4 MIT LIBRARIES HS34 IN MINI N II 3 9080 03317 9133 I | \f\H'0 $~i u 'DEWEY I Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series POWERFUL WOMEN: DOES EXPOSURE REDUCE BIAS? Lori Beaman Raghabendra Chattopadhyay Esther Duflo Rohini Petia Pande Topalova Working Paper 08-1 July 17,2008 RoomE52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Paper Collection http://ssrn.com/abstract=1 162358 Social Science Research Network at Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/powerfulwomendoeOObeam Women: Does Exposure Reduce Powerful Lori Beaman, Raghabendra Chattopadhyay, Esther Bias: Duflo, Rohini Pande and Petia Topalova* Abstract We exploit random assignment of gender quotas across Indian village councils to investi- gate whether having a female chief councillor affects public opinion towards female leaders. Villagers who have never been required to have a female leader prefer male leaders and per- ceive hypothetical female leaders as less effective than their performance is identical. erence for male leaders. Exposure to a female leader does not However, it perceived likely to among male know about villagers. alter villagers' taste pref- weakens stereotypes about gender and domestic spheres and eliminates the negative bias is male counterparts, when stated Female in how female roles in the public leaders' effectiveness villagers exhibit less prior bias, when exposed to them for the first, but not second, time. attitude are electorally meaningful: after 10 years of the quota policy, to stand for and win less or participate in local politics; as a result, their attitudes are largely unaffected. Consistent with our experimental findings, villagers rate their less effective but are also free seats in villages that women leaders as These changes women are more in likely have been continuously required to have a female chief councillor. RW.J Berkeley and Northwestern, IIM Calcutta, MIT, Harvard and IMF respectively. paper are those of the authors and do not implicate the International Monetary Fund, its management, or Executive Board. We thank Ash Center Harvard, Nike Foundation, MIT, YCIAS Yale, and UNICEF for funding, Alexandra Cirone, Catherine Lee and Kudzai Takavarasha for research assistance, and Prasid Chakraborly and the SRG team for outstanding fieldwork We also thank Abhijit Banerjee, Tim Besley, Shawn Cole, Dominic Leggett and numerous seminar participants for comments. "The authors are from The views expressed in this Introduction 1 women In July 2006, accounted for 17 percent of parliamentarians world-wide, and a headed the government in not reflect legal restrictions - every country. Rather, public office is many restricted (UNICEF, only seven countries women can vote, support candidates and run disparities for office in do almost suggest that in both rich and poor countries, women's access to by voter and party bias At the same time, such These gender 2007). woman bias, even if present, in favor of may be male politicians. malleable. For this reason, policy-makers often emphasize the importance of an initial cohort of female politicians and argue that once voters learn that women diminish. This has led to for women in public are no less effective than male politicians, gender bias in politics will more than a hundred office, either countries introducing affirmative action policies by law or through voluntary actions of 1 the last two decades (Krook, 2005; Dahlerup, 2006). While these political parties, over policies have significantly increased female representation in politics (Jones, 2004) and often altered subsequent policy- making (Chattopadhyay and Duflo, 2004; Powley, 2007), little is known about their impact on voter attitudes towards female leaders, despite the obvious importance of this question for evaluating the overall effectiveness of quotas. A large literature issues can cause ller, 1992; on public opinion formation suggests that low voter awareness on group stereotypes to play an important Huddy and stereotypes may A Terkildsen, 1993). hinder the entry of women associating leadership activities with men role in shaping voter preferences (Za- widely discussed reason that explains into politics is social specific why group norms which prescribe behavior (Akerlof and Kranton, 2000; Eagly and Karau, 2002). Holding leader effectiveness across genders constant, such norms can cause voters to favor, and elect, male candidates. Limited exposure to female leaders may, in turn, fuel biased perceptions of female leader effectiveness. While in many extent to which settings, exposure to members of another group creates "empathy," mandated exposure to women leaders can alter social norms the or perceptions details of quotas by country are available at http://www.quotaproject.org. Another rationale for affirmative is gender-specific policy preferences - if male and female leaders have different policy preferences, and female turnout is relatively low, then affirmative action can help ensure equal political voice for men and women. 2 For example Boisjoly et al. (2006) show that students who were randomly assigned to an African- American roommate in college are more likely to sympathize with African- Americans and affirmative action. action of women's ability is debated among academics and policymakers. Using international survey data, Ingelhart and Norris (2003) across countries. They argue document sex-biased attitudes towards roles in public life that these attitudes are difficult to change in the short run and quotas, by violating voters' sense of identity, may precipitate a backlash 2004). For instance, a quota-induced increase in female politicians (Rudman and may be Fairchild, perceived as reducing the value of a traditionally male activity (Goldin, 1990) and /or as restricting voters' choice (Thernstrom and Thernstrom, 1997). However, independent of their impact on voter leader, can tastes, quotas, by exposing voters to a female improve the precision of voters' information about the expected effectiveness of future female leaders. Quotas could, therefore, reduce statistical discrimination. Unless women make incompetent leaders (causing voters to update negatively), mandated exposure can improve the perception of a women leaders' effectiveness simply by reducing the risk associated with electing woman. 3 This paper provides direct evidence on these issues. To motivate our empirical analysis we first use a simple voting model to show how, in an electoral setting, future male candidates may systematically benefit from an initial voter preference for male leaders. Specifically, greater exposure to male leaders improves voter ability to screen male candidates and as a result, causes the expected effectiveness of male candidates to exceed that of their female counterparts if voters are risk averse. Statistical discrimination against female leaders will reinforce the initial and cause the stereotype that women make taste bias setting, political reservation, discrimination even when In general, measuring ficult. ineffective leaders to persist. by increasing voter exposure to female leaders, can reduce voter taste is leaders. To address statistical unaffected. how exposure changes voters' attitudes vis-a-vis women leaders Less biased voters are presumably also more likely to elect, and be exposed 4 In such a this concern, our empirical strategy exploits exposure to female leaders across village councils in the random variation in to, is dif- female mandated Indian state of West Bengal. Since 1998, one third of village council leader positions in this state have been randomly "reserved" 3 One work less 4 This reason is why quotas could lead to less competent female leaders is if, as in Coate and Loury (1993), they anticipation of voter perceptions that quotas lead to less competent politicians being elected. in true even with affirmative action, since in most countries even sentation of women, parties can still decide where to field women when a law requires mandated repre- candidates (Frechette, Maniquet, and Morelli). women for in each election; in reserved councils only women can run for the position of leader. This, combined with the passage of a significant period of time since the introduction of political reservation (two electoral cycles, or ten years) our empirical analysis. We compare makes West Bengal villager attitudes leaders across councils which have been reserved for villages an ideal setting women towards hypothetical, and actual, women Random once, twice, or never. for allo- cation of reservation implies that a difference in voter attitudes across reserved and unreserved mandated exposure. villages captures the causal effect of An important innovation of our study perimental data on voters' taste female leaders' effectiveness. plicit tastes are leaders, IAT is and We is the collection and use of detailed survey and ex- female leaders and their perceptions of gender roles and for examine explicit and implicit measures of voters' tastes. 5 Ex- captured by voters' stated feelings towards the general idea of male and female implicit tastes by taste Implicit Association Tests (IATs) (Nosek et an experimental method now widely used that respondents who more associate those concepts. easily pair Our taste in social two concepts IAT is in al., The 2007). psychology, which relies on the idea a rapid categorization task more strongly a computer-based double-categorization task which examines the strength of respondents' association between images of (anonymous) male and female leaders and normative categories of good and bad. To measure gender-occupation stereotypes we use an IAT which examines and leadership and domestic we asked the strength of association between male and female tasks. Finally, to examine voter perceptions of leader effectiveness villagers to evaluate the effectiveness of hypothetical female through vignettes and recorded speeches Clearly, our in which leader gender is and male leaders described experimentally manipulated. measures of "taste" and "perception of effectiveness" remain imperfect: a lager's perceptions of a potential leader's effectiveness may villager's general distaste for female leaders. the general "feeling" variables remain more That said, vil- influence his feelings towards the idea of male and female leaders; conversely, the performance rating of a leader by a names may be our maintained hypothesis colored is that closely correlated with deep-seated tastes while the specific "effectiveness" questions reflect voter perceptions of leader performance. In villages that have never experienced political reservation, villagers, particularly men, dislike the idea of female leaders. 5 On On a scale of 1 to 10, the average the use of such measures, see Charles and Guryan (2007); Bertrand et man al. rates his feeling towards (2005); Rooth (2007). female leaders in general one whole point below those for male leaders in general. show that men more are significantly IAT measures male leaders with notions of "good" likely to associate relative to female leaders. They The average male ranked the same speech and vignette describing a leader's decision villager 0.05 standard deviations lower also perceive female leaders as less effective when than male leaders. the leader's gender was experimentally manipulated to be female (relative to male). Female villagers' evaluation of hypothetical female leaders, while negative, is not statistically different from male villagers'. Mandated exposure to a female leader does not affect villagers' stated taste for male leaders. IAT show Neither the "feeling" rating of leaders nor the taste leaders in villages reserved for a female leader. and women with domestic leader effectiveness among male activities. villagers. In the increased approval of female However, among male villagers the stereotype (as measured by the occupation IAT) that activities less men it weakens are associated with leadership radically alters perceptions of female It also speech and vignette experiments, we find that male villagers who have been required to have a female leader consider hypothetical female and male leaders equally effective. This reduction in bias is absent provide evidence suggesting that a likely reason for this difference knowledge, and exposure to local politics, among female is villagers. We the lower levels of political among women. Consistent with the experimental data, we find that prior exposure improves villagers' evaluation of their actual leader along multiple dimensions. Specifically, in villages where the leadership position is reserved for the first time and only time in 2003, leader ratings by male villagers are where the leader position has never been reserved. Despite significantly lower relative to villages their less poor evaluation, we show that first time female leaders deliver more public goods and take bribes than their male counterparts. leaders in 2003. is The difference in ratings absent in villages where the leader position We do not find is reserved for prima facie evidence that female leaders between men and women in first for the women second time time reserved villages are differentially selected, or undertake different policies, than leaders elected in the second round of reservation. 