnings of the mother, earnings of the father, if present, earnings of children, earnings of other family members, contributions of an absent father, benefits under social security, proceeds of unemployment insurance, contribution of other persons, other cash income, and income in kind. The relation we wish to study has the general form (1) = B B, 1, where B 10 - I t. y. is the level of benefits received by family i, B is the level of benefits received by a family with no other source of income, t are the tax rates on the 10 different kinds of income, and y. , i'l are the levels of the different kinds of income for family This model is not in itself adequate for our study. of benefits, B , through t through y. & 7 i,10 i. The base level varies across families as a consequence of aspects of AFDC that are not concerned with adjusting benefits in accordance with income. We have found it useful to take account of the race of the family head, the presence or absence of the father, the health of the mother and father, and the number and age of children. Our final specification, arrived at 1 by considerable experimentation , 10 12 1 k=l is k l 'k j-1 J Ui The purist should be comforted to hear that almost all experimentation used the data only for Los Angeles and San Francisco. The chosen specification was then run without change for the other seven cities, the results for which can be regarded as powerful confirmation of the California results. ' where the x'sare variables defined as zero except as follows: x, 1,1 x = 1 for all families = 1 if the family has a mother but no father, and the mother is unhealthy = 1 if the family has a healthy father but no mother = 1 if the family has an unhealthy father and no mother = 1 if the family has two parents and the father is healthy = 1 if the family has two parents but the father is unhealthy = 1 if the head of the family is white = 1 if there are two or more children = 1 if there are three or more children ' x x. i,4 x. x. ' x 1 , x, i,8 x i,9 x = 1 =2 x i,ll if there are five or more children = the number of children minus 5 if there are 6 or more = 1 if there is a child of pre-school age. x 1 if there are four children , \.£- The ten kinds of income are the following y = earned income of the mother (0 if there is no mother) = earned income of the father (0 if there is no father) = earned income of children = earned income of other family members = contributions from absent father == contributions from other persons = benefits from social security = benefits from unemployment insurance ' y 1 » y. _ y. , y. ,. y, , i,3 1,4 i,5 i,6 y l , / y. i,8 •b- v. - = other cash income = incomes in kind „ i,9 y. J , „ i,10 The sample consists of 12,292 one-parent families, of which all but 370 are families having mothers only. no earnings, Of the parents in these families 10,979 had 307 earned less than $100 per month, 560 earned between $100 and $250 per month, and 446 earned $250 per month or more. In addition, the 1932 families with two parents, of which 1585 had no earnings sample contains from either parent, 87 had joint earnings of less than $100, 127 had earnings between $100 and $250, and 133 had earnings of $250 or more. In the regressions, families without earnings make no direct contribution to estimation of the implicit tax rates on earnings. Rather, their role is to make the estimates of the other determinants of benefits more precise and thus to reduce the variance of the estimated tax rates. Table 1 presents estimates of t through t , , the tax rates on earnings, separately for each of the nine cities in the study. enough observations to estimate considerable accuracy. t.. , In every city there are the tax on the earnings of mothers, with Six of the nine cities have values of below 40 per- t cent, and only one, Washington D.C., is above 60 percent. In every citv, hypothesis that For t is 100 percent is rejected decisively. t ? , the the tax rate for the father's earnings, the data are inadequate in Baltimore and Houston (the latter is in a state with no AFDC-UP) estimates are reasonably precise. other two are under 70 percent. on the earnings of fathers. , but in the remaining