6 Our results suggest that while The number of public goods provided by the second time does not significantly on average, and deep preferences and social norms are all women differ. first First difficult to erode, time female leaders and women leaders in councils reserved for and second time female leaders also have similar characteristics leaders are equally biased in favor of women in their policy actions. affirmative action and reduce programs can significantly improve perceptions of female leader effectiveness statistical discrimination against women in leadership positions. Finally, striking evidence that political reservation leads to significant electoral gains for medium-run. In the recently concluded many women stood for election chief councillor position to villages which The had rest of this and Section village council elections in May for women in women find in the 2008, almost twice as and won unreserved councillor positions had been reserved we in councils where the the previous two elections, compared either never been reserved or reserved only once. paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides a conceptual framework, 3 describes the data. Section 4 lays out the institutional context and our empirical and Section 6 concludes. strategy. Section 5 reports the results, Conceptual Framework 2 In most elections, voters We available candidates. and Cain, 1977) to make their choice while uncertain about the relative competence of the use a simple model of statistical discrimination (which follows Aigner may illustrate that voter uncertainty distaste for female leaders. The result is interact with an underlying voter that female candidates are, on average, not elected negatively biased beliefs about their effectiveness as leaders persist. Political reservation and can play an important role in reducing the bias in beliefs. Consider a single village council leadership election with the outcome determined by plurality rule. Candidates differ in competence, resolve disputes. Candidate We assume voters are and /"(.) < 0. i's competence risk averse Risk aversion is e.g. ability to given by is and value candidate with the resources a leader raises politicians for The aversion of whom 7?,, i's a standard assumption in the context of village council elections, risk aversion public resources he or she gets. extract state resources for the village and for the village An important is and a where 77, = r\ + e, and effectiveness as f(rji), many political very plausible if villager's utility implication of risk aversion e< ~ where iV(0, al). /'(.) > economy models. 7 In we equate competence is is concave in the total that voters penalize they lack information. typical spatial voting model, which uses a quadratic utility function, implies risk aversion in voting. Risk is also commonly invoked ambiguous candidates. to explain electoral outcomes such as split-ticket voting and the punishment Voter j's utility from candidate i Uij where m l is a male dummy defined as: is = f(m) + which equals one am + Uij, the candidate if can be interpreted as reflecting taste discrimination against women implement. Let Xi € M, F u> t j ~ N(Q, er^) ls an represent candidate i-i-d random male. is women ~ N{Q,<j* x ). men, and these can cause x and we only allow the variance rflx is given is rn + vlx sufficient This , where to cause are less competent than However, to focus on the possibility that risk aversion (of statistical discrimination reinforcing taste to suffer a "double penalty" of the signal to differ across genders. who maximizes Voters select the candidate women = 77^ across genders voters have prior beliefs that beliefs are self-fulfilling). women discrimination), if 0. voter and politician specific taste shock. mean In general, a difference in signal statistical discrimination (e.g. assume a > or a dislike for the policies each candidate's gender x, and a noisy signal of his/her competence: v ix We Before casting their vote, citizens observe gender. i's (1) their expected utility. The expectation of r/i given by E{r)i\rfix ,x) = - 77(1 7) + 7fo7 2 where 7 = -rf*?-- The error term e = in this equation E{r)i\m x ,Xi) -rji is: °tx + °n which has variance 2 2 + °ix (T„(7„ °f, The variance effectiveness, is is increasing in a„ x Since /(.) . is concave, E[f(r)i)\rfi X ,Xi], declining in the variance of the signal on ability. Consider the case where the signal on candidate of gender x relating observed characteristics to their competence: 8 This While an is the expected leader rflx = jix and actions Xj X x , where the for previously coefficients are is the prediction of a model observed leaders of gender x gender specific. 8 If the model a natural assumption, since men and women may differ in both their actions and characteristics. man may be an effective leader, being assertive may be a liability for a woman. assertive is estimated using Nx past leaders' observed actions, then the standard errors of standard deviation of the resulting prediction error of the signal for a gender will decrease in the will number decrease with (5X and the s/Nx Hence the variance . of elected candidates (of that gender). Taste discrimination, or a preference for the policies selected by men, will imply, for equal expected competence, higher voter will be elected only for her in little relative to the with a male leader (since basis to of the population. male candidate, the 2 <j vF will This creates a vicious because voters have a distaste for Political reservation increases Pf and women To summarize, unchanged by women if lead from a signal about the female circle women is leaders, risk averse voters will prefer - a female candidate leaders, male lower (and so their expected effectiveness is less likely to be elected both and because they are perceived as too risky. 10 Nf. This, in turn, improves the precision of voters' estimate competence across genders, reservation the effectiveness of women In other words, reduces the variance of expected competence of future female leaders. similar levels of is sufficiently favorable 2 be very high, compared to o vM ? This causes statistical candidates as the variance of their ability signal of is Female candidates Therefore, voters will see very few ability to extract information discrimination: aside from any distaste for higher). 0). form a prediction of female politician effectiveness. candidate will be weak and is a > the few cases where the idiosyncratic taste shock among a majority and have utility will Hence, for improve the relative evaluation of leaders. the pool of female candidates (and their investment in job-specific skills) political reservation, then: Political Reservation and Taste Discrimination: Taste discrimination, as captured by a greater preference for male leaders (relative to female leaders), will be unchanged with political reservation. Political Reservation With and Statistical Discrimination: Holding competence constant across a positive cost of running, presumably very few women will choose to run which will accentuate the signal-extraction problem for female candidates. 10 The voter's decision problem resembles the classic two-armed bandit problem (Bergemann and Valmiki, 2008). The two arms are the male and female candidate pools, with unknown variance with respect to competence. Voters get new information on the distribution of competence within a gender only if they select a candidate from that gender. Since the observations the voter uses to gain information and reduce the variance of the signal are also his terms of selecting a leader), he must strike a balance between gaining rewards and gaining information. voter will combine information on the mean with beliefs about the variance of payoffs to maximize the present discounted value of his payoff. He will favor exploiting information (i.e. choose the male candidate arm) if he is sufficiently risk averse, faces a finite time horizon or has a sufficiently high discount rate. reward (in The median genders, political reservation will reduce statistical discrimination as measured by the difference in the evaluation of female and male leader effectiveness. The literature on affirmative action has identified our model. First, leaders, then political reservation if two additional which competent female candidates may respond either by under-investing predicted decline in statistical discrimination. Second, voting choices constrained then political reservation in taste discrimination against The purpose of our model if may effect, if present, Our empirical (Coate cause a backlash and lead to an increase risk averse. 1997). As mentioned similar predictions regarding the efficacy of political reservation is in skills would reduce the is a natural by- earlier, we obtain very to illustrate that statistical discrimination product of taste discrimination when voters are of statistical discrimination outside voters react negatively to having their women (Thernstrom and Thernstrom, is lie worsens voters' prior about the competence of -women and Loury, 1993), or by simply choosing not to stand. This if we assumed that the source biased voter priors about average female leader effectiveness. 11 analysis will not try to disentangle different forms of statistical discrimination. The remainder of this paper uses detailed data on voter attitudes to test these about the implications of 3 forces, political reservation. two predictions Below, we start by describing our data. Data Our data comes from West Bengal, a middle-income Indian (Gram Panchayats, from now on, GP) have been an effective Between June 2006 and November 2007 we surveyed 495 Birbhum village district in we West Bengal (we randomly collected data on the quantity state, where elected body of governance since 1978. villages spread across the 165 selected three villages per and quality village councils of public GPs in GP). In each surveyed good provision, and administered household and individual surveys to a random sample of 15 households. These surveys, together with Implicit Association Tests (IATs), form the main sources of our voter attitude measures. about average competence can exist, for example, if voters conclude that the lower and wealth among female leaders (relative to male leaders) reflect lower effectiveness. 'initial biased beliefs of education levels Measures of Voter Taste 3.1 We measure voters' taste by their explicit as expressed in survey responses households per 5 To village. and in and IATs. implicit feelings towards We leader, a "Feeling of 12 to 10, 1 random sample collected these data for a ascertain respondents' explicit taste for male which has steps from male and female leaders how do you male leader, a female villager feel and female about a and a male Thermometer" which has been widely used leaders, X where [X]" we asked "on a ladder was (separately) a female This question villager. is adapted from the in the political science literature to produce rank-orderings of parties and candidates (Keller and Mirer, 1974) and to measure partisan affiliation (Alvarez, 1990; We IAT is complement the Weisberg, 1980). explicit taste measures with taste IATs (Greenwald et al., 1998). a computerized test which aims to measure attitudes of which respondents explicitly cognizant. Over the last ten years IATs have been widely used (Nosek et may al., An not be 2007) in various subfields in psychology, neuroscience, market research and, recently, economics. 13 To measure implicit bias, an of the association IAT uses a double-categorization task to measure the strength between two concepts. Words from two different series Consider the case where the two series are a series of male and female of good or bad adjectives. The respondent completes two appear on the screen. first test blocks. names and a series In the "stereotypical" block male names and good attributes are clubbed together on one side of the computer screen (say, left side) or seeing a prompt, the respondent has to assign it example given, a male name should be assigned to the a bad attribute to the right (and a this association (i.e. attributes on the hearing to the correct side of the screen. In the In each household good one to the left left). The assumption left). easier. An is side (right side). (and a female The males names and bad attributes on the makes the sorting task l2 On and female names and bad attributes on the other name to the right) and "non-stereotypical" block reverses right, and female names and good that a stronger association between two concepts automatic association can be detected by comparing the we conducted IATs with adults aged between 15 and 45. We targeted at least one respondent IAT respondents from 1,968 households. We do not use IATs from the seventy-seven GPs. As our feeling questions were not affected by piloting, we include per gender in a household, and have 4,378 one pilot village in each of these villages for feelings data giving us 7,182 survey responses across 2,926 households. 13 Rooth (2007) shows that the D-measure for racial bias of Swedish employers correlates positively with the rate at which they call back applicants of different races. Also see Bertrand et al. (2005). response time across the stereotypical and non-stereotypical block. mean response time between ineasure: the normalized difference in "stereotypical" test blocks (Greenwald et al., 2003). IAT bias is given by the D- the "non-stereotypical" and A higher value of the D-measure indicates to implement IATs a stronger implicit stereotype. To the we best of our knowledge, are the first in a field setting in a low income country. Our IATs used either audio or pictorial prompts and, therefore, did not assume literacy or familiarity with computers (Appendix Figure a picture of a participant playing the game. The Appendix lists 1 shows an IAT screen and the set of prompts). 14 to exploit variation in respondent exposure to female leaders to second innovation is the malleability of IAT bias. We Our examine are only aware of one other field study which investigates this question (see Section 3.2). We administered two taste IATs; such IATs have been widely used to measure group prejudice The (Banaji, 2001). good (e.g nice first assesses the associational strength and delicious) and bad (e.g. between male and female names and nasty and horrible) attributes. The second measures the association between these attributes and images of male and female politicians (e.g pictures of either men places male names 3.2 or women names giving speeches or leading crowds). In both cases the stereotypical block or leader pictures or leader pictures and Measure Our model and good attributes on one bad attributes on the other side. unlikely to reduce taste discrimination. Instead, is that the main channel by which reservation influences voter beliefs information on prospective women would be a greater association To examine changes in the of leaders. women A is enhanced natural consequence of the increase in information with leadership activities. gender stereotyping of occupations we administered an activity- based IAT. The IAT assesses whether villagers exposed to reservation are women and female of Leadership Stereotype suggests that political reservation we hypothesize side of the screen, with domestic activities and men with leadership activities. less likely to associate Specifically, it examines 14 Similar IATs have been used for children (Baron. and Banaji, 2006). Wc excluded respondents with an average response time of over 6 seconds in the first test block or less than 65% average correct responses. We dropped all responses for which the respondent took more than 10 seconds to categorize any prompt. ordering of stereotypical and non-stereotypical blocks across respondents. 