cities the Four of the seven are below 40 percent, and an- Only Washington D.C. seems to put a confiscatory tax Estimates of t~, the tax rate on the earnings of the children, are of interest inasmuch as states are permitted (though not required) to disregard in assessing benefits the monthly earnings of the children up to a maximum of $50 per child and $150 per family. The estimates suggest that every city except New York availed itself of this desregard provision V' * ' •' -7- u Q •— •> m o o N-^ o CN C o r-» 4J • (JD C •-\ /—s <r vC <r cn CN r-i >— vD 00 • o r-H • o s— o ' oo oo • • •*-• • " o o -•— 1 •H .e CO n) S o o HM O e c « tO t-i CO ft. /~N /~\ o> cn ro CN cn cn o o o N— H O o N-' o oo vo cn CN rH <r en CO vO CNl ON CO r-l O O v— o • • • ^"N V'—N <r o> oo oo • • r-l CN cn i-l • • N-/* o o N—' I~~ vo • • J3 u 3 00 u-i to • • ! o o c CU u o i-h o o o CO W o oo N_^ O o^ o 1 m O cn o N— o • J* C u l-i c • o o o m m CM o oo en ON cn o o o 2 CO to 0) r-l 4-1 3 CU (0 l-l X w H rJ PQ 14-1 < H cO CXC 3^ m cn o o o i-h o c o I-H to 01 4-1 C-4 to 4J O C c o CNl O o o cn O rH O oo o C O 1-^ CN oo rH r-l O O r-» cn cni <3- O O O r-l to w o u 4-1 cn m m o o o • • 00 *s o m o o • • O o o rH VC CN rH vO • • • rH m cn oo rH rH cu Q o CO CJ> o cn •H u CN o o o CN 00 cn on o o o -<r rH 00 CN -a- on • • o oo rH r-^ o o B CO pa cn o m o o o • • CN) • o o CU u rJ 01 V4 0) CO 43 -C W O rH oo c r4 CU C • 4-1 o a 4-» CO fc u T> rH •H J= u to u cu -C 4-1 o -8- (only for New York is it possible conclusively to reject the hypothesis that the true tax rate on the earnings of the children is zero). The estimates of t , 4 the tax rate for the earnings of other family members, are nowhere near as precise as those for and t„, but seem generally to be less than 40 percent. t.. Table 2 presents estimates of the tax rates on sources of income other than earnings. income. Generally these are higher than the rates for earned The tax rates for contributions of an absent father are estimated with reasonable accuracy in every city. The estimated rate is 80 percent or above in five of the nine cities, and below 60 percent in only one. This component of income is probably the easiest of all to conceal from the case worker, so the true tax rate may be much less than these estimates. The estimated tax rates on the contribution of others seems to be somewhat lower than those for the contribution of fathers, although many of the standard errors are large. The tax rates on benefits under social security are estimated with reasonable precision in all nine cities. is 90 percent or more, In four of them, the estimated rate in three it is between 65 percent and 90 percent, and in two, Houston and San Francisco, it is below 40 percent. Houston has very low tax rates on all forms of income and a low overall level of benefits, but there is no similar explanation of the low rate for San Francisco. The benefits paid under unemployment insurance seem to be taxed at the same rate as benefits under social security, although so few recipients of public assistance also receive unemployment benefits that the standard errors are large. The estimated rates for other cash income are somewhat lower than those for social security but are still generally higher than those on earnings. Finally, except in Los Angeles, it does not seem possible to estimate the tax rates on income in kind. Table 3 presents the estimates of the coefficients of the determinants of benefits other than income. The constant estimates the benefits received -9c_> i C£ • Q C •H J3 co <r « 3 i-H m o o o r-» i-H co CN ON o O O m O O c <r O o o oo 00 r-- C o 01 nj Ov o o o CT\ r- 4-1 o u CO H U c s vO cfl tfl o o o o o CO vO CT\ r-l O VO o c tH O mm o oo on m o o o cm ON -d- r-H O o o *-* • • CO 43 00 )-i 3 .o m O o o oo 00 (0 •H O CO rH <H O r-4 m vo <r o o o P-, u o >* *^N /—N CN CM 00 vO <T 3 s • • • **_• 2: y— -^ CO CO mo o *~s o o o o •— CM vO 00 o o s-o • • o co • • • s»-^ <r /-~\ *"-N 00 ^oo iH 0> -d" CN o o Nw' o • • • o <*s o CU E o o c in cu l~- a) c co O c •w o > • § -J •-^ 00 vO CM • o o >— o 6C co r-l to CU ^\ CO CU r-l • ^-s ^^ CM cm <r o o o s-^ O o •^s o vO • r*. • • • ^— *— co m m o o c iH