10 We randomized the the association between male and female names and domestic and leadership rice) (e.g. governing towards associating women which were equally likely to activities. sleeping and eating puffed To avoid loading the results with domestic activity, we chose gender neutral domestic activities be performed by Unlike the taste IATs, this of and public speaking) (e.g. IAT does not capture a value judgement. Rather, IAT to more strongly with family than with it is informative men and women as potential leaders. Rudman and show that respondents in the U.S. associate female names whether the respondent considers both Kilianski (2000) use such an men and women. career. There is also some evidence that responses to occu- pation IATs are influenced by the environment. Dasgupta and Asgari (2004) administered this IAT to American college students of female professors were more and found that students likely to associate women in colleges with a higher proportion with professional activities. endogenous selection into college makes a causal interpretation of these results However, difficult. Measures of Leader Effectiveness 3.3 To measure bias in voter perception of leader effectiveness, we administered speech and vignette experiments of the "Goldberg paradigm" type (Goldberg, 1968). Such experiments, which ran- domly vary the gender of the protagonist, have been widely used to assess bias in the perception of the effectiveness of women as leaders (Matland, 1994; and Karau, 2002)). Our experiments were administered prime-aged male and female respondent we conducted in 15 Huddy and Terkildsen, 1993; Eagly as part of a longer survey given to a randomly selected households per village. Overall, 6,717 male and 6,780 female adult surveys. In the speech experiment the respondent heard a short tape-recorded leader speech which was adapted from an actual village of six speech recordings (three village council leader in a village to a villager complaint and meeting speech. Respondents were randomly assigned one male and three female) and told that meeting in another this was a speech by a district. In the speech, the leader responds about a broken tube-well by requesting effort for local public goods. 15 villagers to contribute money After hearing the speech the respondent was asked seven questions on different aspects of the leader's perceived performance and overall effectiveness, such as 5 A "How would you rank literal translation is the effectiveness of the Pradhan on a scale of included in the Appendix. 11 1 to 10?" and "Do you think the Pradhan be successful will in getting resources to the village by lobbying?". did not include any questions on whether the villager sympathized with the leader; rather, We all questions were about evaluating the leader's action and his or her effectiveness. Each respondent also heard a randomly selected "vignette "in which a situation of resource was described and the leader decided whether to invest scarcity irrigation project. in a drinking water or an Vignettes varied along two dimensions: the leader's choice and the leader's gender. At the conclusion of the vignette, respondents were asked to evaluate the leader using four questions, similar to those asked after the speech. The leader's gender was randomly varied across respondents such that a respondent was exposed to the same leader gender lagers' responses across the speech in the speech and vignette. This allows us to combine and vignette and ask whether, holding actual action constant, on average, rank female leaders below male villagers, Finally, we asked leaders. villagers to evaluate their actual leader's effectiveness sions (using a ladder-based scale of 1 to 10). 3.4 on multiple dimen- Questions included "Do you think the Pradhan has done a good job looking after the needs of your village?" and effectiveness of the current vil- "How would you rank the Pradhan?" Discussion Clearly, neither our "taste" nor "perception of effectiveness" measure counterpart to the corresponding parameter in the model. Voters is a perfect empirical may be more likely to associate female leaders with bad adjectives in general because they consider them incompetent. Equally, villagers may deem a woman leader giving the speech ineffective because they want to punish her for violating norms of prescribed behavior. In other words, akin to the utility function posit, our measures may we capture both voter taste and perception of effectiveness. However, as long as the relative weights of taste and statistical discrimination vary across these measures expect our taste measures to be, on average, less affected effectiveness measures. 12 we by reservation than our perception of Institutional Context 4 As a background and Empirical Strategy for the empirical analysis, we describe political reservation in West Bengal and our empirical strategy. The Panchayat System and 4.1 Political Reservation many prominent India has had universal franchise since Independence, as well as including a prime-minister and now its first female leaders, female President. However, the share of national and state legislatures averages only 10 percent. An women in important policy response was the 1993 constitutional amendment which, while mandating a three-tier elected local self-government institution in every Indian state, the Panchayat, required reservations, or quotas, for all three villages, tiers. This policy has led to a dramatic and the number of is now In each Indian state, the Panchayat consists of a system of village (Panchayat Samiti), and Gram council, district (Zilla Panchayat, which buildings, water, roads, etc.) The main Unlike source of financing for many Indian its activities is The GP is in this state active elected Panchayat since 1978. West Bengal Panchayat model. five years. council decision-making veto power, he or she is is These councillors the only full-time states, typical Gram is elect (from directly elected from each among ward the set of councillors) a by majority voting. While the Pradhan does not have formal member al., on Pradhans. some other Indian The and a vice-chief councillor, Upa-Pradhan. control over the final council decisions (Besley et In In fact, the 1993 has an electorate of roughly 10,000 spread across multiple villages. chief village councillor, Pradhan, GP focuses on the village the State government. divided into electoral wards, and a ward councillor by plurality rule every Our study states which introduced Panchayats only after the 1993 constitutional was, in part, based on the Panchayat (GP) (Gram Panchayat), block targeted welfare recipients within the villages. for identifying amendment, West Bengal has had an amendment close to 40 percent. responsible for the provision of village infrastructure (public is and Parishad) councils. in female leadership across Indian rise in local female elected leaders village-level women Pradhan elections are direct. L3 of the council and exercises significant 2007). In our analysis we, therefore, focus The in amendment constitutional each council be reserved be reserved for women. 1993 required that one third of ward councillor positions women. And in each district, one third of the Pradhan positions In other words, at each election a third of identified as "reserved" for Each Indian for in women: only women can be GPs in every district are Pradhan elected as in these GPs. 17 state separately decided the rules for implementing political reservation. West Bengal the Panchayat Constitution Rule was modified the positions of ward councillors and Pradhans for in women and In 1998 to introduce reservation for for two disadvantaged minorities, Scheduled Castes (SC) and Scheduled Tribes (ST) (Government of West Bengal, 1998). At the time our data was collected, two elections had been conducted with reservation: 2003. In Section 6 we discuss the results of the third election, held in May 1998 and in 2008. In the case of Pradhans, the West Bengal electoral rules state that, prior to an election, in a district should be randomly assigned to three and tables provided These lists GP GP elections. In each starting with starting with using (the GP Reserved in the electoral law): for serial number number 2 1 GPs list on each on each numbers and same was true reserved for list list was reserved was reserved. women. Second, ST, and Unreserved. 18 features on the SC or ST list for for a woman, and We reconstructed in 2003 every third the 2003 reservation list Chattopadhyay and Duflo, 2004). there (since GP for and found that the rule held, with no exception electoral law tables in 1998, see and administrative block list SC, Reserved number rank are ordered by their serial numbers. In 1998, every This assignment rule has three consequences. may be (on the basis of their serial are redone at every election to ensure that no two consecutive third lists GPs GP is First, there is implicit stratification of numbers serial reserved twice in a row - for instance, random assignment women randomization by start with a block identifier). if it was first on a to being list in 19 SC/ST Third, a GP 1998 but second on a in 2003. Figure 1 shows the patterns in GP reservation in our study district of Birbhum. ''Electoral gender quotas usually require that women Of the 56 constitute a certain percentage of either party candidate These quotas are typically constitutionally mandated (as in Burkina Faso, Nepal, Philippines and Uganda), mandated by electoral law (as in many parts of Latin America, Belgium, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia and Sudan) or imposed by political parties (as in Argentina, Bolivia, Ecuador, Germany, Italy, Norway and Sweden). A growing concern that requirements on candidate lists may not increase actual female representation in politics has led a number of countries (such as Jordan, Uganda and lists or the elected body, such as the legislature. Rwanda) to introduce gender quotas using political reservation, similar to the Indian system. 18 The extent of reservation for SC and ST in a district is proportional to their population share. 19 A block is the administrative unit below the district. 14 GPs the reserved in 1998, 20 were also reserved in the 2003 election. Thirty five were reserved for Pradhans Birbhum at the in 2003 and 74 GPs reserved for time first in is GPs had women never been reserved at the time of the survey. and the are female, overall fraction of female GP 43 percent (due to political disturbances one reserved Pradhans did not have a in Pradhan time of our survey). GPs In non-reserved few women are elected, but this number has increased over The facie the increase appears to be unrelated to the reservation policy. GPs elected in 2003 from of All the women Pradhans In Table 1 that were only reserved in 1998 (14%) elected from never reserved we use 1991 census data GPs First Reserved 2003 in 1998, Prima fraction of women comparable to the fraction 2003 (16%). to check for systematic differences between villages in our sample, based on the reservation status of the Reserved in is time. GP and Reserved they belong in to: Never Reserved, Only As expected given 1998 and 2003. the randomization, the village characteristics as of 1991 do not jointly predict the reservation assignment of GPs level or less) differences 6, having a hand (6)). Our There are in the local elections. statistically significant (at the 10 percent according to reservation status in only three variables (sex ratio under pump and having a permanent approach road, see p- values in columns (5) and regressions include controls for these three variables (the regression results are not sensitive to their inclusion). Empirical Strategy 4.2 As explained above, the sample has four types of GPs: First Reserved 2003, Reserved 1998 and 2003, Only Reserved 1998, and Never Reserved. Randomization allows us to study GPs its reduced form effect by comparing the means of outcomes of interest across with different reservation status. Since reserved GPs, but relatively few unreserved and all previously reserved GPs, have a female Pradhan (Figure what would be obtained by instrumenting GP. We, The out, therefore, focus for on the reduced form unit of observation in our regressions we report separate results for of reservation assignment reduced form 1), this effect is close to Pradhan's gender by the reservation status of the results. is villager male and female the regression specification differs across these. 15 i in villagers. The GP We first set g situated in block b. Through- have two sets of outcomes, and of outcomes are common across ' respondents, and include the difference in a villager's feelings towards male versus female leadthe ers, IAT D-measures, and The specifications. first we report two evaluations of the Pradhans. For these outcomes simply compares outcomes of interest across ever reserved GPs and never reserved GPs, = y ig where Rg is an indicator variable ever reserved). The second Vig Rg is i an indicator for the first GP the time + GP for the + ab + Xig-y e ig GP (2) being currently or previously reserved (now on, separates reserved and unreserved = @2Rg2 + for the (3R g fcandl Rg2andl + PlRgl GPs + Xigl + only being reserved in 1998 and further: "6 Rg 2 2003 (during the second round of reservation). in + (3) fyg for the Rg 2 an di GP ' s being reserved an indicator for being reserved in both 1998 and 2003. Standard errors are always clustered by GP. All regressions include block fixed effects ucation, caste, religion, household size principal component analysis. We (aj,) and proxies and demographic controls (Xig ): age, for ed- household wealth constructed using a also include investigator gender fixed effects, a survey period hand-pumps and presence of outcomes consists of the vignette and speech responses. As described in indicator and three village controls (under 6 sex ratio, presence of approach road). Our second set of Section 3.3, each respondent received a vignette about a Pradhan and heard a Pradhan speech in a male or female voice. are interested in whether The gender of the Pradhan was randomized across respondents. male and female Pradhans are judged difference varies with reservation status of the presented with a "female" stimulus vignette with a female leader). y, g We (i.e. differently, We and whether the GP. Let Fi g indicate whether respondent i was heard the speech in a female voice, or was given the estimate: = 5Fig + X(Rg * Fig + \iRg + X ig j + ) 16 ab + e ig (4) F and Vxg = SFig + A 2 (-Rg 2 * Fig + A 2and {Rg 2and\ ) i * ig ) + \\ {Rg \ * Fjg) + y^ R k fj. k + X ig ~j + a b + e lg , (5) k Rk the indicator variables main control for the effect of different reservation categories. In equation (4) the coefficients of interest are S which captures bias towards female leaders in unreserved GPs, and A which indicates whether current or past exposure to a female leader changes the level of bias. In equation we (5), are interested in A 2 On many we ask respondents multiple issues of interest outcomes we expect the on the variables of coefficients Ai, and how they outcomes within a "family" (Kling et al., 2007). standard deviation in the never reserved sample. outcomes by estimating the To summarize, our the reservation we for We never reserved direction. To outcome we construct a GPs and dividing by the on the average across these normalized outcomes. 20 effect from estimating either equation estimating equation (3) or equation family" of obtain an average effect for the "family" tables report two sets of regressions. Panel dummy same " report effects which average across Specifically, for each normalized transformation by subtracting the mean Within a questions. interest to go in the avoid drawing inferences based on selected outcomes, (5). level of bias for the relevant attitude 5 and from each other. differ of A2 an di , The second (2) or to last row A reports the coefficients on equation in measure (usually the mean (4), and Panel B from each table reports the baseline for the unreserved sample). Results Do 5.1 Our model Villagers Know of voter behavior Their Leader? is based on the premise that villagers are aware of local politics and are able to gather information about leader providing evidence on this in Table villagers exhibit relatively high levels of As Kling et al. (2007), We start our empirical analysis by 2. Male in actions. we obtain very knowledge and involvement similar results if seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) system, where we account we estimate the standardized effects using a for correlation across outcomes and average across outcomes to obtain an average effect for the "family" of outcomes. 17 in local politics. However, we observe a significant gender gap limited exposure. row to last in women showing much more every measure, with Table 2 provides the means of variables measuring awareness and activism in the sample of never reserved GPs. political male, but only 33% gender gap exists 13% The second in 53% 67% of simila.r-sized of the male, but only having ever approached the Pradhan about their needs or village of female, villagers state and A Pradhan's name. their current previous Pradhans (columns (l)-(4)). Further, for issues (columns (5) know of female, villagers In these GPs, A (6)). large majority of men have heard of the village meeting, even though a minority has actually attended one (76% and 34%, respectively, see columns (7) and (9)). In contrast, only A Panel Panel we of the have heard of the meetings and only Table 2 shows the coefficient on the "ever reserved" variable in the coefficients on the reservation variables in equation name. For example, men are 11-12.5% GP is Pradhan GP the if effect of reservation seriously), or female male know That villagers said, know equation (2), and in (1) through (6) Pradhans and to know name the have attended. the of their name Pradhan if of the previous was previously reserved. eral possible interpretations: thority. less likely to 7% columns (3). In currently reserved, and between 10-14% less likely to This negative 5.2 women see that both genders are less likely to have interacted with female their the B 56% it may on villagers' interactions reflect discrimination (villagers Pradhans may be their do not take female leaders less proactive, or less likely to an important point from Table 2 know who with the village leaders has sev- Pradhan is, that even in reserved is and have, be a trusted village au- at some point, seen GPs him a majority of or her. Preference for Male Leaders In Table 3 we examine differences in villagers' general feelings towards As a reminder, we measure an villager's general rating of explicit preference for scale). preference for male leaders by the D-measure in the taste IAT. IAT leaders. male leaders by the difference between a male and female Pradhans (on a 1-10 ranking of leaders, we also report the rating and male and female results for We measure an implicit To benchmark respondents' respondent preferences for male versus female villagers. The second Villagers in to last Birbhum row of Table 3 presents summary statistics for never reserved GPs. are not shy about admitting explicit preferences for males. In columns (1) 18 and (2) we exhibit a bias is see that much men rank male villagers 0.69 points higher smaller, but significant, bias in favor of male magnified in the case of leaders (columns (3) and (4)). than female Women For both genders, this villagers. Male villagers. male leaders villagers rate 1.44 points higher than female leaders. For female villagers the difference, while smaller (0.56), remains significant. This distaste for female leaders "ever reserved" (Panel A, column is not ameliorated by exposure. is (3)) positive (0.22) and significant for ing that their relative preference for male leaders GPs which have in Columns attributes." These strengthened and leader taste IATs. Both demonstrate among male and female Neither is villagers. Men are significantly results are discouraging of the view that affirmative action can, in the short to Our evidence differs when respondents possible explanation that social norms that rural India. The more affected by reservation. tends to be muted even is finding that men are from that of quota system which forces them to women more biased elect rich countries where exhibit strong implicit bias (Bertrand et their implicit preferences are unaffected. explicit bias al., 2005). A once reserved GPs, but only as measured in women by medium should not be leaders are deep-rooted in That explicit attitudes, supports the "backlash" hypothesis. though is good with male names while women associate female names with positive run, alter voter preferences. by villagers, suggest- experienced a gender quota. a strong same gender preference 1 male (compared to female leaders) (5)-(8) report findings for the villager likely to associate Rather, the coefficient of is, men protest against the stating a dislike for female leaders, even The fact that this effect is strongest in GPs that were only reserved once (Panel B, see coefficient on reservation in 1998 or in 2003) leaves open the Section possibility that villagers get used to quotas over time. This possibility norms which militate against female leadership, ences, could also explain consistent results across explicit combined with same-gender and implicit attitudes not female, villagers. Specifically, women's explicit attitudes ognize that ranking female leaders below male leaders same sex preference on the part of men "women are wonderful" attributes (Eagly and Mladinic, 1989). Our discussed in 5.5. Social 21 is finding of countries, where these tests exhibit a 19 is may reflect for prefer- male, but the fact that they rec- prescribed behavior, even though they differs effect from what is typically found in developed - and everyone associates women with good female leaders (and this like is captured by their implicit two taste IATs Finally, the very similar results across the may villagers beliefs). have, in both cases, mostly perceived the gender of the character and did not associate pictures of female leaders with leadership. In that sense, IAT may have both genders suggests that for failed to sufficiently we recognize that the second capture a "leadership" dimension. Gender-Occupation Stereotypes 5.3 Our results suggest that reservation has not significantly altered voters' taste for female leaders. In Table 4 lead. We we examine whether it use an occupation-based leadership activities with has made them more aware IAT which men and domestic tests whether activities of the possibility that villagers are more GPs. Specifically, with women. women respondents are faster at associating leadership actions (on average, deviation faster). men IAT suggests in leadership activities in never reserved women with domestic activities than with are 0.1 standard deviation faster, Exposure to a female leader can likely to associate In contrast to the same-sex preference observed in taste IATs, the occupation that both genders exhibit significant bias against women and women 0.15 standard significantly reduces this association for men. This suggests that reservation-induced exposure lowered the strength of the stereotype linking men with leadership activities, at least among male can lead. To the best of our knowledge, this the is villagers first who may have learned that study that identifies a causal women effect of a policy on implicit beliefs, as measured by an IAT. Overall exposure does not reduce stereotyping women and a strengthening of the stereotype associating exposed to a female Pradhan for the first among women. time in 2003. If anything, Panel B shows domestic activities among Section 5.6 provides a women somewhat speculative explanation for this result. These results suggest a more nuanced view While reservation does not make male it villagers makes them recognize that women can updated their perception of the lead. competence .of of how political reservation affects attitudes. more sympathetic to the idea of female leaders, This opens up the possibility that they women 20 leaders, which is what we turn may have to now. Perceptions of Effectiveness 5.4 Hypothetical Leaders 5.4.1 Table 5 examines villagers' evaluation of the actions performed by hypothetical Pradhans as A described in the tape-recorded Pradhan speech or in a vignette. a Pradhan of the same gender in respondent was exposed to the speech and the vignette and asked multiple questions on the perceived effectiveness of the Pradhan. columns In variable (1) and we report the coefficients from regressions in which the dependent the average of the normalized outcomes across is A we In Panel vignette. (2) see that men in all questions in the speech and the never reserved villages rate the effectiveness of a hypothetical female Pradhan 0.055 standard deviation below that of a male Pradhan (with a standard error of 0.027). While lower and insignificant of 0.031), we cannot reject the hypothesis that for women (0.035, with a standard error both genders are equally biased. Reservation alters male evaluations: the coefficient on the interaction between female Prad- han and ever reserved Pradhan and is 0.096 and is strongly significant. Adding the Panel B, we see a similar impact of reservation across are positive, with similar-sized, and all is not strongly significant). In reservation categories: some sufficient to erase statistical discrimination against female leaders. persists even after the woman has all statistically indistinguishable, point estimates. are striking in that they suggest that for male villagers exposure, at is on female interaction with reservation suggests that political reservation completely erases, its indeed reverses, this bias (though the resulting pro-female bias leader coefficients left, office. coefficients The results point, to a female Moreover, this effect In contrast, reservation has no impact on leadership evaluation of female villagers. Columns (3)-(10) consider different subsets of the effectiveness questions that enter the over- all assessment. 22 The results are in never reserved GPs evaluate the hypothetical female Pradhan more negatively than her male counterparts. This bias the case of Why 22 They for all women are are is absent in GPs which have been villagers, reservation has women's evaluations still remarkably consistent across outcomes. reserved at On each outcome some point men in time. In no impact. of the effectiveness of female leaders unaffected by reservation? averaged across the speech and vignette questions. Appendix Table Al reports results separately speech and vignette questions. 