vO 00 o o— o • • **-^ • u a o r-l o m o oo CO w J 3 CO CU O 4-1 o o m O o o 00 CM <r co 4-1 r-l cm CM i-H r-l CM -j- CO r-l r-l oo in O o o EC to H tfl H m o o Vw^ o o u -3" 00 a* -3" 00 i-H ON 4-1 • cu Q co o o **^ o vO CO CM vO O O o w* o • • • • • r-H • o 'w' CT\ vO CO o • • I o o i i **^s o H 6£ •"N cfl cr. CO CJ 00 o •H • • w • o Vw' o 4=" u y—\ S-~\ CM CO co CN <f 4-1 r-l r-4 O oV o • • o ^— ^— /*-N vO vD vO i-H o> co • • • o v-x o ,—*, vO CO vO rH o\ r^» • • o o~' CO s m r^ • O >w^ CU u Q 6 /— •H i-H 4J oo r-l • Cfl • pq CO 3 C o •H •H 4J 4-1 3 C 3 4-1 w u o CO CU M Cfl X. 4-1 U 4-1 14-4 cfl O iw C o u i i Cfl (4 CU 4-1 3 c CJ cu CO o 14-4 o cu /> M a CO H < O -~O to 43 • t-l r-i t-l 4-1 i oo r^ \D vO o o o ^-^ o • • • O •H 4-1 0) CO C O • 43 •H 4= J3 •H ^J • /— CO vO r>. O o o s-x a> v CO O r-l CT> • .>-' /— y— -*-s m CM o o— r^. U~l o o O o CO cu E o >, 3 O cfl r-l 1-1 3 E co cu c C -H p. 3 4= c CO •H tfl CJ CU s u o CJ 4=" c cu 4-1 o •H cu e "o o c CJ MC -H 4^ • r-4 V—* -10- by a family with no other source of income whose characteristics are such that all of the variables x ^ 2''*"' x i 12 are zero. This control group no father, and with one child consists of families with a mother who is nonwhite, not of pre-school age. the There is very substantial variation among cities in level of benefits paid to families in this group: Houston pays only $66 per month, while New York pays $168, for example. The reported health of the parents does not seem to have any systematic effect on the level of benefits that a family receives. The estimated effect of poor health of the mother when there is no father present is less than $10 per month in absolute value for every city except San Francisco, where it is paradoxically negative. Families with fathers but no mothers receive substantially lower benefits than those with mothers only in every city except New York. have a systematic Again, the health of the father in these families does not effect on the level of benefits. Families with two parents receive higher benefits than those with only a mother in all the cities except Chicago, Baltimore (if the father is healthy) and Detroit (if the father is unhealthy). Once again the health of the father has no system- atic effect on the level of benefits. In results not reported here we found that the health of the mother likewise has no systematic effect. Only Chicago seems to discriminate substantially by race. It pays approximately $42 per month more to families headed by whites than to those headed by nonwhites. In every city the benefits paid for .additional children decline as the number of children grows. This effect is strongest in Houston, where the second child adds $18 per month to benefits while the sixth child adds only $1. Baltimore, a more generous city, drops from $41 for the second to $7 for -11- On the other hand, in New York benefits drop only slightly for the sixth. from $44 for the second to $40 for the sixth child. Since the more generous cities tend to reduce the incremental benefits paid for children less than do the less generous ones, the constants in Table 3 understate the actual variation in the benefits paid to families with large numbers of children. Finally, in four of the cities benefits are reduced if one or more of the children is too young for school; in the other five benefits are the same or slightly higher. There is thus no evidence of any substantial subsidy to mothers who are unable to work because of the need to look after young children , Table 4 presents a comparison of the benefits paid by the various cities to a black family with no father and three children, at various levels of the mother's earnings. At lower levels of earnings New York is the most generous city by a wide margin, and even at earnings of $400 per month, only Pittsburgh with its tax rate of only 18 percent pays a higher level of benefits than does New York. Washington D.C. pays benefits to families with no earnings not too far below the level of $200 per month typical of the cities other than Houston and New York, but its tax rate is so high that it pays almost nothing to families with earnings of $200 per month or