2] One possibility much the is lower exposure of female villagers to local politics (see Ta-ble 2). For the presence of female leaders to alter an individual's perception of their competence, she needs to have observed them it is in action. If women unaware are largely of local politics then unsurprising that reservation docs not affect their evaluations. Table 6 provides evidence which supports this hypothesis. We use the average of the responses to the speech and vignette questions as the relevant outcome variable. We expand our set of explanatory variables to include the interaction of the reservation effect with whether the villager knows the current or previous Pradhan's name. Columns that even among men OLS (l)-(3) present the the effect results. driven by those is The who know estimates, while noisy, suggest the Pradhan. concern of reverse causality columns (4)-(6) report IV regressions. a villager knows the Pradhan's proximity to the Pradhan (reads the newspaper, name with (lives in knows the name woman of legislator and has heard on this is leader in action. Our still women Section if 6). how social The IV noisily estimated). even if it women least leaders are less effective among men. This updating suggests that does not change voter preferences, alter the future electoral voters place enough weight on leader competence (we provide evidence And even if electoral outcomes are unchanged, enhance voter welfare by improving the information available to The speech and of village meetings). results suggest a relatively rapid about women's effectiveness as leaders, at political reservation can, fortunes of and vignette results are consistent with the predictions of a model of statistical have seen a of voter beliefs whether for the same village, has the same caste) and political knowledge discrimination in which villagers update their initial prior that after they instrument a set of variables indicating geographic estimates are significantly larger for both genders (though The speech and We To address the political reservation can villagers. vignette experiments allow us to measure bias but may not perfectly predict reservation influences leader evaluation in situations where the information available about leaders may 5.4.2 Actual Leaders differ with their gender. Our survey asked each respondent ferent dimensions using the experiments. The same We now directly examine this. to evaluate their actual Pradhan's 1 to 10 ladder which was used performance on four for the vignette dif- and speech questions were purposefully chosen to be similar to those asked about the 22 hypothetical Pradhan in the speech and vignette. In Table 7 question. In we report both the average outcome all Pradhan cases villagers evaluate their reserved in 2003. Column row shows that Pradhans (1) in for the four questions that are first reserved for a for shows a negative, but smaller and effective The in male respondents. The first is in strongly significant. never reserved is GPs standard analogous to the speech and vignette results, considered hypothetical female Pradhans less coefficients of interest are very similar across individual in GPs first (BPL) program outcomes (columns and in preparing the list of "below the poverty line" beneficiaries. However, consistent with the experimental data, the second row villagers' evaluation of female from that of Pradhans in Pradhans level. in twice reserved unreserved GPs, equality between the coefficient of the percent (3)-(10)). reserved in 2003 are ranked lower on general effectiveness, ability to look after village or respondent needs, for "first women GPs is in Table 7 shows that statistically indistinguishable both men and women. For men, we can reject the reserved" and "reserved in 1998 and 2003" at the For women, the coefficients do not cannot reject that 3 Column than their male counterparts. Female Pradhans 1 2003 score 0.2 standard insignificant, effect for female villagers (-0.07 deviation with a standard error of 0.06). 23 This where (male) respondents first woman deviations less than Pradhans in unreserved GPs; this coefficient (2) GPs as significantly less effective in examines the average outcome GPs and separately for each differ; this, in part, reflects the fact that we did not, rate their female leaders lower than male leaders. Finally, row shows that the current (mostly male) leaders in GPs that were previously reserved in 1998 are evaluated at par with leaders from never reserved GPs. These results are consistent with the view that exposure to a female leader causes villagers to update their prior on average female effectiveness. The first cohort of women leaders fails to benefit from this updating, potentially because voters "stick" with their assessment of a specific leader (Mullainathan and Washington, 2009). In contrast, the second cohort of female leaders does not appear to suffer from statistical discrimination. Needless to is that, unlike the hypothetical leaders in the speech are an important caveat and vignette, male Pradhans and second These results echo Duflo and Topalova (2004) who, using nation-wide data more dissatisfied with female leaders in general (also see Duflo, 2005) 23 say, for India, showed that villagers may be time female Pradhans Women Are First-time we In Table 8 is Pradhans While public goods, the average all in GPs first reserved in 2003 are statistically indistinguishable GPs of repairs or constructions since in column more from the effective effect in GPs (column than Pradhans GPs first (1)). If from GPs last anything, in never reserved GPs. 24 reserved in 2003, the effect in is that women Pradhans we do not (2) any see invest in more, but lower quality, public goods. significant differences in the quality of public provision across currently reserved, previously reserved or twice reserved GPs. performance of the smaller and insignificant (0.04, with standard error of 0.06). is second possibility However, number 0.19 standard deviations higher in villages in reserved twice reserved A Leaders Less Effective? present evidence that, prima facie, male Pradhans do not outperform female Pradhans. Across election better leaders than first-time female Pradhans. women elected in first-time reserved GPs is good Once again, the indistinguishable from women elected reserved for the second time. Since public goods are mainly financed by State Government funds, the contrast between villagers' (especially Pradhans seem by men in which male) negative evaluation of female Pradhans and the fact that female to invest more, with no discernible reduction in quality, is unlikely to be explained resenting a "big government" approach. There are, however, (at least) two other ways villagers may have to pay for these goods: voluntary contributions and bribes. In our household survey we can identify whether the household paid a bribe to receive a and whether the household paid bribes and made voluntary contributions provision. In likely to column (3) we see that on average, individuals have paid a bribe. 25 Further, in columns and (4) (5) we observe very in different reservation categories. all card drinking water in currently reserved self-reported villager satisfaction with public goods (we average across GPs for BPL GPs are less similar levels of public goods) across 26 24 This result is broadly consistent, with Munshi and Rosenzweig (2008) 's finding that in non-caste dominant GPs, women leaders demonstrate higher competence as measured by public good provision using nationally representative data. 5 26 This The effect is driven by BPL card; there is no difference in payments for water maintenance, results are very similar for individual satisfaction measures, except the unsatisfied with the way female BPL list. Men, in particular, are BPL quota implies that there leaders allocate them. However, the existence of a no way to allocate BPL cards to please everyone (our satisfaction results differ from Duflo and Topalova (2004): an Indian-wide data set they found that, on average, villagers were less likely to be satisfied with public good provision when women were in charge. is in 24 The evidence women suggests that leaders provide While we may have a lower effective price. performance, the weight of the evidence failed to more public goods, measure some critical of equal quality, at aspect of Pradhan consistent with our experimental findings. is villagers rate female leaders in villages reserved for the first time That is, more negatively even though they perform at least as well as the average male Pradhan. This bias disappears for the second cohort of women. we examine whether female Finally, ences. This men motivated by the fact that is We Appendix Table A2). (see leaders' decisions are biased women towards women's prefer- leaders invest in different types of goods than Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004) and use the follow differ- ence in male and female villagers' complaints in public meetings to construct a measure of female Column preferences. first (6) shows that female leaders invest more pass, this suggests an alternative explanation for in women-preferred goods. At both the apparent taste discrimination against female leaders and the observed backlash in male preferences for female leaders in Table 3. However, Pradhans this explanation in first and second reserved was particularly strong To for square with the fact that the policy choices of female difficult to is GPs GPs are equally pro-woman, reserved only once (Table further investigate possible differences in Pradhan while the "backlash" effect 3). selection across first time and second time reserved GPs, we compare salient leader characteristics by reservation status 9. Male and female leaders come from in women are younger, less educated, and are landless and less wealthy households. demographics between time reserved reserved differ: GPs GPs are women more leaders in first likely to However, we see little for the first time in 2003 than (23 percentage points, significant at the 8 percent level). in experience in serving as Pradhan, as seen in Table 8, Table likely to systematic differences and second time reserved GPs. be Pradhan more in That Women women in first in twice said, this difference does not translate into differential public goods provision. Moreover, their average political experience, which includes experience in political positions In ones. 7 other than council president, does not differ significantly. summary, the evaluation of the actual Pradhan The This is first time men are exposed to a female somewhat, surprising since one different types of women) once they Surprisingly, this is may closely mirrors that of the hypothetical Pradhan (either real or hypothetical), they expect, parties to field different candidates (or voters to select realize that female leader's decisions reflect the policy preferences of also true for previously (but not currently) reserved 25 GPs. women. women, while similar, are attenuated the first and While we can not insignificant. performance differences underlie men's possibility that The This difference disappears the second time around. consider her ineffective. dislike for time and their favorable evaluation of Pradhans elected Pradhans GPs in effects for fully rule in GPs out the reserved for reserved for the second time, the consistency between these two sets of results strongly points to the possibility that exposure to female leaders reduced bias. Robustness Checks and Alternative Explanations 5.5 we conduct a number In Table 10 of robustness checks to examine possible alternative explana- tions for our results. A first possibility is that female leaders get worse evaluations than male leaders, not because of their gender, but because they are new and inexperienced (roughly 60% women have previous experience while the experience of 9). In the vignette and speech experiments, respondents leaders is who have I of Table 10 we restrict the evaluation of a Pradhan elected to any Another GP is sample to never reserved Pradhans significantly lower, see Table never had a female leader assume that female Pradhans are new and inexperienced, and therefore Panel of male likely to GPs and show uncorrelated with whether the Pradhan is may be worse. In that a respondent's new (i.e. has not been women leaders worse position prior to 2003). possibility, which we alluded to earlier, is that voters give evaluations simply because they are elected on a reserved seat. This, however, cannot explain the absence of bias for idea of reservation. women elected from twice-reserved GPs, unless voters get used to the If correct, this explanation suggests that voters will rank other reserved Pradhans below unreserved Pradhans, but GPs which were previously reserved for women. In Panel II we show Pradhans lower than non SC Pradhans (potentially because they are previous reservation for time female leaders is does not affect we show the speech and vignette. It is GP women reservation in general. 26 SC in SC also discriminated against), was previously reserved that previous reservation for exposure to that while voters rank Similarly the negative evaluation of this. unaffected by whether the Finally, in Panel IV, in women Pradhan would improve their ranking of reserved for SC (Panel first III). does not reduce voter bias that makes a difference, not exposure to Women Are 5.6 Leaders Hindered by Voter Bias? women Reservations ensure that difficult. we report In Table 11, experience on the job We first men is on for this question Pradhans their lives than for how affected by GPs in first well they are received by voters. (on a scale from life reported happiness). 28 In column self women reserved for This difference is coefficient absent for Pradhans elected in GPs is GPs In column (2) in either We sample to first more on-the-job women who Pradhans elected (for see that, relative to leaders elected from creating restrict the 1998 or 2003 Duflo, 2004). Table 11 we with and the mean -0.47, reserved for the second and second first strongly significant. is we using the 5, less satisfied time; moreover, the difference in stated satisfaction levels of female Pradhans in time reserved to 1 (1) of 2003 are significantly in Pradhans elected from unreserved seats (the 3.7). job more their based on surveying Pradhans which suggest that their results consider Pradhans' stated satisfaction with standard phrasing see that is But discrimination may make get elected. in elected from second-time reserved GPs. GPs shown that their gender created problems. While not in women 1998 or 2003) report their gender as (in either Thirty-four percent of the difficulties. GPs 1998 we use survey data from Chattopadhyay and women time reserved were elected Pradhan from reserved first time female Pradhans state the table, only 10 percent of the second time Pradhans did. column Finally, in (3) we expand the sample to and examine whether the Pradhan plans the first time in either We run Pradhans elected for re-election. 1998 or 2003 are 12% more unreserved GPs. This difference in to all likely to Both the in GPs reserved for absent for Pradhans in twice reserved GPs. is and lower bias Incumbents plan to not rerun than incumbents interpret these findings as suggesting that bias lowers time female leaders. in either 1998 or 2003, life and job satisfaction absent for second time level of satisfaction are leaders. Although somewhat speculative (especially since we do not see any other women), this may also explain why, significantly less likely to associate in Table 4, women with after for first one round of reservation, leadership activities, except in effects for women were GPs that had been reserved twice. " face The question is asked, "Which picture best describes very satisfied and the frowning-crying face is how satisfied you are with your life right now very dissatisfied? (Show picture with 5 faces)." 27 if the smiling Conclusion and Epilogue: Electoral Outcomes 6 Indian villagers prefer male leaders and have negatively biased priors on the effectiveness of female leaders. Male villagers rate their feeling towards female leaders more than one point below that towards male leaders; moreover, in never reserved villages hypothetical leaders performing the same We action are evaluated as less effective have argued that, in large part, if they are female. the overall "feeling" for male leaders reflects taste- based discrimination, or a deeply rooted social norm that leadership positions. Such social norms appear hard to it is inappropriate for alter, women to fulfill even after ten years of political reservation. In contrast, the effectiveness rating of a leader in a speech or a vignette, which we suggest reflects statistical discrimination, appears to be easier to change. We flects do not find any evidence that negative feelings towards the idea of female leaders worse performance by female Pradhans. Pradhans on many dimensions If of performance: anything, female Pradhans outperform male for instance, at a lower price. Moreover, villagers' rating of the they provide more public goods performance of their actual female Pradhan closely tracks their ranking of hypothetical leaders: below men (possibly reflecting the statistical discrimination), first cohort of female leaders but the second cohort with men. Another alternative, and potentially complimentary, explanation is rated is rated at par is that men dislike female Pradhans because they implement pro-woman policies. This explanation inconsistent with the fact that first-time and second-time female Pradhans are equally as to implement pro-woman policies but only first-time Taken together, the weight reservations, or leaders makes more generally quota systems, may play an important it translate into a Our results difficult to predict priori permanent improvement do suggest that if However, villagers' however, likely and that political role in reducing bias in continued preference for male whether a temporary program of reservation can in the electoral fortunes of women. reservation improves electoral outcomes for should be stronger after two cycles of reservations than after one cycle. May is, Pradhans receive negative evaluations. of the evidence suggests that exposure matters, perceptions of female leader effectiveness. re- 2008 Panchayat elections provide a unique opportunity to was marked by a strong anti-incumbent voting - The women, the effect recently concluded test this prediction. This election after 30 years of uninterrupted electoral success, 28 Communist Party the election, it is lost in a majority of GPs. very likely that political parties would not seat unless they expected her to As we mentioned elect the in Section 4.1, we analyze the GPs) that were not reserved Columns women who ran ward is a female candidate in an unreserved indirect: directly elected results, which May women in 2008. show the impact ward councillors 2008 election have not yet occurred. reflect villager preferences, are available. electoral results for the 1185 for wards (spread across the 165 Birbhum There were, on average, three candidates per GP (4) and for, and won, ward councillor positions. In non-reserved wards belonging (5) ward councillors were of previous reservation on the fraction of Pradhan was reserved both we in women (33% of the wards are reserved, so roughly see a striking difference for wards for wards in in in unreserved wards in GPs GPs where 1998 and 2003. Specifically, relative to wards GPs, the proportion of female candidates to Pradhan before 5.2% of the candidates, and 4.8% women). These numbers are unchanged councillors are reserved only once. However, of election that had never been reserved for a female of the elected all Pradhan Pradhan. The Pradhan elections following the In Table 11 GPs field this win the position. However, ward councillor election ward. Given the highly contested nature of in double reserved 38% of that were the position never reserved GPs increased by 3.3 percentage points and the proportion of women elected more than doubled (10.1% versus 4.8%). 29 The increased entry to field stand women in of women into politics may reflect either a change in parties' response to altered citizens' attitudes, or a greater willingness of for election, after they see that the second cohort of female Pradhans is willingness women to well liked. 30 Regardless of the mechanism at work, these results provide striking evidence that while ten years of exposure to leaders, women by giving voters a women may not have changed voters' stated preference for male chance to learn about the effectiveness of improved women's access to Beyond leaders women leaders, they have political office. their implications for the possible role of quotas in inducing durable changes in representation in politics, these results provide some of the first evidence on the potential 29 Bhavnani (2008) reports similar findings for urban wards of Mumbai, where previous reservation for women improved future representation of women on unreserved seats. 30 Even though we do not see impact of reservations on the attitude of the average woman, wc have argued that the most likely explanation is that many of them arc not exposed to politics. Women who are capable of standing for election must, however, be the most politically aware. 29 role for public policy in mitigating voter discrimination. of women is widely documented, there is While the political under-representation almost no credible evidence on whether public policy Much of the evidence from outside the political sphere suggests that policies which limit awareness of a candidate's gender may be an optimal can influence voters' belief systems and prejudice. short run response to discrimination (Goldin and Rouse, 2000). political settings where such strategies are important medium-run figures may role. While the Our results suggest that, in infeasible, political affirmative action first generation of women who may play an are powerful political encounter significant prejudice, their experience can pave the way for others to go further. References Aigner, D. and G. Cain (1977). Statistical Theories of Discrimination in Labor Markets. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 30, 175-187. and R. Kranton (2000). Identity and Economics. nomics 115(3), 715-154. The Quarterly Journal of Eco- Akerlof, G. M. (1990). The Puzzle of Party Identification American Politics Quarterly 18, 476-91. Alvarez, - Dimensionality of an Important Concept. M. (2001). Implicit Attitudes can be Measured. In H. Roediger and J. Nairne (Eds.), The Nature of Remembering: Essays in Honor of Robert G. Crowder. Washington, DC: American Banaji, Psychological Association. Baron, A. and M. Banaji (2006). The Development of Implicit Attitudes: Evidence of Race Evaluations from Ages 6 and 10 and Adulthood. Psychological Science 17(1), 53-58. Bergemann, D. and J. Valmiki (2008). Bandit Problems. In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Bertrand, M., D. Chugh, and S. Mullainathan (2005). Economic Review 95(2), 94-98. S. Durlauf and L. Blume (Eds.), Implicit Discrimination. American and V. Rao (2007). Just Rewards? Local Politics and Public Resource Allocation in South India, mimeo, Harvard. Besley, T., R. Pande, Bhavnani, R. (2008). Can Governments Remedy Political Inequality? Evidence from Randomized Quotas in India, mimeo, Stanford. Duncan, M. Kremer, D. Levy, and J. Eccles (2006). Empathy or Antipathy? The Consequences of Racially and Socially Diverse Peers on Attitudes and Behaviors. American Economic Review 96, 1890-1906. Boisjoly, J., G. J. Guryan Working Paper 13661. Charles, K. and (2007). Prejudice and the Economics of Discrimination. NBER Chattopadhyay, R. and E. Duflo (2004). Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India. Econometrica 72(5), 1409-1443. 30 S. and G. Loury (1993). Will Affirmative-Action American Economic Review 83(5), 1220-1240. Coate, Dahlerup, D. (2006). Women, Quotas and Politics. Policies Eliminate Negative Stereotypes? New York: Routledge. Dasgupta, N. and S. Asgari (2004). Seeing is believing: Exposure to counterstereotypic women leaders and its effect on the malleability of automatic gender stereotyping. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 40, 642-658. Why Duflo, E. (2005). Political Reservations. Journal of the European Economic Associa- tion 3(2-3), 668-678. Duflo, E. and P. Topalova (2004). Unappreciated Service: Performance, Perceptions, and Leaders Women Mimeo. in india. Eagly, A. and S. Karau (2002). Role Congruity Theory of Prejudice toward Female Leaders. Psychological Review 109, 573-598. Eagly, A. and A. Mladinic (1989). Gender Stereotypes and attitudes toward Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 15(4), 543-558. Frechette, G., F. Maniquet, and M. Morelli. Incumbents Interests, women and men. Voters Bias and Gender Quotas. American Journal of Political Science forthcoming. Goldberg, P. (1968). Goldin, C. (1990). A Are Women Prejudiced Against Women? Transaction 5, 28-30. Pollution Theory of Discrimination. Mimeo, Harvard. Goldin, C. and C. Rouse (2000). Orchestrating Impartiality: the Impact of "Blind" Auditions on Female Musicians. American Economic Review 90(4), 715-741. Government of West Bengal Department of Panchayats The West Bengal Panchayat (Constitution) Rules, 1975. Rural Development. (1998). & Greenwald, A., M. Banaji, and B. Nosek (2003). Understanding and Using the Implicit Association Test: I. An Improved Scoring Algorithm. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 85(2), 197-216. Greenwald, A., D. McGhee, and Cognition: 1464-1480. The J. Schwartz (1998). Measuring Individual Differences in Implicit and Social Psychology 75(6), Implicit Association Test. Journal of Personality L. and N. Terkildsen (1993). Gender Stereotypes and the Perception of Male and Female Candidates. American Journal of Political Science 37(1), 119-147. Huddy, Ingelhart, R. and P. Norris (2003). Rising Tide: the World. Cambridge: Cambridge University. Gender Equality and Cultural Change Around Jones, M. (2004). Quota Legislation and the Election of Experience. Journal of Politics 66(4), 1203-1223. Keller, S. Women: Learning from and T. Mirer (1974). The Simple Act of Voting. American the Costa Rican Political Science Review 68, 572-91. J., J. Liebman, and L. Katz (2007). Econometrica. Kling, Experimental Analysis of Neighborhood 31 Effects. Krook, M. (2005). Politicizing Representation: Campaigns for Candidate Gender Quotas Worldwide. New York: Ph.D. diss Columbia University. Matland, R. E. (1994). Putting Scandinavian Equality to the Test: An Experimental Evaluation of Gender Stereotyping of Political Candidates in a Sample of Norwegian Voters. British Journal of Political Science 24, 273-292. S. and E. Washington (2009). Sticking With your Vote: Cognitive Political Attitudes. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. Mullainathan, and Munshi, K. and M. Rosenzweig (2008). The Efficacy of Parochial and Competence in Indian Local Governments. Mimeo. Politics: Caste, Dissonance Commitment, Nosek, B., A. Greenwald, and M. Banaji (2007). The Implicit Association Test at Age 7: A Methodological and Conceptual review. In J. A. Bargh (Ed.), Automatic Processes in Social Thinking and Behavior. Powley, E. (2007). Rwanda: The Impact of Women Legislators on Policy Outcomes Affecting Children and Families. Background Paper, State of the World's Children. Rooth, D. O. (2007). Implicit Discrimination in Hiring: Real World Evidence. IZA Discussion Paper 2764. Rudman, L. and K. Fairchild (2004). Reactions to Counterstereotypic Behavior: The Role of Backlash in Cultural Stereotype Maintenance. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 87(2), 157-176. Rudman, L. and S. Kilianski (2000). Implicit and Explicit Attitudes Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 26(11), 1315-1328. Thernstrom, ible. New S. and A. Thernstrom (1997). America In Black York, NY: Simon and Schuster. UNICEF (2007). The State of The World's Children: dend of Gender Equality. New York: UN. Weisberg, H. (1980). Behavior 2, 33-96. Zaller, J. (1992). A And Women Toward Female Authority. White: One Nation, Indivis- and Children: The Double Divi- Multidimensional Conceptualization of Party Identification. Political The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 32 A Appendix IAT A.l We administered three IATs. Taste IAT 1: The prompts used IAT in each are listed below. Villagers Male names: Badal, Shyamol, Saurabh, Gopal, Anup, Ashok, Tapan, Raju Female names: Geeta, Minoti, Anjali, Rekha, Jharna, Minu, Rupa, Basanti Good Bad attributes: good, nice, fun, happiness, love, clean, sweet, heaven attributes: bad, Taste IAT 2: Good and Bad mad, sorrow, inauspicious, sad, dirty, spoiled, hell Leaders Male and Female Leaders: Pictures Attributes: Same as Taste IAT (available from authors) 1. Gender Occupation Stereotype IAT: Domestic activities: Eating puffed rice, Listening to the radio, Sleeping, Taking rest, Clay modelling, Harvesting, Caring for animals, Threshing rice Leadership words: ing, Gram Pradhan, Public speaking, Govern, Chairperson, Lobbying, Leader, Campaign- Taking bribes Male and female names: same as A. 2 in Taste IAT: Villagers Vignette and Speech Note Respondents were given one of four vignettes, where we randomly varied the gender of the Prad- han (Male (Tapan Das) or Female (Sandhya Das)) and the investment decision Respondents received one recordings. Vignette We of six speech versions randomized the gender READ OUT: We South 24 Parganas. We of - Pradhan three male voice recordings and three female voice at the respondent level Pradhan of will read a short description of the will ask (Irrigation or Water). CHANDI village you some questions about what you think the Pradhan should have done. There are no right or wrong answers. Please answer each in terms of your own reactions. Pradhan Tapan Das [Pradhan Sandhya Das] has been serving the end of the year approaches, there villagers water. have been pressing him in district is [her] to only a limited amount make improvements There was enough money to make investments still of Panchayat money remaining one area. Prior to villagers at the no safe drinking water available :;:: for ten months. As in the budget. Yet, two major areas: irrigation and drinking in only Pradhan Tapan Das [Pradhan Sandhya Das] consulted with expressed frustration that there was in his [her] . Gram in making a Sabha. the village. decision, Many Many people people, especially children, were getting sick. Others were upset about the quality of the irrigation system. Poor irrigation system meant that, in dry years, Sandhya Das] considered the demands carefully, Das [Shrimati Sandhya Das] knew the health off many people lost their crops. and wondered what to cost of bad water do. Shri On quality. Yet, Tapan Das [Shrimati the one hand, Shri Tapan wouldn't everyone be better with better irrigation. After careful reflection Pradhan Tapan Das [Pradhan Sandhya Das] decided to improvement [drinking invest in irrigation Speech READ OUT: Labhpur in district You will water]. hear a tape-recorded speech from the village meeting of West Dinajpur. We will ask Gram Panchayat you some questions on the effectiveness of the leader. There are no right or wrong answers. Please answer each in terms of your own reactions. VILLAGER: The tube well of our Kumarpara your locality has been done PRADHAN: As a partially, not functioning. The repairing job of the tubewell in but the same work at Nutangram has been completed. For repairing of tubewells result of which, other is maximum amount Panchayat of funds of the is being drained out. works can't be done. From the next stage you, the people, should take mental preparations that the minor repairing jobs of the tubewells won't be done by the Panchayat. if the work involves a large amount of money, e.g. if a pipe is needed then Rs.250, Rs.300, this type of works will be done by the Panchayat. people have to take initiative to collect subscriptions to do will this. But it involves the for the I mean money above minor repairing jobs the In the future, the plan of the Panchayat be "plans with equal sharings" ("Samobhagi Parikalpana"). The Government won't provide money. The Government provide some amount of will money and people either by giving labor or helping financially. In this done. Suppose a village road work and the Panchayat will the Panchayat did mostly. A. 3 Public Good all the the rest have to be borne by the the work of the Panchayat have to be has to be constructed, then the people of the village will do the earthen supply the morram. Therefore the people Then preparation have to be taken. way that I the total work can be would now made with like all villagers to will now share the jobs, which a success. So in the next stage that approve the village budget. Variables Quantity and Quality Variables: Water and sanitation quantity variable: a dummy for whether a tubewell was built, a tubewell was repaired, a sanitation pit was built, a sanitation pit repaired. Water and Sanitation quality variable: handpumps are perennial, provide clean water, no stagnant water, have drainage and sanitation - no stagnant water, drainage 34 facility. Irrigation quantity variable: dummy for whether an irrigation pump was built or repaired. road was built or repaired since 2003. Roads quantity Roads quality variable: a dummy for whether a metal number condition of road (1-5) and variable: of potholes in 100m. Transport quantity variable: number of transportation related infrastructure (bus stop, bus service, taxi). Transport quality variable: dummy for Schools and other education shelter. was facility built, and an indicator a dummy for a CE for whether such Center/CE primary schools, middle schools, quality variable: whether math was number for all quantity variable: a facility was repaired, a libraries and secondary built, a dummy of doctors. whether a health Health Quality variable: having a labor room. Fair Price facility facility bus stand has for whether any educational dummy for whether there is a creche SSK, Anganwadi, Schools and other education facilities schools. primary schools have drinking water, for if dummy Library. Educational facility quantity variable: Health Quantity variable: the number of health test scores. facility facilities presence of a bus stand and latrines, a facilities, was repaired (0 if blackboards and reading and dummy no health for whether a health facility existed), and having tap or hand-pump water and an indicator Shop Quality measure includes: whether prices displayed, no bad behavior of shop keeper, and no complaint against shop. Satisfaction Variables: Average satisfaction is the satisfaction across five different kinds of public goods: water provision, public transport, schools, health care and computed public good satisfaction measure is variables take the value of one the question was answered if fair price shops. Each of the individual as the average of the responses of a set of questions. provision: satisfied with the quantity of the water supply in All the affirmative. Satisfaction with water and the quality of the water supply respectively. Satisfaction with public transport: satisfied with the frequency, reliability, cost of public bus system, the quality of the buses and the behavior of the driver/conductor. (if Satisfaction with schools: satisfied with available) the school's building, playground, recreational facilities, classrooms, toilets, drinking water, meals, quality of the teaching, quality of study material and behavior of teacher. Satisfaction with price shops: satisfied fair with the quality of items, the quantity of items, the fairness of shopkeeper and the availability of items in the shop. Satisfaction with health care: satisfied with treatment, behavior of doctors, behavior or paramedical staff quality of medicine, cleanliness inside the facility in outpatient health facilities and satisfied with treatment, behavior of doctors, behavior or paramedical staff quality bathrooms in inpatient of medicine, quality of food, cleanliness inside the wards, cleanliness inside the health facilities. 35 — OS © £ -a w Io <2 <u O. § s 1*1 B u. o c a oo en K T D 00 o\ co C5 o o CM £ L> © ^3 o e »s os o O c u o G C a id o -G ri t 'J c/i Of OS flj 04 c 3 O § u r; s u -a B fa £ I art e 0J o o 3 6D i-i:-_i 0. CO o o o to o in o CO o o suuqpcij 0|Biuaj uoijdkjj CM o o Table 1. Villaee-level Randomization Census Variable Total Population Fraction SC / ST Population Average Household Size , Sex Ratio Under 6 Literacy Fraction Women Literate Fraction Irrigated Land Village has a Bus or Train Stop Village has Permanent Approach Village has Road Tube Well Village has Hand Pump Village has Well Village has Community Tap Number of Schools Number of Health Check First Reserved Only Reserved 1998 and Reserved Never 2003 2003 1998 Reserved (1) (2) (3) (1) Diff:(l) and Diff: (3) and (2) (4) (6) (5) 1.318 1,197 1,267 1,362 -102.279 -78.373 (1318) (1295) (1418) (1555) (178.537) (189.410) 0.432 0.502 0.450 0.471 0.004 -O.001 (0.281) (0.256) (0.235) (0.265) (0.056) (0.033) 5.436 5.222 5.362 5.497 0.137 -O.059 (0.612) (0.449) (0.571) (2.454) (0.093) (0.135) 1.093 1.034 1.046 1.036 0.206 0.015 (0.590) (0.276) (0.218) (0.226) (0.113) (0.025) 0.387 0.351 0.391 0.373 0.014 0.021 (0.119) (0.129) (0.121) (0.137) (0.032) (0.017) 0.287 0.265 0.296 0.275 -0.003 0.023 (0.125) (0.123) (0.113) (0.134) (0.033) (0.016) 0.599 0.485 0.607 0.500 -0.038 0.054 (0.321) (0.349) (0.323) (0.352) (0.054) (0.049) 0.280 0.433 0.290 0.259 -0.130 0.061 (0.451) (0.500) (0.456) (0.439) (0.097) (0.054) 0.110 0.300 0.176 0.194 -0.225 -0.006 (0.314) (0.462) (0.383) (0.397) (0.082) (0.052) 0.910 0.933 0.912 0.977 -0.022 -0.018 (0.288) (0.252) (0.285) (0.151) (0.020) (0.031) 0.124 0.000 0.100 0.057 0.000 0.013 (0.331) (0.000) (0.302) (0.233) (0.000) (0.012) 0.440 0.533 0.402 0.528 0.043 -0.066 (0.499) (0.503) (0.493) (0.500) (0.082) (0.074) 0.065 0.050 0.042 0.010 0.022 -0.018 (0.248) (0.220) (0.202) (0.098) (0.020) (0.017) 1.190 1.233 1.265 1.160 -0.167 0.149 (0.895) (0.810) (0.889) (0.910) (0.160) (0.111) 0.170 0.217 0.118 0.218 -0.036 -0.015 (0.403) (0.490) (0.324) (0.809) (0.090) (0.069) Overall Effect: F stat 0.300 0.600 Overall Effect: m 0.586 0.438 Facilities p value N 60 105 108 Notes: 1 The census variables are from the 1991 Census of India. variables have between 454 and 478 total N refers to the maximum number of observations. Infrastructure observations across GPs. 2 "First Reserved 2003," "Reserved 1998 and 2003," "Only Reserved 1998," and "Never Reserved" are indicator variables for GPs reserved for a female Pradhan for the first time in 2003, in both 1998 and 2003, only in 1998, and not reserved in either election, respectively. 3 Columns (l)-(4) report means with standard deviations in parenthesis Columns (5)-(6) report tests of differences of means across columns (1) and (2) and columns (3) and (4), respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. Tests are based on regressions with block fixed effects and standard errors are clustered by GP « u r3 OjO 0) wi — v> — t— © — ©_©„ ° — o ° o o o 9 p, 9 p. ° p. JS >> > ~ <3 <^> < vo Tf vo © o o © o o CO J ~3 u — ' o "^ - — "Q -z o 2 P o 9 o. -1- © o d d MS d I c On d d VO JO u •a J3 u s CN 3 vO S M On in * S o o o P o P 9 d © © P d r»l r-> o •a L, CO •j3 0) <-^ o vo o d © ON no o in d d p g o c 13 o a o CO NO (L> 2 O 4) 00 !3 — ^ o m o P d o d <N S 2 o 9 o p ("- r-i ON rO m o P O d d d ON 00 O d in © r- o d d tVO o Xo CS O a. o ft. D. < JP -a K n — en - * J m _~ ° ~ © o P o P o o o _ P o 9 P, -r vo m © p d d JJ o j= On r-- r- vo <s L, ft, c u X u **• c VO — CM © © q — 3 d q — p © d © -T O © 9 P. : © d On o d q d CO In vo vo c „ o P © no C3 D. "3 rn f; m N n p © P (N P © © P P © d o d o **" o C3 r«i r-- *^" in* m © cn o © d p c ^a CJ -p .a j§ u 2 5 S S « ft. o P o "3r^ M c- ^ - m iN r~ oo 00 r- -r © ro ^- Ov © CN © q c; © cq © d d O © p © n x r» ^ S ^ © © © ^ © © s o ov On r^i *~* © ON — On © in © On 2 r- P o 9 o 9ddo9o CN ON m © © © © r<-> c <N en P O 9 o — - © S "* © © © d 9 © ^> a~ © © vo vo m c © © (N -O c; C 0O On rs ra *— "O HJ e Q> W 4> - CO ON On u E; r. ft, E — u £ t/5 1J ft< i 00 ON ON t 4J to <u D U './ ^ ^ ~B O a = O <a B > X 5 O" C « C3 < IG t3 U a u c J^ — 2C X -— u JD 3 O c O T3 E " JC a j c 00" EH >^ 5 h a <U eb <U j3 ^ C O 1 ra > < CU K JO G u 3 n. O — O .—; en C J5 t/1 SO '«, "O g fc^ t- 2 CO o "3 Oi -- II — 15 p CO y 1) J3 K -rr T3 -C 1i o o > rd a> -a j- L~ y 8 VO 00 ON ON c 5 on -= © © CN « S u ESO - -J u 3 a u "z: u W XJ ^ 62 ^ p V '— > O -II- z fc u < c/j "c3 E cj Bj ^° 2 5~ © S 9 © o O 00 o o O o r- 2s _ T> a. © o 9 d OJ nj E Cfl S * 2 "~ — o 3; © m * m © o © o o o © d © d © © fi o o o d p oo « a — m S s \p V c U. cd jiS ap 13 o a T3 H r-- o\ cn V~l ©do n vi in 5 3 33 u o O m o © CN = T3 E o r^ o ^ If ~pop© d d d d i CA TO c K^ fc 00 cn O cn d £ (N m "* t © o m o o © © © d Lr 5! 2 ci © © © ©. "3- — — vo o © d d •>* Mt~- CN 3- s *r\ o ft< m — CN o s 5 £1 E _u — o O C3 Tf £ u s I > ft. •* r- •* — p © © 3 90 0- odd — n — en in cn cn U1 c ri tJ- <r^ o J2 o * © © d d d d d d O g T3 Oi .22 u 3 (U X LS — c o 1- t» O © © ft. o o 2 © © p d d © d d d CN ©. •a 00 - cn d oo CN <u CO s d d U u 3 U bO > flj OJ in b TO '5. p, to O <L) 00 yj E a. _ to -: a a> •o E T3 (^1 J4 to E c TO > oo §s r— © © CS oo cn — 0\ v£> d CN i/-i O c u Q c <U TO 5 o U to < to HJ C u rsi 0> < aj 0> 5 U i TO <u c II en o o CN a - cn o o cn u 5, E a C/3 -^ u oc CJ 3- U w O T3 C a O CN "Q 1—4 s p4 oo T3 -C u .- M & ~ > II o - oi tt a Oi p. E 5 u CN '— >p TO =; <u ,«3 t«— 5u -£E T3 cr '~ o (L) to -a = 'J QJ ~ U to U o c: u u - o s QJ .5 e s. -o QJ C 4J -: c a c _o TO 3 > c JH — — < <u u 1 --> U IN o 0) T3 U u to 5 c c2 Z — < c o TO i o to i to H CO H "_i TO "5 a r_ is > C^ X "to c <u TO — TO cz TO U > CO a! a 3 to o :r V t/1 g — — — -C ~ H -1- — 3 U 3 eg ' QJ -3 "o ~D JS ti-i 1 ~ TO oCJ "C ~ ~ > Table 4. Gender and Leadership: Implicit Associations IAT (D-measure of bias against females) Leadership/Domestic and Male/Female Male Female 111 (2) A Panel Ever Reserved -0.077 0.021 (0.030) (0.040) Panel B First Reserved 2003 Reserved 1998 and 2003 Only Reserved 1998 Test: 2003 = both 1998 and 2003 = 1998 Mean of Never Reserved Sample N -0.086 0.122 (0.040) (0.053) -0.036 -0.106 (0.047) (0.072) -0.094 -0.027 (0.040) (0.049) 0.507 0.010 0.110 0.150 (0.021) (0.027) 477 357 Notes: 1 Dependent variables measure indicates are the IAT D-measure, a stereotype associating defined in notes to Table women leadership activities. Reservation variables are as defined in Tables 2 The regressions include clustered by GP. 3 the controls defined in notes to Table 2, The sample The p-value from a Wald test size reflects the 3. A positive with domestic activities and 1 men and 2 notes. and standard errors are sampling strategy (see Table 3 notes). of the equality of the coefficients on First Reserved 2003, Reserved 1998 and 2003 and Only Reserved 1998 is Dwith reported. in ; , 1 — ; I s <u »J c t- Os so OS tl M O S M O O o o o o ea E m *£ — ^ t 'O 'O I* >n p © p o p o © © © © ° © oo c^ in °. o 9 o <-? <u u- P .E in c o TJ 03 o o © n o q o q d d d Os <D 03 2 3 a> tD | 53 O m c c <n m o ro d = -3- 1/1 rsi © o o d d i <u a! -rr iri i r oo m c o ~ © o q d d E — r- oo \o in h in t o o oo o o o o o © o © © © SO & u m o © d = i/"> so in »n o .