more. -12- u Q ^^ . CO cd 3 /_^ r~ cm oo to 43 •— CT. CN cr> CO- 1 n-^ N--* /~\ *-n o o O CM 1-1 en <r CM CM r-4 CM CM <-H •~D <t r-i cn 1 sy s-^ s_-* O u M •i-l CJ cd c cd p y: fn C ^N /~N /— 00 ro CM <- ~d- </> w 1 i »*_• •— ^-N 1^ ON i-H r-l r»« CM r-i — 1 ^x vo O t» r-~ oo co <r m v— v 43 ec M 3 XI S~\ to m r- <r 4-1 4-1 •H i-H 1-1 0-. -co- ^~N m cn ^o i ^ •— •"N t-t i-H i-H 1 *_• •— m in en CM CM 1 s-^ N ~' r-. cm cn I m •«-• 4>2 n o ^-s >-l 3 00 CM vO 0) i-H z •H CH c m vw cn r^ in 1 CO- v-' *w^ O s~\ i-H i-l y^N vD m en ^^ N--* cn -h <r cn si" CM o CM «-• to 01 01 0) /— <*~S r-» >- H M u ^N I-H 01 oo to S3 *»— cn cm i-i </> /-n >. O VO <t CM CM m m 1 1 I x^ N—' v— •~ ON 00 cn r-l m <r cn ct\ r-. cn cn *w to u c o u to 3 o * •-s ^d o <j- -a- CO <T 00 CO .-I </> I N_^ S-i 0) 43 o 4-1 m cn 01 i-H I-l Q *— <r m CTv m CM CO- y~s 03 0> 4J o 60 /— efl to w O vO •H 43 -ai-i u •CO- -d" w r-l r>» <T .-1 o cn cn cm 1 -I r~- 1 si- i-H ,-1 cn <n r-» oo r-t CM m 1 1 0) u 3- in oo 00 r~- 1 1 I s* VO vO m i-H 1 1 pa >. 43 >, 43 4-> i-H «4J * >. I-H 4-1 c to 4-1 to c o u C O p * #1 >. >. 43 l-> r-l c o 1-1 ^ x: ca oj «-l 4-1 0) r-l 4= JZ 43 4-1 n) 01 CO Xi oi 4J C O 3 s b 03 ^H 4-1 crj C 01 U 43 4J ^H cd ?> rH >> C 4= O M 0) CO 01 43 43 *-" efl Pm (3 3 P. 0) M 01 « to cd 0) 4J 43 C C 0) 3 M cd CL wi 01 JZ 43 43 4-1 43 4J 4-1 CCJ 4-1 Cd O "4-1 PQ tS^ eg 4-i n-i c o 10 01 0) 4-1 B •H -H 43 x) 3 cd 0) 33 oj -a ^H -H x: 3 O U Cd T3 c > c 0) i-H CM <* CO CO co CM 00 CM CM CO CM CM ^^ C^ 00 CM • o <f <r m CO -dN t /-N s-*> co o in cm CM to r-» G\ CM CM in -3- m co CM CO CM -<t m CM co 00 CM .-1 o o o CO co \0 <t CO CO • CO m m -* CM CM in 00 CO CM t-H ^a- r-. -* CO • o O \0 CM co CO CM O CO v£> H CO CO r^ r^ CO O^ r- co sr CM **s ^~v /-^ vO CM CO vO CM i-{ CM CM vO CO co * CM CM CM r-» O o o m 00 \D v£> • CO O 00 C/> vO • 1 co 1 o 00 CM CO to -C 13 rH H 0) U T-t M-l T3 c *» (0 A' •o u JZ u u u 3 o 14-1 c o 1 u IM C 3 <u M a. m-i •o iH •H AU J= 0) TJ CO i-H * -2 U •H CO 3 CO h XO •H t^ O O o x; CO CO u co -I u o M o cr T3 CO cu «-) <-" to C CO U -H m i « g 3 W CO n > U T3 CM Qj CO 8 CO CO *-> 3 XI CO 2 O =a4- TABLE 4 Comparison of Benefits at Various Levels of Earnings BENEFIT AT CITY No earnings Earnings of $100 per mon Earnings of $200 per moi Earnings of $400 per month New York 253 219 185 Detroit 215 160 105 San Francisco 215 176 137 59 Chicago 207 168 129 51 Los Angeles 207 172 137 67 Pittsburgh 192 174 156 138 Baltimore 186 136 86 Washington, D.C. 162 90 18 Houston 101 81 59 Note: 117 17 Benefits are for a family with a nonwhite mother in pood health, no father, and three children of school age. -15- Potential Sources of Bias 3. In this section we consider alternative explanations of our finding that earnings are taxed at low rates in most cities. These explanations are statistical in nature and our discussion will be carried out in the context of a stylized version of our actual regression equation. B. (3) where = B l u. o - ty ' . 1 + u. 1 is a random disturbance. The estimate of the tax rate, l t will 11 11 be biased downward if there is a positive correlation between v. and u.. We will consider two possible sources of such a correlation: first, v. and B. are jointly determined, so the usual problem of simultaneous equations arises, and u. are uncorrelated in the population they may and, second, even if y have a positive correlation in the sample because of the peculiar way in which it is drawn. and y. are jointly determined, then there is an equation in If B. the reduced form of the system for y. (4) = a Q We have written - a., y a lU± u . rather then + a., u • in this equation because there seems to be a presumption that the relation between u.and y sloped — is negatively families who receive unusually high benefits (positive u.) given their earnings ought to work less, and earn less, than families with The regression coefficient estimating the tax negative values of u.. rate is (5) ^ f ^B,(y. - y) -.2 -16- where V is the sample mean of the V. wc ,,. plim (6) — plim o u , o the variance of u. 1 plim — , 1 A nlimft plim a a, 1 2 a, t+ + a_a J U o 1 = (B ) - ta u li . + u.)