= «3 £ 2 S H, 9 V a OS ITS — C — = ~ = ^ ~ ra 73 ~[fl t/n U U u ~ re > S U o « CO rsi -3- Os c3 rsi m -f o — o m E Csl o o d d : <u oo CM en rn c © ~ c — c o d 03 2 d ro — 5sO — cr »n o d d — so so — — S o o rM 9 d © ro o c d d — in oo O o so i- \o »n —< p -^ p o o o o p o o o OO os )p. SO fcu c V*s on .5 oo ^ so rn r-1 3- d o C »n o •n »n — S? - 3 S - -E - < i- ra ^L) U- _ tn rsi 4J "3- rsi m o oo o ^t o 03 2 ^3- r-si rsi v-i M -_< ^ — o >n o CJ SO 3 u in m *n oo -o in h ^ >n S P o p o o O ^T O O O O O tN ^ °. o rs) -rr TD j: c o 5 o "-p 3 Q p u ,o — 03 — ^ m — OS O o o o o SO *T) S i -_ E m iQ ro o - i — so o O oo c o — o o o o o o rn rj * m o e rsj t-~ rsi — « u 03 <U s —<0 £ z V M a u. u JU f . > < 2 o q 03 c_? 53 vn — o os m o o m o d © © r*j r~rsi so •£} S -3- Ml 13 — - O O O O h O O d d d ci d ci oo r- r~ r- oo 3<* SO r- o os o ro o H ° o d o 03 > q o o o o ^ d o d d P d 9 d rsi o o <u 5 u ^ + cy 2 2 i- t c S > = ° ^ > a 5 2 — ii II m J3 a> r^ °° os os ra JH C/l CD £ CU £1 u CO 03 03 •^i E E o 3 £ d PL, 03 H £ Pm „U <L> o u- Ph ii ^ O £ "O ^ C3 c SJ <l> — — rs" u > ij oo —<U ' m O o (N O s D <u O — '-'. C u f o ii T3 3 m o o d O *N <N "^T oo X c> O" _= — r ra 3" "5 ca (4 (J B # t -n "S -C Oh J= i QJ a < — tL, t. 1 S <S) c ' a > < ^ „ — oZ U 13 3> - o ur 2" J5 8 ^ JT- e >, — (NinS^O^O^-MSOCN^ — © O O ~ — P p p p 3 on in C^ oopooooooopooo — -": --; ; p 1 O , o ~- P — r-_ o — P ~- — — — — u r C —— 3 ^ In <s> . doPodoooPoPcJdo : a! 2 E -a _3 ^ ac > _ oc —^ i/i S3 O o- E -g n rf -' i "> H £o .2? 3 re " o> n * n GO CN VO oo O ~ O~ — o 00P0— O O O ddpo'ddddpdpd ' a T3 ' r*^ 11 o m Q. X PJ uj v-it^inrninfit^i^i^'n — PopoPopoooopop ^ddd^ddddddddd <1' — ©\voovo^5r^om r<-i « > u u e P. •£ re S -a td C 2 is u v ' I iC r^ (N in in * O o o d PoooooPooo pdddddpddd c ^ ""-"' o> <D < o 5 ~o < ^ b re C J2 J5 >o vo IN sy m m — * ^ f 2 o o q p p p p p p P o o o d d d d d d d ^ d 9 d d d C- =t PJ <* r^- 'i ,, I o Cu -S D. <U OJ O u : a) c o o — c j " re 5 oo -o ca 1 1 ^ o <u C *- <U fli re — -> re QJ ^^ ^ .2 oi u > </5 tu * c a -3 — - -a q « JC3 V »— CL<L> o c > tt) * c $ <u -a L. a. B P <u U u. T3 t f C/l t/J <U u > u aj tu W > ti - i-S c 3 -^ £ 2 -2 I -SI U U. s re * -a > 4J §£ S m td u. o § ^ .2 5 o I ^3 c Z — rsi t; " — *r. — tfl _0> « E -J <D ft, U* m m c ^ cd _CJ 03 2 i — — f- rn co Tt so «n ^f *n o p P o p p o d o d o 9 !> S2 ^1 fN » ^ 2 ^ o — o t d o d 9 < VI ar- o -* * so 3 o "i o o fo P o <n ci 6 d d d 9 "3- 03 o Mc (9 C3 M g ^ ^ s o >. z CD -J <L> C/l - U d u ^2 bfl 03 c co B u Cl> o _ ""! — m 3 o O p 3 d > > 73 m r> £; O ~ o SO O SO S so f^ o o o P o 9 d d d 9 d ^r O ^ ST o P o 9 d 9 d 2; rn* £3 V£>- sc o CN 2 (LI o — o m rco .. •*j~> "» ~ ^ P o 9 d "~ CN so oo o SO ° h O " CD c O (N -O o o o o . ?? o t; ST a « Os K. CN & o 9 o 9 d d 9 d 9 d o o m cn CN »n C o <L> > u u. CO — t!> rt sS •— (D ft. o Os O - co VI u SO M" CN SO ZZ .2 o u. O 9 d d SO 0O Tf so -T d o oi to CO 2 cn so 9 N so o o o 9 ro o >o r C O © o l o 3 O —g _= j T3 eg o X - c" 53 UJ O odd cn Ov ^r co o o o E Cl> O * (N ^> d ft. I~- Os CN Vi m d d « a c ca 5 > < cu to p t (0 CO 2 n c Os P in — r- c in H o o o c p 9 d d d d d T3 CO Os o o p d d p r-i u SO ^5 SO <4-l o ca C T3 ca OO Os Os E; <L» W (U i— II B CD s m c c CN ac - >* O O o o CN (N W 1— -O T3 CO CU t/3 3 a -OO Q> ON 1 ' T3 :o O 0> -a d> > a> T3 C/J eg !L* oc! >i irt U G Cci c ••* (U H ^5 T? = — ra cu a. CI TO C3 i> £ u w cu -W VI cu f- oi CU cn u _3 _- C <u o C/J "3 .c cn o c '1 4J -CJ o £ m ~ T3 G ^ U u 5d 5 ca c o tfc cu 1_ (U U 3 -5 H Z O O E o o t <+-i C C/l u u 6 cn c II rn m o o o o CN CN •5 CO ~ X) J3 J3 1/5 on a U-i <U o o -i-* X CO H c "— sS •£ II rN U CO CO OS ON OS OS tu -s 5 3 i o m CO c a c C E c C/l 1 U > 2 III = CO cu 0) CO > u M V o- cn U 3 3 > c ~3 tU D. U < £ tN ro <u ~ ; ' 1 w _c <D (J c y t> s g .0 — n O 0> u £ B a. .£P re u On ON co r- in »n no rn m NO en in O O O <* en ON O O 1 < E LJ_ On m 3 * 2 *n * "* 9 00 9 O N 9 O X OO o o 9 9 e<-> in r> -^r On r- <" O in no <3- r- U M rz u. U ^ (N °° £ m £ 9 o 9 © 9 L/-, O _n > < £ <?' •a s s 9 o n t^ O m m o J3 9 o o 9 o NO - (N On PT 2 S £3 >o Q o ° o 9 o 9 O O o 9 o o o " - r- o o o — (N NO OO ON ^r in ' "=* a <D NO ^t" r- co 1 Z 2 00 a, < — On O O no — q m O o o O 00 O O (N on > o bS t~~ 0000 CO ON 1 — II en en a O cs -3 CO b 3 a e 3 ON ~0 > CO a 00 en O O CN a C4 OO c cn CO *~~ 00 ON On -0 O tt5 5 _ -D a) II II en en r <N 1 4_; JJ Crt VI S s "-' es B 5 - O u - Hu <u a O ^ _ H (N Cj no ii3 — o u T3 > OJ to cd c3 ^o on r^ *t (N on in o o o o ^ o o n o N o o o o o o o ca o C3 -J_ t£ S < « -i, a ca CJ Ph O c -e — i<u < Oh — o B 0> E — r- oo g; <N oo On u £3 o. X -* ^3 oo J3 -* Jg o> 2 — 2 — ^ O o ""! ' i « ~ — m - O O. Si-sa « o -3 E 5 DO <u en r^ 1 oo 25 oo — 2 o 2 9 o r- e 00 2 S <N 9 o o 6 p C o ca ' o = d V ~ X 75 0) <u TJ ^ :z x: ~ (D x £ m o oo O — rN on ro o o o — m o o o o o i c "3 u a C CO £ =j O r_ o — O On oo o _ oo o — UT 9 o o o o 9 o £"> oo oo -* o O O O (N -c r-j O o < T] oo in on — — O o o — H 9 m o o 9 o o o r- U r- l - fN> -sr on o o o IT) i3 O C c en u u to en O o M < tn — i en 5 g U ON OO -* oo oo £N no o — o o o o o © o (N O — — g O- ^> -* S "^ no ^ r- S -7 O O O O ^ °^ ON r-~ u r > — W *Q D. i £ 5 x cd -— u C/l "O T3 en u > s — C v. u -C o u — t C u rN P> ~ P — — in On O )£ O o — o 9 o "9 o o o 9 o 2 a> > T3 " T3 _e i 9 o EJ ^ ON ^ ss « £9 OO w-i c3 Cu a. QJ CJ Eg £ 2 o 00 u ~ - 5 = o ^ o 73 73 C- 7j u •= (n oo rg rn rJ r-~ o <N - c '5 cu u J= > B c a ae cd ^^ > c z aD en C4 JD en V as c u i:> t s c tl c u c i o n* 3 a O £ en u ~ u -3 a. -J M jS z -3 tl _f -^ en ^_, C^ >i C CO 1> = U *S i Table Robustness 10. Average I. Evaluation of First Time Evaluation of II. in 2003 Term in 2003 * Reserved Reserved 2003 (for Only Reserved 1998 IV. Reserved 2003 SC Panel -0.100 -0.030 (0.067) (0.064) -0.082 -0.052 (0.058) (0.053) (for * Woman for SC in 1998 0.125 0.006 (0.132) (0.119) Reservation Woman) Reserved 1998 and 2003 (for First 0.007 (0.073) 1998 Evaluation of Female Pradhans and First 0.016 (0.072) 2003 in SC Reserved for III. in SC Reserved for -0.212 -0.070 (0.074) (0.075) Woman) 0.042 0.003 (0.087) (0.063) Woman) Previously Reserved for 0.007 -0.028 (0.086) (0.076) SC 0.040 -0.007 (0.132) (0.131) Reservation on Female Leadership: Speech and Vignettes Results A Female Pradhan Female Pradhan Panel (21 SC Pradhans SC Reserved for Female (D New Pradhans Pradhan as effect Male * Ever Reserved -0.046 -0.040 (0.035) (0.034) SC -0.014 0.020 (0.039) (0.039) 0.004 0.017 (0.042) (0.045) B Female Pradhan * Reserved for SC in 2003 Female Pradhan * Reserved SC in 1998 for -0.028 0.030 (0.047) (0.048) Notes: 1 The regressions in Panel I —I II use the average evaluation coefficient for Pradhan (explained in notes to Table 7) as the dependent variable. 2 In Panel sample 3 In Panel the explanatory variable of interest I is II In Panel whether the Pradhan was elected for the the explanatory variables of interest are whether the and the interaction of being reserved 4 is first time in 2003 and the restricted to the set of never reserved Pradhans. III. for a woman Pradhan the explanatory variables of interest are the in GP was reserved for SC in the 1998 and being reserved for an women 2003 and 1998 elections SC Pradhan in 2003. reservation status indicators and the interaction of "Previously Reserved for SC" indicator with the "First Reserved 2003" indicator. The regressions also include the interaction of 5 The in "Only Reserved 1998" and "Reserved 1998 and 2003" with "Previously Reserved SC" indicator. regressions in Panel IV use the average perception of Pradhan effectiveness in the speech and vignettes (explained notes to Table 5) as the dependent variable. The explanatory variables of interest are the indicators for female Pradhan speech/vignette and the interaction of this indicator with the reservation for in the addition, the regressions include the indicator variables for ever reserved for 2003 and 1998 6 for in in the in SC status of the GP. Panel A, and reserved for In SC in Panel B. All regressions include the controls defined in Table defined SC notes of Table 1. 2, and standard errors are clustered by GP. Reservation types are 1 1 x © c <N _c !/. C c o o o © '-C u <u V c £ ta » (N ^ \o oo n — «n m o — — o ©' o o o o — o o o © o oo »n ir> ^oo (N O — _ 0- O 5 o - c o c g f2 £ -H: i 2 £ C/l aj xi CO cfl ^. > u u 4> o 5 u OJ Os C/3 a c O l/J B c L> *z! •-> «J w )0 - \o S — ~— ^ vo — ~ ~ — ~ —~ — -2 ~ P O © O ° o o r*1 -_ cu v_ — oo N n 2 O IN <N "1 o c iC u o .5 — CL -> o a -6 3 Z a o X <L> «! 4J (U 1/1 § i- 3 = — £ 13 .— -n O ra rj 1) & v? u p lc 4> £X a 3 p ^J- tS — 5 , g 3 o s o c o &c CN V) <D i> oi O " c a. o r- T3 c S "j *"' ra —— a u 1J 6 u JS a =a "3 o o > ao in ti-. (fi ^ a. en £ M ~ — (S o 2 j3 -a u c u ,_; U 7 O < =§ a _o Z < 2 (S a Cl. o o o °l 5 "31 1) = B CL) > <§ 5 — O 3 CD r- on 22 ^> no g r- mc [n \o 5- o ~ CN m (N — (N o p © o o P © ©' rsi ; ^^ oe c r^ r*-i fn ~ o __ r^ o ND no - — « < ~ s o acu > CL> 1) -^ X. i S > CD o £ = <| 3 9 S u Cu CU c S a (A B ~5 U S u c Q cu 0) ab CQ & XI 5 o u -5 >^ U r- •5^5= c s 'C S3 C/l o u o a 3 fS ^ a O DMo c ra on on •«= ^:l u iu ra o ^ € g , » 2 h ,u S3 B '5 w 6 o - >. .3 S -a m o o (N p*"l 3 5 £ 2 o o (N ^ T3 V3 CS a 00 a) on fj & 3C ON 1 g :" OJ Ol C '"" '= ° « cu 5 > — w -° cq — -= S -O ~ or c ^ -a I 59 tl^ 1 i *— 6i 1 1 "i 4-. u <N i/i +3 aj — n c u >- o Z - U Bi i r^i "O S tti « O QJ S R a € S « 2 c c _ -— o O <N u u u . ro ^ t; ° u w !9 •a S3 =; 5 < i TO q « 5 q b > CL 6 J3 -; feh no m m ro o o o © © © © - oo m T © — o ~- o On o o o © © © ©' o no r**i p-) iri p\i ia r- 00 M no m o t o © o o © © o © VO ^ "i " O c. 00 — o p to o — — P o — m — if © no © O O O O ©'©©'© t *T O >0 o o o o © O © O NO (N m m On — — t o wn o o r* o o © o o : NO CO iTi TT = o o o o l S < O U ^ ~ O * V r- cu « o o © © © o © rvl OC rn Op O © — — — — O O © O o o o © — — — — © © o ©* vn O m On nO NO On o o © * rs °0 — 5 © Ov nT N — ~ — — © on m 5 © — n in P © tj- q = ^ — © © © 1«I Cd <*1 vo" £ a s ^O ON CO r-j £^ C _Z M (N m (N no T m in NO in © •*r On r* rJ On no ^ c« s -^ '5 S S o (*- ©©©'©©' © o p p © © o o © o ©' o m cc r- co © o r© r^ © co © no © © © o o © o •— r» oo r- Ji = o O -s »n © © On © © o o © © © r- o r- no r- r- no © © © © © VT -3- On On feb. CO On O © o m o o O O © © © © © © © r*-, p © p — p © m © © m m r— >n o no © no © o © r© © © ©'©©'© =S-2§5 g r^T _ -^r — O © © © ©' o o ^" P On On ™ On ^ qq © — © P © P ° © P ©' P © n*> *n © © © £J rs £ o *-. r- On no © _ o — — o o © o > fT o o © © o © © ©' ©' ©' © o o P in © P rP © P ©' ; a — rj © *d- — r- no o m © t o © « o o o o o r~ o o © o o © © o 2? TO f O — NO co o © on o o ©©'©'© On Nf> © © © © © o o o © © © © E -a -o " — TT TT — O — — © © © © © © © ©'©©'©' © © © © o m no no on — t— — p © o — © o ©' o © o o © © © © © © © p p © ©'©'©' o © © © © © o © © o © ^ v ~ § 5 S ©©'©©© ©©'©©' © < — o o ; -a _ _ ST C 5 E "S « u u 5 Is e9 I a | i |-| cu 3 >" « E Z S Its J § £ « E a Q 1! > 6b " u . Table A2. Effect of Female Leadership on Public Goods Quantity Coefficients on GP GP Reserved Previously only N At Least One New Tubewell was Built 495 At Least One Tubewell was Repaired At Least One Drainage/Sanitation At Least One Drainage/Sanitation At Least One At Least One Irrigation Irrigation Number of Metal Roads Pump was Pump was 482 Facility Facility was Built was Repaired 396 495 Built 319 Repaired Built or Repaired Since Number of transportation 495 2003 related infrastructure 495 495 (bus stop, bus service, taxi) At Least One Educational At Least One Educational Facility Facility was Built was Repaired At Least One Community Education Center There is a NGO (PHC, Health Sub Center) Facilities At Least One Health At Least One Health Number of Trained Facility Facility was (0 if no fac) Dais, Untrained Dais and Private Doctors Average Effect 495 495 495 Built was Repaired 465 495 Child Center/Creche Number of Health 495 495 495 in Reserved 2003 GP in 1998 Reserved in Mean of 2003 and Never 1998 Reserved 0.152 0.073 0.160 0.365 (0.066) (0.063) (0.088) (0.482) 0.208 0.130 0.080 0.628 (0.067) (0.064) (0.089) (0.484) 0.053 -0.113 0.052 0.428 (0.067) (0.059) (0.091) (0.496) 0.150 -0.017 0.032 0.178 (0.067) (0.062) (0.071) (0.384) 0.137 0.005 -0.013 0.180 (0.053) (0.051) (0.050) (0.385) 0.110 -0.078 -0.005 0.417 (0.092) (0.086) (0.123) (0.495) 0.274 0.046 0.079 0.118 (0.117) (0.070) (0.065) (0.448) 0.074 0.250 0.303 1.302 (0.175) (0.160) (0.225) (1.20!) 0.053 -0.030 0.026 0.117 (0.042) (0.036) (0.055) (0.322) 0.165 0.039 0.001 0.296 (0.072) (0.069) (0.097) (0.458) -0.007 0.030 -0.001 0.009 (0.010) (0.023) (0.009) (0.095) -0.045 -0.039 -0.027 0.045 (0.016) (0.021) (0.023) (0.208) -0.025 0.027 -0.005 0.257 (0.049) (0.052) (0.084) (0.468) 0.011 -0.004 -0.018 0.014 (0.015) (0.014) (0.009) (0.116) 0.061 0.016 0.047 0.009 (0.023) (0.016) (0.024) (0.095) -0.069 -0.158 0.384 1.014 (0.232) (0.226) (0.423) (2.012) 0.192 0.039 0.097 (0.070) (0.061) (0.082) Notes: 1 All regressions include block fixed effects, and standard errors are clustered by 2 Reservation status defined in Table 3 Average effect coefficients are GP. 1 from a regression on the average of all the dependent variables normalized by the mean and standard deviation of the never reserved sample. listed in the rows above Figure Al: Female/Male Politician Good/Bad Stereotypic Block Example Figure A2: Participant Performing IAT