/v(a i o + u. li a, - y) a lUl - y) o ta O \ ) a u = o, and plim -1 I J. r ) u 2 u. 1 = ^ t = v o so we have , 1 2 2 (j) W; - ta o + (a Q J- I plim We note that plim y = a (B 7 T * = t Now . 1 ' 1 2 U 2 u. 4a i Here the slope of the regression line is not less than t but, rather, is greater. Our estimate of the tax rate ought to be overstated if the bias from simultaneity is a problem. on the other hand, would cause a downward bias Errors in observing y in the estimate of the tax rate. Suppose that the true level of earnings is v. so the true relationship is (8) B. l = B o + - tv. i Howeve r, we observe i which differs from y y. (9) u. y i = y + V i i * where E(y • y. ) = E(v. ) = 0. by a random error of observation, v : -17- Then the regression coefficient is (10) t = \ (y - y) | N I | I (y ± - y) ± -,2 and 1 P lim v I . plim (11) plim - = plim [(B + u B ) - (y 2 £ y* + v + u " ty 2 \ P lim „ I We let a ( = t 1 + v T) > and a^ = plim - - y) i = i and + v (v i | " (y ) [ v ± plim ^ . i - v) _ and note that Uy* + v. - v) = O 2 . + a Thus 2 plim (12) t = t —^* a which is less than t if a v 2 . y* + a 2 v > 0. The econometric technique of two-stage least squares can, in principle, eliminate biases due either to simultaneity or to errors in the right-hand variable. We applied this method using as instruments or first-stage variables the following characteristics: the age, race, health, education and birthplace (whether born in the south) of the mother, and separately of the father where present, the number and ages of the children, the number of non-parental adults, and the city in which the family lived; complete interaction was allowed between race and the other characteristics. those reported earlier. Our results were very little different from In particular, there was no definite tendency for the tax rates estimated by two-stage least squares to exceed those estimated by ordinary least squares. 2 -18- Another source of bias arises from the nature of the sample. A family enters the regression only if it receives positive benefits. At higher levels of earnings it is less likely that a family will appear in the sample than at lower levels of earnings. Those families that have high earnings and do appear in the sample are likely to be those who receive unusually high benefits for their incomes. In terms of our statistical model, observations with high values of v. are likely to have positive values of the disturbance, u.. would not receive If they did not, then it is probable that they positive benefits and therefore would not appear at all. Consequently, there may be a positive correlation between y. and u, , and our estimate of the tax rate mav be biased downward on this account. There can be no doubt that our results are contaminated by the way the sample was chosen. There are two reasons to believe, however, that the bias may not be too severe. be equally biased — First, all of the estimated tax rates should unearned income should drive families out of the sample just as surely as earned income. Our finding that the tax rates on earned income are substantially lower than those for unearned income cannot be explained by the nature of the sample. Second, the severity of the bias depends on the dispersion of the disturbances. If there were no disturbances, 101 all of the observed values of B. and y. would lie along6 the line B. = B i and our regression would estimate •'l t precisely. In fact, - ty., the dispersion of the residuals in our regressions is relatively small, as shown in Table 3, -19- It seems likely to us, therefore, that our finding of relatively low tax rates on earned income under AFDC cannot be explained purely as a statistical artifact, and that the prevailing belief that the system of public assistance imposes a nearly confiscatory tax on earnings needs substantial revision. Date Due 21 7f «| ftN. )EC JUN 3 1994 2 1995 3 "f?j RPR 5'8'd WR22'85 feMTi Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 TDflD 003 TST 7M MIT LIBRARIES 3 TOAD D03 TST 736 MIT LIBRARIES 3 3 TDfiD DD3 TST 7fi7 TOflO QD3 c, s^ ? -^ MIT LIBRARIES 3 TOAD DD3 TST 753 10AO 0D3 T2A 3 Alt. MIT LIBRARIES 3 "DflD 003 126 A2M MIT LIBRARIES 3 TOAD D03 TEA A73 MIT LIBRARIES 3 TOAD DD3 TEA AS?